Skip to main content
Log in

Securing the base: electoral competition under variable turnout

  • Published:
Public Choice Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

I evaluate the ‘Securing the Base’ strategy, which prescribes that candidates position themselves away from the political center in order to maximize turnout among their supporters and reduce defections of their supporters to third party candidates. My results support the notion that voters abstain due to indifference and imply that candidate positioning has a large effect on voter turnout and third party voting. Nonetheless, my results indicate that the candidates can best compete by adopting centrist positions. While a candidate can increase turnout among his supporters by moving away from the center, many moderate voters will defect to his opponent.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

References

  • Adams, J. (2000). Multicandidate equilibrium in American elections. Public Choice, 103, 297–325.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Adams, J., & Merrill, S. (2003). Voter turnout and candidate strategies in American elections. Journal of Politics, 65, 161–189.

    Google Scholar 

  • Adams, J., Merrill, S., & Grofman, B. (2005). A unified theory of party competition. New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Adams, J., Dow, J., & Merrill, S. (2006). The political consequences of abstention due to alienation and indifference: applications to presidential elections. Political Behavior, 28, 65–86.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Alvarez, M., & Nagler, J. (1995). Economics, issues, and the Perot candidacy: voter choice in the 1992 presidential election. American Political Science Review, 3, 714–744.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ansolabehere, S., Snyder, J., & Stewart, C. (2001). Candidate positioning in U.S. House elections. American Journal of Political Science, 45, 136–149.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Banks, J., & Duggan, J. (2005). Probabilistic voting in the spatial model of elections: the theory of office motivated candidates. In D. Austen-Smith, & J. Duggan (Eds.), Social choice and strategic decisions: essays in honor of Jeffery S. Banks. New York: Springer.

    Google Scholar 

  • Black, D. (1958). The theory of committees and elections. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Brody, R., & Page, B. (1973). Indifference, alienation, and rational decisions: the effects of candidate evaluation on turnout and the vote. Public Choice, 15, 1–17.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brownstein, R. (2004). Bush aims to solidify his base. Los Angeles Times. August 22.

  • Burden, B. (2004). Candidate positioning in U.S. congressional elections. British Journal of Political Science, 34, 211–227.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Callander, S., & Wilson, C. (2006). Context-dependent voting. Quarterly Journal of Political Science, 1, 227–254.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Converse, P. (1966). The concept of the normal vote. In Campbell, et al. Elections and the political order.

  • Coughlin, P., & Nitzan, S. (1981). Electoral outcomes with probabilistic voting and Nash social welfare optima. Journal of Public Economics, 15, 113–122.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Downs, A. (1957). An economic theory of democracy. New York: Harper and Row.

    Google Scholar 

  • Erikson, R., & Romero, D. (1990). Candidate equilibrium and the behavioral model of the vote. American Political Science Review, 84, 1103–1126.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Geweke, J., Keane, M., & Runkle, D. (1994). Alternative computational approaches to inference in the multinomial probit model. Review of Economics and Statistics, 76, 609–632.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Glaeser, E., Ponzetto, G., & Shapiro, J. (2005). Strategic extremism: why Republicans and Democrats divide on religious values. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 4, 1283–1330.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hinich, M. (1977). Equilibrium in spatial voting: the median voter result is an artifact. Journal of Economic Theory, 16, 208–219.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hinich, M., & Ordeshook, P. (1969). Abstention in equilibrium and the electoral process. Public Choice, 7, 71–106.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lacy, D., & Burden, B. (1999). The vote-stealing and turnout effects of Ross Perot in the 1992 presidential election. American Journal of Political Science, 43, 233–255.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lacy, D., & Burden, B. (2001). The vote-stealing and turnout effects of third party candidates in U.S. presidential elections. Working paper.

  • McKelvey, R., & Patty, J. (2006). A theory of voting in large elections. Games and Economic Behavior, 57, 155–180.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Milbank, D., & Allen, M. (2004). Bush fortifies conservative base: campaign seeks solid support before wooing swing voters. Washington Post, July 15.

  • Miniter, B. (2005). The McCain myth: the moderation the makes him a Senate powerhouse will keep him out of the White House. The Wall Street Journal, May 31, 2005.

  • Nagourney, A. (2003). Political parties shift emphasis to core voters. New York Times, August 30.

  • Peress, Michael (2010). The spatial model with non-policy factors: a theory of policy-motivated candidates. Social Choice and Welfare, 34, 265–294.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Plane, D., & Gershtenson, J. (2004). Candidates ideological locations, abstention, and turnout in U.S. midterm Senate elections. Political Behavior, 26, 69–93.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Quinn, K., Martin, A., & Whitford, A. (1999). Voter choice in multi-party democracies: a test of competing theories and models. American Journal of Political Science, 43, 1231–1247.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rosenstone, S., Behr, R., & Lazarus, E. (1984). Third parties in America: citizen response to major party failure. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schofield, N. (2003). Valence competition in the spatial stochastic model. Journal of Theoretical Politics, 15, 371–383.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schofield, N. (2004). Equilibrium in the spatial ‘valence’ model of politics. Journal of Theoretical Politics, 16, 447–481.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schofield, N., & Sened, I. (2006). Multiparty democracy: elections and legislative politics. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Schofield, N., Martin, A., Quinn, K., & Whitford, A. (1998). Multiparty electoral competition in the Netherlands and Germany: a model based on multinomial probit. Public Choice, 97, 257–293.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Spretnak, C. (2000). How Gore lost the Green vote. San Francisco Chronicle, November 19.

  • Stokes D. (1963). Spatial models of party competition. American Political Science Review, 57, 368–377.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Thurner, P., & Eymann, A. (2000). Policy-specific alienation and indifference in the calculus of voting: a simultaneous model of party choice and abstention. Public Choice, 102, 51–77.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wright, G., & Berkman, M. (1986). Candidates and policy in United States Senate elections. American Political Science Review, 80, 567–588.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zipp, J. (1985). Perceived representativeness and voting: an assessment of the impact of choice vs. echoes. American Political Science Review, 79, 50–61.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Michael Peress.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Peress, M. Securing the base: electoral competition under variable turnout. Public Choice 148, 87–104 (2011). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-010-9647-0

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-010-9647-0

Keywords

Navigation