Aranson, P. H. (1992). The common law as central economic planning. Constitutional Political Economy, 3, 289–319.
Article
Google Scholar
Barzel, Y. (2000). Dispute and its resolution: delineating the economic role of the common law. American Law and Economics Review, 2(2), 238–258.
Article
Google Scholar
Benson, B. L. (1989). The spontaneous evolution of commercial law. Southern Economic Journal, 55(3), 644–661.
Article
Google Scholar
Cenini, M., & Parisi, F. (2010). Punitive damages and class actions. In J. G. Backhaus, A. Cassone & G. Ramello (Eds.), Class actions for Europe: perspectives from law and economics. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.
Google Scholar
Coase, R. H. (1960). The problem of social cost. Journal of Law and Economics, 3, 1–44.
Article
Google Scholar
Cooter, R., & Kornhauser, L. (1980). Can litigation improve the law without the help of judges? Journal of Legal Studies, 9(1), 139–163.
Article
Google Scholar
Cooter, R. D., & Rubinfeld, D. L. (1989). Economic analysis of legal disputes and their resolution. Journal of Economic Literature, 27, 1067–1097.
Google Scholar
Dari-Mattiacci, G., & Parisi, F. (2005). Rents, dissipation, and lost treasures: rethinking Tullock’s paradox. Public Choice, 124, 411–422.
Article
Google Scholar
Erlich, I., & Posner, R. A. (1974). An economic analysis of legal rulemaking. Journal of Legal Studies, 3, 257–286.
Article
Google Scholar
Eisenberg, M. A. (1988). The nature of the common law. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.
Google Scholar
Fon, V., & Parisi, F. (2003). Litigation and the evolution of legal remedies: a dynamic model. Public Choice, 116, 419–433.
Article
Google Scholar
Fon, V., Parisi, F., & Depoorter, B. (2005). Litigation, judicial path-dependence, and legal change. European Journal of Law and Economics, 20, 43–56.
Article
Google Scholar
Goodman, J. C. (1978). An economic theory of the evolution of common law. Journal of Legal Studies, 7(2), 393–406.
Article
Google Scholar
Gould, J. P. (1973). The economics of legal conflicts. Journal of Legal Studies, 2, 279–300.
Article
Google Scholar
Hadfield, G. K. (1992). Biases in the evolution of legal rules. Georgetown Law Journal, 80, 583–616.
Google Scholar
Hayek, F. (1973). Law, legislation and liberty. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Google Scholar
Hathaway, O. A. (2001). Path dependence in the law: the course and pattern of legal change in a common law system. Iowa Law Review, 86, 601–661.
Google Scholar
Hirshleifer, J. (1982). Evolutionary models in economics and law. In R. Zerbe (Ed.), Research in law and economics (Vol. 4, pp. 1–60). New York: JAI Press.
Google Scholar
Hylton, K. N. (2006). Information, litigation and common law evolution. American Law and Economics Review, 8(1), 33–61.
Article
Google Scholar
Kaplow, L. (1986). Private versus social costs in bringing suits. Journal of Legal Studies, 15, 371–385.
Article
Google Scholar
La Porta, R., Lopez-de-Silanes, F., Shleifer, A., & Vishny, R. W. (1998). Law and finance. Journal of Political Economy, 106(6), 1113–1155.
Article
Google Scholar
Landes, W. M. (1971). An economic analysis of the courts. Journal of Law and Economics, 14, 61–107.
Article
Google Scholar
Landes, W. M., & Posner, R. A. (1975). The independent judiciary in an interest-group perspective. Journal of Law and Economics, 18, 875–901.
Article
Google Scholar
Landes, W. M., & Posner, R. A. (1979). Adjudication as a private good. Journal of Legal Studies, 8(2, Special Issue), 235–284.
Article
Google Scholar
Mahoney, P. G. (2001). The common law and economic growth: Hayek might be right. Journal of Legal Studies, 30, 503–525.
Article
Google Scholar
Menell, P. (1983). A note on private versus social incentives to sue in a costly legal system. Journal of Legal Studies, 15, 41–52.
Article
Google Scholar
Parisi, F. (2002). Rent-seeking through litigation: adversarial and inquisitorial systems compared. International Review of Law and Economics, 22, 193–216.
Article
Google Scholar
Parisi, F., & Fon, V. (2009). The economics of lawmaking. London: Oxford University Press.
Book
Google Scholar
Posner, R. A. (1975). The economic approach to law. Texas Law Review, 53, 757–782.
Google Scholar
Posner, R. A. (1994). What do judges and justices maximize? (The same thing everybody else does). Supreme Court Economic Review, 3, 1–41.
Google Scholar
Priest, G. L. (1977). The common law process and the selection of efficient rules. Journal of Legal Studies, 6, 65–82.
Article
Google Scholar
Priest, G. L., & Klein, B. (1984). The selection of disputes for Litigation. Journal of Legal Studies, 13, 1–55.
Article
Google Scholar
Rose-Ackerman, S., & Geistfeld, M. (1987). The divergence between social and private incentives to sue: a comment on Shavell, Menell, and Kaplow. Journal of Legal Studies, 16, 483–491.
Article
Google Scholar
Roe, M. J. (1996). Chaos and evolution in law and economics. Harvard Law Review, 109(3), 641–668.
Article
Google Scholar
Rowley, C. K. (1989). The common law in public choice perspective: a theoretical and institutional critique. Hamline Law Review, 12, 355–383.
Google Scholar
Rubin, P. H. (1977). Why is the common law efficient? Journal of Legal Studies, 6, 51–63.
Article
Google Scholar
Rubin, P. H. (1982). Common law and statute law. Journal of Legal Studies, 11, 205–223.
Article
Google Scholar
Rubin, P. H. (2005). Micro and macro legal efficiency: supply and demand. Supreme Court Economic Review, 13, 19–34.
Google Scholar
Rubin, P. H. (2007). The evolution of efficient common law. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.
Google Scholar
Rubin, P. H., & Bailey, M. (1994). The role of lawyers in changing the law. Journal of Legal Studies, 23, 807–831.
Article
Google Scholar
Shavell, S. (1982). The social versus the private incentive to bring suit in a costly legal system. Journal of Legal Studies, 11, 333–339.
Article
Google Scholar
Shavell, S. (1997). The fundamental divergence between the private and the social motive to use the legal system. Journal of Legal Studies, 26, 575–612.
Article
Google Scholar
Shavell, S. (1999). The level of litigation: private versus social optimality of suit and of settlement. International Review of Law and Economics, 19, 99–115.
Article
Google Scholar
Stake, J. E. (2005). Evolution of rules in a common law system: differential litigation of the fee tail and other perpetuities. Florida State Law Review, 32(2), 401.
Google Scholar
Terrebonne, R. P. (1981). A strictly evolutionary model of common law. Journal of Legal Studies, 10(2), 397–407.
Article
Google Scholar
Tullock, G. (1967). The welfare cost of tariffs, monopolies and theft. Western Economic Journal, 5, 224–232.
Google Scholar
Tullock, G. (1971). The logic of law. New York: Basic Books.
Google Scholar
Tullock, G. (1980). Efficient rent-seeking. In J. M. Buchanan, G. Tollison & G. Tullock (Eds.), Toward a theory of the rent-seeking society (pp. 97–112). College Station: Texas A&M University Press.
Google Scholar
Tullock, G. (1997). The case against the common law. Durham: Carolina Academic Press.
Google Scholar
Tullock, G. (2004). On the efficient organization of trials. In C. K. Rowley (Ed.), The selected works of Gordon Tullock (Vol. 1). Indianapolis: Liberty Funds.
Google Scholar
Tullock, G. (2005a). Rent seeking and the law. In C. K. Rowley (Ed.), The selected works of Gordon Tullock (Vol. 5). Indianapolis: Liberty Funds.
Google Scholar
Tullock, G. (2005b). Technology: the anglo-saxons versus the rest of the world. In Trials on trial: the pure theory of legal procedure (New York: Columbia University Press, 1980). Reprinted: In C. K. Rowley (Ed.), The selected works of Gordon Tullock (Vol. 9). Indianapolis: Liberty Funds.
Google Scholar
Tullock, G. (2005c). The case against the common law (1997, Carolina Academic Press). In C. K. Rowley (Ed.), The selected works of Gordon Tullock (Vol. 9). Indianapolis: Liberty Funds.
Google Scholar
Zywicki, T. J. (2003). The rise and fall of efficiency in the common law. Northwestern University Law Review, 97, 1551.
Google Scholar
Zywicki, T. J. (2008). Spontaneous order and the common law: Gordon Tullock’s critique. Public Choice, 135, 35–53.
Article
Google Scholar