Skip to main content
Log in

Proportional versus winner-take-all electoral vote allocations

  • Published:
Public Choice Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This paper considers how the welfare of voters is affected under an Electoral College system when some state elects to award electoral votes in proportion to the number of votes received by each candidate rather than awarding all electoral votes to the winner of the state. I show that a majority of voters in that state is made worse off as a result of the change. I also give conditions under which voters in other states are made better or worse off as a result of the change.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

References

  • Amy, D. J. (1993). Real choice/new voices: the case for proportional representation elections in the United States. New York: Columbia University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Austen-Smith, D., & Banks, J. S. (1996). Information aggregation, rationality, and the Condorcet jury theorem. American Political Science Review, 90, 34–45.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Banzhaf, J. F. III (1965). Weighted voting doesn’t work: a mathematical analysis. Rutgers Law Review, 19, 317–343.

    Google Scholar 

  • Banzhaf, J. F. III (1968). One man, 3.312 votes: a mathematical analysis of the Electoral College. Villanova Law Review, 13, 304–332.

    Google Scholar 

  • Barber, K. L. (2000). A right to representation: proportional election systems for the twenty-first century. Columbus: Ohio State University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Brams, S. J., & Affuso, P. J. (1976). Power and size: a new paradox. Theory and Decision, 7, 29–56.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brams, S. J., & Davis, M. D. (1974). The 3/2’s rule in presidential campaigning. American Political Science Review, 68, 113–134.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brams, S. J., & Davis, M. D. (1975). Comment on “Campaign resource allocations under the Electoral College”. American Political Science Review, 69, 155–156.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Colantoni, C. S., Levesque, T. J., & Ordeshook, P. C. (1975a). Campaign resource allocations under the Electoral College. American Political Science Review, 69, 141–154.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Colantoni, C. S., Levesque, T. J., & Ordeshook, P. C. (1975b). Rejoinder to “Comment” by S. J. Brams and M. D. Davis. American Political Science Review, 69, 157–161.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Feddersen, T., & Pesendorfer, W. (1996). The swing voter’s curse. American Economic Review, 86, 408–424.

    Google Scholar 

  • Feddersen, T., & Pesendorfer, W. (1997). Voting behavior and information aggregation in elections with private information. Econometrica, 65, 1029–1058.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fey, M. (1997). Stability and coordination in Duverger’s law: a formal model of preelection polls and strategic voting. American Political Science Review, 91, 135–147.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gelman, A., Katz, J. N., & Bafumi, J. (2004). Standard voting power indexes do not work: an empirical analysis. British Journal of Political Science, 34, 657–674.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gelman, A., Katz, J. N., & Tuerlinckx, F. (2002). The mathematics and statistics of voting power. Statistical Science, 17, 420–435.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hill, S. (2002). Fixing elections: the failure of America’s winner take all politics. New York: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hummel, P. (2010). Proportional versus winner-take-all electoral vote allocations. Stanford University Working Paper.

  • Myatt, D. P. (2007). On the theory of strategic voting. Review of Economic Studies, 74, 255–281.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Owen, G. (1975). Evaluation of a presidential election game. American Political Science Review, 69, 947–953.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Palfrey, T. (1989). A mathematical proof of Duverger’s law. In P. C. Ordeshook (Ed.), Models of strategic choice in politics (pp. 69–91). Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Piketty, T. (2000). Voting as communicating. Review of Economic Studies, 67, 169–191.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rabinowitz, G., & MacDonald, S. E. (1986). The power of the states in U.S. presidential elections. American Political Science Review, 80, 65–87.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Razin, R. (2003). Signaling and election motivations in a voting model with common values and responsive candidates. Econometrica, 71, 1083–1119.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shapley, L. S., & Shubik, M. (1954). A method for evaluating the distribution of power in a committee system. American Political Science Review, 48, 787–792.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shotts, K. W. (2006). A signaling model of repeated elections. Social Choice and Welfare, 27, 251–261.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Strömberg, D. (2008). How the Electoral College influences campaigns and policy: the probability of being Florida. American Economic Review, 98, 769–807.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Patrick Hummel.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Hummel, P. Proportional versus winner-take-all electoral vote allocations. Public Choice 148, 381–393 (2011). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-010-9660-3

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-010-9660-3

Keywords

Navigation