Abstract
Many terror attacks occur at the beginning of electoral terms. We present a game theoretical model with incomplete information to account for this empirical pattern. Both terrorists and governments can be of weak or strong types. We find that the risk of terror attacks is highest at the beginning of electoral terms, because striking early allows the terrorists to collect valuable information about the government’s type, and also because terrorists know that even initially weak governments sometimes retaliate to show toughness closer to an upcoming election. The model’s predictions are consistent with anecdotal evidence.
This is a preview of subscription content,
to check access.References
Azam, J.-P., & Thelen, V. (2008). The roles of foreign aid and education in the war on terror. Public Choice, 135, 375–397.
Bali, V. (2007). Terror and elections: lessons from Spain. Electoral Studies, 26, 669–687.
Barros, C., Passos, J., & Gil-Alana, L. (2006). The timing of ETA terrorist attacks. Journal of Policy Modeling, 28, 335–346.
Basuchoudhary, A., & Shughart, W. F. II. (2010). On ethnic conflict and the origins of transnational terrorism. Defence and Peace Economics, 21, 65–87.
Berman, E. (2009). Radical, religious, and violent: the new economics of terrorism. Cambridge: MIT Press.
Berman, E., & Laitin, D. (2008). Religion, terrorism and public goods: testing the club model. Journal of Public Economics, 92, 1942–1967.
Berrebi, C., & Klor, E. (2006). On terrorism and electoral outcomes: theory and evidence from the Israeli-Palestinian conflict. Journal of Conflict Resolution, 50, 899–925.
Bueno de Mesquita, E. (2005). Conciliation, counterterrorism, and patterns of terrorist violence. International Organization, 59, 145–176.
Bueno de Mesquita, E. (2007). Politics and the suboptimal provision of counterterror. International Organization, 61, 9–36.
Buenrostro, L., Dhillon, A., & Wooders, M. (2007). Protests and reputation. International Journal of Game Theory, 35, 353–377.
Cauley, J., & Im, E. I. (1988). Intervention policy analysis of skyjackings and other terrorist incidents. American Economic Review, 78, 27–31.
Crettez, B., & Deloche, R. (2010). Terrorism, key assets, and critical infrastructures: to protect or to rebuild? That is the question. Public Choice, 144, 105–118.
Enders, W., & Sandler, T. (1993). The effectiveness of antiterrorism policies: A vector-autoregression-intervention analysis. American Political Science Review, 87, 829–844.
Enders, W., & Sandler, T. (2006). The political economy of terrorism. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Frey, B. S., & Rohner, D. (2007). Protecting cultural monuments against terrorism. Defence and Peace Economics, 18, 245–252.
Frey, B. S., Luechinger, S., & Stutzer, A. (2009). The life satisfaction approach to valuing public goods: the case of terrorism. Public Choice, 138, 317–345.
Gassebner, M., Jong-A-Pin, R., & Mierau, J. (2008). Terrorism and electoral accountability: one strike, you’re out! Economics Letters, 100, 126–129.
Gould, E., & Klor, E. (2010). Does terrorism work? Forthcoming in the Quarterly Journal of Economics.
GTD. (2009). Global terrorism dataset. Dataset.
Horne, A. (2006). A savage war of peace: Algeria 1954–1962. New York: New York Review of Books.
Iannaccone, L. R., & Berman, E. (2006). Religious extremism: the good, the bad, and the deadly. Public Choice, 128, 109–129.
Intelligence and Security Committee. (2009). Could 7/7 have been prevented? Review of the intelligence on the London terrorist attacks on 7 July 2005. UK civil service report.
Jaeger, D., & Paserman, D. (2008). The cycle of violence? An empirical analysis of fatalities in the Palestinian-Israeli conflict. American Economic Review, 98, 1591–1604.
Karol, D., & Miguel, E. (2007). The electoral cost of war: Iraq casualties and the 2004 U.S. presidential election. Journal of Politics, 69, 633–648.
Kreps, D., & Wilson, R. (1982). Reputation and imperfect information. Journal of Economic Theory, 27, 253–279.
Krieger, T., & Meierrieks, D. (2010). What causes terrorism? Public Choice (forthcoming)
Krueger, A. B., & Maleckova, J. (2003). Education, poverty and terrorism: is there a causal connection? Journal of Economic Perspectives, 17, 119–144.
Kurrild-Klitgaard, P., Justesen, M., & Klemmensen, R. (2006). The political economy of freedom, democracy and transnational terrorism. Public Choice, 128, 289–315.
Mickolous, E. F., Sandler, T., & Murdock, J. M. (2007). International terrorism: attributes of terrorist events, 1968–2006 (ITERATE). Vinyard Software. Dunn Loring.
Montalvo, J. (2010). Voting after the bombing: a natural experiment on the effect of terrorist attacks on democratic elections. Review of Economics and Statistics (forthcoming).
Pape, R. (2003). The strategic logic of suicide terrorism. American Political Science Review, 97, 343–361.
Rohner, D., & Frey, B. S. (2007). Blood and ink! The common-interest-game between terrorists and the media. Public Choice, 133, 129–145.
Shughart, W. F. II. (2006). An analytical history of terrorism, 1945–2000. Public Choice, 128, 7–39.
Siqueira, K., & Sandler, T. (2007). Terrorist backlash, terrorism mitigation, and policy delegation. Journal of Public Economics, 91, 1800–1815.
Time Magazine. (2004). Defenseless targets. Time Magazine, 164, No. 10.
Zussman, A., & Zussman, N. (2006). Assassinations: evaluating the effectiveness of an Israeli counterterrorism policy using stock market data. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 20, 193–206.
Author information
Authors and Affiliations
Corresponding author
Rights and permissions
About this article
Cite this article
Hodler, R., Rohner, D. Electoral terms and terrorism. Public Choice 150, 181–193 (2012). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-010-9697-3
Received:
Accepted:
Published:
Issue Date:
DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-010-9697-3