Skip to main content

The information content of elections and varieties of the partisan political business cycle

Abstract

This event study uses economic forecasts and opinion polls to measure the response of expectations to election surprise. Use of forecast data complements older work on partisan cycles by allowing a tighter link between election and response thereby mitigating concerns of endogeneity and omitted variables. I find that forecasters respond swiftly and significantly to election surprise. I further argue that the response ought to vary across countries with different institutional foundations. In support, I find that there exist three distinct patterns in forecasters’ responses to partisan surprise corresponding to Hall and Soskice’s three varieties of capitalism.

This is a preview of subscription content, access via your institution.

References

  • Alesina, A. (1987). Macroeconomic policy in a two-party system as a repeated game. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 102, 651–678.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Alesina, A. (1988). Macroeconomics and politics. NBER Macroeconomics Annual, 11-55.

  • Alesina, A. (1989). Inflation, unemployment, and politics in industrial democracies. Economic Policy, 8, 55–98.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Alesina, A., & Rosenthal, H. (1995). Partisan politics, divided government, and the economy. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Alesina, A., & Summers, L. (1993). Central bank independence and macroeconomic performance. Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking, 25, 157–162.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Alesina, A., & Sachs, J. (1988). Political parties and the business cycle in the United States, 1948–1984. Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking, 20, 63–82.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Alesina, A., Roubini, N., & Cohen, G. (1997). Political cycles and the macroeconomy. Cambridge: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Banks, A., Overstreet, W., & Muller, T. (1988–2002). Political handbook of the world. Washington: CQ Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Barro, R., & Gordon, D. (1983). Rules, discretion, and reputation in a model of monetary policy. Journal of Monetary Economics, 12, 101–121.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Berlemann, M., & Markwardt, G. (2003) Partisan cycles and pre-electoral uncertainty. Unpublished manuscript.

  • Chappell, H., & Keech, W. (1988). The unemployment consequences of partisan monetary regimes. Southern Economic Journal, 55, 107–122.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cukierman, A. (1992). Central bank strategy, credibility, and independence. Cambridge: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dixit, A., & Lambertini, L. (2003). Interactions of commitment and discretion in monetary and fiscal policies. American Economic Review, 93, 1522–42.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Drazen, A. (2000). The political business cycle after 25 years. NBER Macroeconomics Annual, 15, 75–117.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Evans, C., & Marshall, D. (2001). Economic determinants of the nominal treasury yield curve. WP-01-16, Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago.

  • Gallo, G., Granger, C., & Jeon, Y. (2002). Copycats and common swings: the impact of the use of forecasts in information sets. IMF Staff Papers, 49, 4–21.

    Google Scholar 

  • Grier, K. (2008). US presidential elections and real GDP growth, 1961–2004. Public Choice, 135, 337–352.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hall, P., & Soskice, D. (2001). An introduction to varieties of capitalism. In Hall, P. & Soskice, D. (Eds.), Varieties of capitalism pp. 1–68. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Heckelman, J. (2002). Variable rational partisan business cycles: theory and some evidence. Canadian Journal of Economics, 35, 568–585.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hibbs, D. (1977). Political parties and macroeconomic policy. American Political Science Review, 71, 1467–1487.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hibbs, D. (1987). The political economy of industrial democracies. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hibbs, D. (1992). Partisan theory after fifteen years. European Journal of Political Economy, 8, 361–373.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mankiw, N. G., & Reis, R. (2002). Sticky information: a model of monetary non-neutrality and structural slumps. NBER Working Paper 8614.

  • Mankiw, N. G., Reis, R., & Wolfers, J. (2003). Disagreement about inflation expectations. NBER Working Paper No. 9796.

  • North, D. (1990). Institutions, institutional change, and economic performance. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rogoff, K. (1985). The optimal commitment to an intermediate monetary target. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 100, 1169–90.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Williamson, O. (1985). The economic institutions of capitalism. New York: Free Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wlezien, C., & Erikson, R. (2002). The timeline of presidential election campaigns. Journal of Politics, 64, 969–993.

    Google Scholar 

  • Woodford, M. (2002). Inflation stabilization and welfare. Contributions to Macroeconomics, 2(1), article 1.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Cameron A. Shelton.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and Permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Shelton, C.A. The information content of elections and varieties of the partisan political business cycle. Public Choice 150, 209–240 (2012). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-010-9699-1

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-010-9699-1

Keywords

  • Political business cycle
  • Varieties of capitalism
  • Forecast data
  • Opinion polls

JEL Classification

  • E32
  • E63
  • P16
  • P51