Skip to main content
Log in

Appropriation, violent enforcement, and transaction costs: a critical survey

  • Literature Survey
  • Published:
Public Choice Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This paper focuses on the extension of transaction costs to appropriative activity and coercive power in the property rights approach. It has been argued that including the costs of appropriation and violent enforcement in transaction costs is based on the assumption that Coaseian bargaining can be extended to any institutional scenario, i.e., voluntary as well as coercive exchange. However, voluntary transactions cannot capture the logic of coercive power. This means that the assumption of an efficient political market is not valid, and that the “political Coase theorem” lacks the logical consistency to provide a cornerstone for political theory.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

References

  • Acemoglu, D. (2003). Why not a political Coase theorem? Social conflict, commitment, and politics. Journal of Comparative Economics, 31, 620–652.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Alchian, A., & Woodword, J. (1988). The firm is dead; long live the firm. Journal of Economic Literature, 26(1), 65–79.

    Google Scholar 

  • Allen, D. (1991). What are transactions costs? Research in Law and Economics, 14, 1–18.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Allen, D. (2000). Transaction costs. In B. Bouckaert & G. Degeest (Eds.), The encyclopedia of law and economics : Vol. 1. The history and methodology of law and economics (pp. 893–926). Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.

    Google Scholar 

  • Anderson, J., & Marcouiller, D. (2002). Insecurity and the pattern of trade: An empirical investigation. Review of Economics and Statistics, 84(2), 342–352.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Anderson, J., & Marcouiller, D. (2005). Anarchy and autarky: Endogenous predation as a barrier to trade. International Economic Review, 46(1), 189–231.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ankarloo, D., & Palermo, G. (2004). Anti-Williamson: A Marxian critique of new institutional economics. Cambridge Journal of Economics, 28, 413–429.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Arrow, K. (1962a). Economic welfare and the allocation of resources for invention. In K. Arrow (Ed.), The rate and direction of inventive activity: economic and social factors (pp. 609–625). Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Arrow, K. (1962b). The economic implications of learning by doing. Review of Economic Studies, 29, 155–173.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Arrow, K. (1965). Knowledge, productivity, and practice. Bulletin SEDEIS, Etudes no 909, Suppl.

  • Barzel, Y. (1974). A theory of rationing by waiting. Journal of Law and Economics, 17(1), 73–95.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barzel, Y. (1977). An economic analysis of slavery. Journal of Law and Economics, 20(1), 87–110.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barzel, Y. (1982). Measurement cost and the organization of markets. Journal of Law and Economics, 25, 27–48.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barzel, Y. (1985). Transaction costs: Are they just costs? Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics, 141, 4–16.

    Google Scholar 

  • Barzel, Y. (1997). Economic analysis of property rights (2nd ed.). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Barzel, Y. (1999). Property rights and the evolution of the state (Working Paper). Washington: University of Washington, June.

  • Barzel, Y. (2002). A theory of the state, economic rights, legal rights, and the scope of the state. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Becker, G. (1983). A Theory of competition among pressure groups for political influence. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 98(3), 371–400.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Becker, G. (1985). Public policies, pressure groups, and dead weight costs. Journal of Public Economics, 28, 329–347.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Berggren, N., & Karlson, N. (2003). Constitutionalism, division of power and transaction costs. Public Choice, 117, 99–124.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Block, W. (1976). Defending the undefendable: The pimp, prostitute, scab, slumlord, libeler, moneylender, and other scapegoats in the rogue’s gallery of American society. New York: Fleet Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bowles, S., & Jayadev, A. (2007). Garison America. Economics Voice. The Berkeley Electronic Press, March. www.bepress.com/ev.

  • Buchanan, J. (1973). The Coase theorem and the theory of the state. Natural Resources Journal, 13, 579–594.

    Google Scholar 

  • Buchanan, J. (1975). The limits of liberty: between anarchy and Leviathan. Chicago: Chicago University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Buchanan, J. (1986). Liberty, market, and state: political economy in the 1980s. Brighton: Wheatsheaf Books.

    Google Scholar 

  • Buchanan, J. (1987). Economics: between predictive science and moral philosophy. College Station: A & M University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Buchanan, J. (1992). Better than plowing and other personal essays. Chicago: Chicago University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bush, W. (1972). Individual welfare in anarchy. In G. Tullock (Ed.), Explorations in the theory of anarchy (pp. 5–18). Blacksburg: Center for the Study of Public Choice.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bush, W., & Mayer, L. (1974). Some implications of anarchy for the distribution of property. Journal of Economic Theory, 8, 401–412.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Calabresi, G. (1991). The pointlessness of Pareto: Carrying Coase further. Yale Law Journal, 100(5), 1211–1237.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Caplan, B. (2005). From Friedman to Wittman: The transformation of Chicago political economy. Economic Journal Watch, 2(1), 1–21.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cheung, S. (1969). A theory of share tenancy. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cheung, S. (1970). The structure of a contract and the theory of a non-exclusive resource. Journal of Law and Economics, 13(1), 49–70.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cheung, S. (1974). A theory of price control. Journal of Law and Economics, 17, 53–72.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Coase, R. (1937). The nature of the firm. Economica, 4(16), 386–405.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Coase, R. (1959). The federal communications commission. Journal of Law and Economics, 2, 1–40.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Coase, R. (1960). The problem of social cost. Journal of Law and Economics, 3, 1–44.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Coase, R. (1988a). Blackmail. Virginia Law Review, 74(4), 655–676.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Coase, R. (1988b). Six: Notes on the problem of social cost. In R. Coase (Ed.), The firm, the market and the law (pp. 157–185). Chicago: The University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Coase, R. (1988c). One: The firm, the market, and the law. In R. Coase (Ed.), The firm, the market and the law (pp. 1–31). Chicago: The University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Coase, R. (1992). The institutional structure of production. American Economic Review, 82(4), 713–719.

    Google Scholar 

  • Coleman, J. (1988). Markets, morals and the law. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cooter, R. (1982). The cost of Coase. The Journal of Legal Studies, 11(1), 1–33.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cooter, R. (1995). The Coase theorem and international economic relations. Japan and the World Economy, 7(1), 29–44.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Coyne, C. (2005). Social interaction without the state. In E. Stringham (Ed.), Anarchy, state and public choice (pp. 49–59). Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.

    Google Scholar 

  • Demsetz, H. (1964). The exchange and enforcement of property rights. Journal of Law and Economics, 7, 11–26.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Demsetz, H. (1988). The theory of the firm revisited. Journal of Law and Economics and Organization, 4, 141–161.

    Google Scholar 

  • Demsetz, H. (1997). The economics of the business firm: seven critical commentaries. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Demsetz, H. (2008). From economic man to economic system: essays on human behaviour and the institutions of capitalism. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Demsetz, H. (2010). The problem of social cost: What problem? (Unpublished Manuscript). Los Angeles, California, University of California.

  • Dietrich, M. (1994). Transaction cost economics and beyond. London: Routledge.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Dixit, A., & Olson, M. (2000). Does voluntary participation undermine the Coase theorem? Journal of Public Economics, 76, 309–335.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fourie, F. (1993). In the beginning there were markets? In C. Pitelis (Ed.), Transaction costs, markets and hierarchies. Oxford: Basil Blackwell.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gardner, B. (1983). Efficient redistribution through commodity markets. American Journal of Agricultural Economics, 65, 225–234.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Garfinkel, M., & Skaperdas, S. (2007). Economics of conflict: An overview. In T. Sandler & K. Hartley (Eds.), Handbook of defense economics : Vol. 2. Defense in a globalized world (pp. 649–709). Amsterdam: North-Holland, Chap. 22.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Hicks, J. (1935). A suggestion for simplifying the theory of money. Economics, 2, 1–19.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hodgson, G. (1988). Economics and institutions, a manifesto for a modern institutional economics. Cambridge: Polity Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hsiung, B. (2003). Reconciling Coase and Buchanan on the Coase theorem. Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics, 159, 392–413.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hsiung, B. (2004). Coase theorem and the Taiwan strait conflict. Kyklos, 57(4), 505–518.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jayadev, A., & Bowles, S. (2006). Guard labor. Journal of Development Economics, 79, 328–348.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Knight, J. (1992). Institutions and social conflict. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Krueger, A. (1974). The political economy of the rent-seeking society. American Economic Review, 64(3), 291–303.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kurrild-Klitgaard, P., & Svendsen, G. T. (2003). Rational bandits: Plunder, public goods, and the Vikings. Public Choice, 117(3–4), 255–272.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lange, O. (1936/1964). On the economic theory of socialism. In B. Lippincott (Ed.), On the economic theory of socialism (pp. 55–143). New York: McGraw-Hill.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lenin, V. I. (1916/1999). The state and revolution. Chippendale: Resistance Books.

    Google Scholar 

  • Long, N., & Sorger, G. (2004). Insecure property rights and growth: The roles of appropriation costs, wealth effects, and heterogeneity (CESIFO Working Paper, No. 1253). August. www.ssrn.com.

  • Mack, E. (1982). In defense of blackmail. Philosophical Studies, 41(2), 273–284.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mann, M. (1986). The sources of social power : Vol. 1. A history of power from the beginning to A.D. 1760. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Marx, K. (1867/1978). Capital, a critique of political economy. Moscow: Progress. 3 Volumes.

    Google Scholar 

  • Marx, K. (1973). Grundrisse. New York: Vintage Books.

    Google Scholar 

  • Medema, S., & Zerbe, R. (2000). The Coase theorem. In B. Bouckaert & G. De Geest (Eds.), Encyclopedia of law and economics (Vol. I, pp. 836–92). Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.

    Google Scholar 

  • Milonakis, D., & Fine, B. (2007). Douglass North’s remaking of economic history: A critical appraisal. Review of Radical Political Economics, 39, 27–57.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Moss, L. (1974). Private property anarchism: An American variant. In G. Tullock (Ed.), Further explorations in the theory of anarchy (pp. 1–31). Blacksburg: Center for the Study of Public Choice.

    Google Scholar 

  • North, D. (1981). Structure and change in economic history. New York: Norton.

    Google Scholar 

  • North, D. (1989). A transaction cost approach to the historical development of politics and economies. Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics, 145, 661–668.

    Google Scholar 

  • North, D. (1990a). Institutions, institutional change and economic performance. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • North, D. (1990b). A Transaction Cost Theory of Politics. Journal of Theoretical Politics, 2(4), 355–367.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • North, D. (1992). Transaction costs, institutions, and economic performance (Occasional Papers, No. 30). International Centre for Economic Growth, 32 pages.

  • North, D. (1993). Institutions and credible commitment. Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics, 149(1), 11–23.

    Google Scholar 

  • North, D., & Thomas, R. (1973). The rise of the Western world, a new economic history. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Nozick, R. (1974). Anarchy, state, and utopia. New York: Basic Books.

    Google Scholar 

  • Olson, M. (1965/1980). The logic of collective action, public goods and the theory of groups. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Olson, M. (1982). The rise and decline of nations: Economic growth, stagflation, and social rigidities. New Haven: Yale University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Olson, M. (1990). How bright are the northern lights? Some questions about Sweden. Lund: Institute of Economic Research, Lund University.

    Google Scholar 

  • Olson, M. (2000). Power and prosperity, outgrowing Communist and Capitalist dictatorships. New York: Basic Books.

    Google Scholar 

  • Palermo, G. (2000). Economic power and the firm in new institutional economics: The conflicting problems. Journal of Economic Issues, 34(3), 573–601.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pareto, V. (1927/1971). Manual of political economy, New York: A. M. Kelley.

    Google Scholar 

  • Powell, B., & Stringham, E. (2009). Public choice and the economic analysis of anarchy: A survey. Public Choice, 140, 530–538.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Powell, B., & Wilson, B. (2008). An experimental investigation of Hobbesian jungles. Journal of Economic Behaviour and Organization, 66, 669–686.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Samuels, W. J. (1974). The Coase theorem and the study of law and economics. Natural Resource Journal, 14(1), 1–33.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schlag, P. (1989). The problem of transaction costs. Southern California Law Review, 62, 1661–1699.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schlicht, E. (1996). Exploiting the Coase mechanism: The extortion problem. Kyklos, 49(3), 319–330.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schlicht, E. (1997). The Coase mechanism and the iteration argument: Reply. Kyklos, 50(4), 581–585.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Simmel, G. (1987). Philosophie de l’argent. Paris: PUF.

    Google Scholar 

  • Skaperdas, S., & Syropoulos, C. (2002). Insecure property and the inefficiency of exchange. Economic Journal, 112, 133–146.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Smith, A. (1776/1961). An inquiry into the nature and causes of the wealth of nations. London: Methuen.

    Google Scholar 

  • Stefanadis, C. (2007). Appropriation, property rights, and openness to international trade (Working Paper). Department of Agricultural and Resource Economics, University of Arizona.

  • Stigler, J. (1966). The theory of price (3rd ed.). New York: Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Stigler, G. (1992). Law or economics? Journal of Law and Economics, 35(2), 455–468.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Taylor, M. (1982). Community, anarchy and liberty. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Taylor, M. (1987). The possibility of cooperation. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Thompson, E., & Faith, R. (1981). A pure theory of strategic behaviour and social institutions. American Economic Review, 71, 366–380.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tilly, C. (1985). War making and state making as organized crime. In T. Skocpol & P. Evans (Eds.), Bringing the state back in (pp. 169–191). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Tornell, A., & Lane, P. (1999). The voracity effect. The American Economic Review, 89, 22–46.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tornell, A., & Velasco, A. (1992). The tragedy of commons and economic growth. Journal of Political Economy, 100, 1208–1231.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tullock, G. (1967). The welfare costs of tariffs, monopolies, and theft. Western Economic Journal, 5(3), 224–232.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tullock, G. (Ed.) (1972). Explorations in the theory of anarchy. Blacksburg: Center for the Study of Public Choice.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tullock, G. (Ed.) (1974a). Further explorations in the theory of anarchy. Blacksburg: University Publications.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tullock, G. (Ed.) (1974b). The social dilemma: The economics of war and revolution. Blacksburg: University Publications.

    Google Scholar 

  • Vahabi, M. (2002). From the Walrasian general equilibrium to incomplete contracts: Making sense of institutions. Economie et Institutions (Economics and Institutions), 1, 99–143.

    Google Scholar 

  • Vahabi, M. (2004). The political economy of destructive power. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.

    Google Scholar 

  • Vahabi, M. (2009a). An introduction to destructive coordination. American Journal of Economics and Sociology, 68(2), 353–386.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Vahabi, M. (2009b). A critical review of strategic conflict theory and socio-political instability models. Revue d’Economie Politique, 119(6), 679–720.

    Google Scholar 

  • Vahabi, M. (2010a). Integrating social conflict into economic theory. Cambridge Journal of Economics, 34(4), 687–709. doi:10.1093/cje/bep043, 14 July 2009.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Vahabi, M. (2010b, forthcoming). Economics of destructive power. In D. Braddon & K. Hartley (Eds.), Elgar handbook on the economics of conflict. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar. Chap. 5.

    Google Scholar 

  • Vira, B. (1997). The political Coase theorem: Identifying differences between neoclassical and critical institutionalism. Journal of Economic Issues, 31(3), 761–779.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wallis, J., & North, D. (1986). Measuring the transaction sector in the American economy, 1870–1970. In S. Engerman & R. Gallman (Eds.), Long term factors in American economic growth (pp. 95–148). Chicago: Chicago University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wallis, J., & North, D. (1988). Should transaction costs be subtracted from gross national product. The Journal of Economic History, 48(3), 651–654.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • White, L. (2008). Can economics rank slavery against free labor in terms of efficiency? Politics, Philosophy & Economics, 7, 327–340.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Williamson, O. (1975). Markets and hierarchies: Analysis of anti-trust implications. New York: Free Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Williamson, O. (1979). Transaction cost economics: The governance of contractual relations. Journal of Law and Economics, 22(2), 233–261.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Williamson, O. (1985). The economic institutions of Capitalism. Firms, markets, relational contracting. New York: Free Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Williamson, O. (1989). The firm as a nexus of treaties: An introduction. In M. Aoki, B. Gustafsson, & O. Williamson (Eds.), The firm as a nexus of treaties (pp. 1–26). London: SCASS, Sage.

    Google Scholar 

  • Williamson, O. (1992). Markets, hierarchies, and the modern corporation: An unfolding perspective. Journal of Economic Behaviour and Organization, 17(3), 335–352.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Williamson, O. (1996). The mechanisms of governance. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wittman, D. (1989). Why democracies produce efficient results. The Journal of Political Economy, 97(6), 1395–1424.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wittman, D. (1995). The myth of democratic failure: Why political institutions are efficient. Chicago: Chicago University Press.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Mehrdad Vahabi.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Vahabi, M. Appropriation, violent enforcement, and transaction costs: a critical survey. Public Choice 147, 227–253 (2011). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-010-9721-7

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-010-9721-7

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation