Skip to main content
Log in

Voting for Pareto optimality: a multidimensional analysis

  • Published:
Public Choice Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

We compare unanimity rule and majority rule in their abilities to produce Pareto superior and Pareto optimal alternatives in fixed number of rounds of voting using a two-dimensional spatial voting model with random proposals, sincere proposals, and strategic proposals. Our findings show that for random or sincere proposals, majority rule is at least as likely to select a Pareto optimal outcome as unanimity rule. For strategic proposals, the subgame perfect equilibrium under unanimity rule is Pareto optimal. For other k-majority rules, the outcome is Pareto optimal or very close to it. For outcomes that are both Pareto optimal and Pareto superior, unanimity rule outperforms majority rule.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

References

  • Aldrich, J. (1995). Why parties? Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Arrow, K. (1951). Social choice and individual values. New York: Wiley.

    Google Scholar 

  • Austen-Smith, D., & Banks, J. (2005). Positive political theory II: strategy and structure. Ann Arbor: The University of Michigan Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Banks, J. (1985). Sophisticated voting outcomes and agenda control. Social Choice and Welfare, 1(4), 295–306.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Becker, G. S. (1962). Irrational behavior and economic theory. Journal of Political Economy, 70(1), 1–13.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bianco, W. T., Lynch, M. S. Miller G. J., & Sened, I. (2008). The constrained instability of majority rule: experiments on the robustness of the uncovered set. Political Analysis, 16, 115–137.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brennan, G., & Buchanan, J. M. (2000). The reason of rules. Indianapolis: Liberty Fund.

    Google Scholar 

  • Buchanan, J. M. (1967). Public finance in democratic process. Chapel Hill: The University of North Carolina Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Buchanan, J. M., & Tullock, G. (1962). The calculus of consent. Ann Arbor: The University of Michigan Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chen, Y., & Ordeshook, P. C. (1998). Veto games: spatial committees under unanimity rule. Public Choice, 97, 617–643.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Colomer, J. M. (2001). Political institutions: democracy and social choice. New York: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Compte, O., & Jehiel, P. (2004). Bargaining over randomly generated offers: a new perspective on multi-party bargaining. C.E.R.A.S.-E.N.P.C., C.N.R.S., France.

  • Cornes, R., & Sandler, T. (1996). The theory of externalities, public goods, and club goods (2nd edn.). New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Denzau, A., Riker, W., & Shepsle, K. A. (1985). Farquharson and fenno: sophisticated voting and home style. American Political Science Review, 79(4), 1117–1134.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dougherty, K. L., & Edward, J. (2004). The Pareto efficiency and expected costs of k-majority rules. Politics, Philosophy, and Economics, 3(2), 161–189.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dougherty, K. L., & Edward, J. (2005). A nonequilibrium analysis of unanimity rule, majority rule, and Pareto. Economic Inquiry, 43(4), 855–864.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Duggan, J. (2006). Endogenous voting agendas. Social Choice and Welfare, 27, 495–530.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fabella, R. (2000). A contractarian approach to Pareto efficiency in teams: a note. Theory and Decision, 48(2), 139–149.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Feld, S. L., Grofman, B., & Miller, N. (1988). Centripetal forces in spatial voting: on the size of the yolk. Public Choice, 59(1), 37–50.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ferejohn, J. A., McKelvey, R. D., & Packel, E. W. (1984). Limiting distributions for continous state Markov voting models. Social Choice and Welfare, 1, 45–67.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gode, D. K., & Sunder, S. (1993). Allocative efficiency of markets with zero intelligence (zi) traders: market as a partial substitute for individual rationality. Journal of Political Economy, 101(1), 119–137.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gode, D. K., & Sunder, S. (1997). What makes markets allocationally efficient. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 112(2), 603–630.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Groseclose, T., & Milyo, J. (2010). Sincere versus sophisticated voting in Congress: theory and evidence. Journal of Politics, 71(1), 60–73.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hammond, T. H., & Miller, G. J. (1987). The core of the constitution. The American Political Science Review, 81(4), 1155–1174.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hinich, M., & Munger, M. C. (1997). Analytical politics. New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Janis, I. L. (1972). Groupthink: psychological studies of policy decisions and fiascoes. Boston: Houghton Mifflin.

    Google Scholar 

  • Johnson, D. B. (1991). Public choice: an introduction to the new political economy. Mountain View: Bristlecone Books.

    Google Scholar 

  • Krehbiel, K. (1998). Pivotal politics: a theory of U.S. lawmaking. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lindahl, E. ([1919] 1967). Classics in the theory of public finance. New York: St. Martin’s Press. Chapter Just taxation—a positive solution, pp. 168–176.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lord, C. (1984). Roll calls of the continental congresses and the congresses of the confederation, 1777–1789. ICPSR data set 7537.

  • McKelvey, R. D. (1976). Intransitivities in multidimensional voting models and some implications for agenda control. Journal of Economic Theory, 12, 472–82.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McKelvey, R. D. (1986). Covering, dominance, and institution-free properties of social choice. American Journal of Political Science, 30(2), 283–314.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Miller, G. J., & Hammond, T. H. (1990). Committees and the core of the constitution. Public Choice, 66(3), 201–227.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mueller, D. (2003). Public choice III. New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Niou, E. M. S., & Ordeshook, P. C. (1985). Universalism in Congress. American Journal of Political Science, 29(2), 246–258.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ordeshook, P. (1986). Game theory and political theory. New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Ostrom, E. (1990). Governing the commons. New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Penn, E. M. (2009). A model of farsighted voting. American Journal of Political Science, 53(1), 36–54.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Plott, C. R. (1967). A notion of equilibrium and its possibility under majority rule. American Economic Review, 57, 787–806.

    Google Scholar 

  • Poole, K. T., & Rosenthal, H. (1997). Congress: a political-economic history of roll call voting. New York: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Riker, W. H. (1980). Implications from the disequilibrium of majority rule for the study of institutions. American Political Science Review, 74(2), 432–446.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schofield, N. J. (1978). Instability of simple dynamic games. Review of Economic Studies, 45, 575–594.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sen, A. K. (1979). Collective choice and social welfare. New York: North-Holland.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sen, A. K. (1987). On ethics and economics. New York: Blackwell.

    Google Scholar 

  • Shepsle, K. A. (1979). Institutional arrangements and equilibrium in multidimensional voting models. American Journal of Political Science, 23(1), 27–59.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shepsle, K. A., & Weingast, B. R. (1984). Uncovered sets and sophisticated voting outcomes with implications for agenda institutions. American Journal of Political Science, 28(1), 49–74.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sins, H. (1980). A rehabilitation of the principle of insufficient reason. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 94(3), 493–506.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stewart, C. (2001). Analyzing Congress. New York: Norton.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tsebelis, G. (2002). Veto players: how political institutions work. New York: Russell Sage Foundation.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tullock, G. (1998). On voting: a public choice approach. Northampton: Edward Elgar.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tversky, A., & Kahneman, D. (1974). Judgment under uncertainty: heuristics and biases. Science, 185(4157), 1124–1131.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Keith L. Dougherty.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Dougherty, K.L., Edward, J. Voting for Pareto optimality: a multidimensional analysis. Public Choice 151, 655–678 (2012). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-011-9763-5

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-011-9763-5

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation