Public Choice

, Volume 147, Issue 1–2, pp 209–225

Determinants of congressional minimum wage support: the role of economic education

Article

Abstract

Much has been made about the lack of economic education among the public at large, yet little has been said about the limited education of Members of Congress. This paper examines the economic education levels of Members of Congress voting on the 2007 increase in the minimum wage. Controlling for a variety of characteristics of members and constituents, this study finds that members who majored in economics as undergraduates were less likely to vote for the minimum wage increase than their colleagues. No other major had a consistent influence. A large number of statistical specifications confirm the robustness of the finding.

Keywords

Economic education Congressional voting behavior Minimum wage 

JEL Classification

A20 D72 J38 

Preview

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

References

  1. Anderson, S., & Habel, P. (2009). Revisiting adjusted ADA scores for the U.S. Congress, 1947–2007. Political Analysis, 17(1), 83–88. CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  2. Baldwin, R. E., & Magee, C. S (1998). Is trade policy for sale, Congressional voting on recent trade bills. National Bureau of Economic Research, NBER Working Papers: 6376. Google Scholar
  3. Bishin, B. G. (2003). Independently validating ideology measures: a look at NOMINATE and adjusted ADA scores. American Politics Research, 31(4), 404. CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  4. Blendon, R. J. et al. (1997). Bridging the gap between the public’s and economists’ views of the economy. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 11(3), 105–118. Google Scholar
  5. Brunell, T. L., Koeztle, W. Dinardo, J., Grofman, B., & Feld, S. L. (1999). The R2=.93: where then do they differ? Comparing liberal and conservative interest group ratings. Legislative Studies Quarterly, 24(1), 87–101. CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  6. Carroll, R. et al (2009). DW-NOMINATE scores with bootstrapped standard errors. http://voteview.com/dwnomin.htm. Accessed 13 May 2009.
  7. Caplan, B. (2002). Systematically biased beliefs about economics: robust evidence of judgmental anomalies from the survey of Americans and economists on the economy. The Economic Journal, 112(479), 433–458. CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  8. Caplan, B. (2007). The myth of the rational voter: why democracies choose bad policies. Princeton: Princeton University Press. Google Scholar
  9. Clement, D. (2006). Interview with David Card. The Region: Banking and Policy Issues Magazine, Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis, 10–21. Google Scholar
  10. Coates, D., & Munger, M. C. (1995). Legislative voting and the economic theory of politics. Southern Economic Journal, 61(3), 861–872. CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  11. Congressional Staff Directory. http://csd.cqpress.com/scripts/searchMembers.cfm. Accessed 21 November 2008.
  12. Converse, P. E. (1964). The nature of belief systems in mass publics. In Apter, D. E. (Ed.) Ideology and discontent. New York: Free Press. Google Scholar
  13. Davis, O. A., & Hinich, M. J. (1966). A mathematical model of policy formation in a democratic society. In J.f, Bernd (Ed.) Mathematical applications in political science, vol. II. Dallas: SMU Press. Google Scholar
  14. Dennis, C., Bishin, B., & Nicolaou, P. (2000). Constituent diversity and Congress: the case of NAFTA. Journal of Socio-Economics, 29(4), 349–360. CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  15. Dougan, W. R., & Munger, M. C. (1989). The rationality of ideology. Journal of Law and Economics, 32(1), 119–142. CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  16. Downs, A. (1957). An economic theory of democracy. New York: Harper and Row. Google Scholar
  17. Ellenberg, J. (2001). Growing apart: the mathematical evidence for Congress’ growing polarization. Slate online: http://www.slate.com/id/2060047/. Accessed 13 May 2009.
  18. Enelow, J. M., & Hinich, M. J. (1984). The spatial theory of voting. New York: Cambridge University Press. Google Scholar
  19. Fowler, L. L. (1982). How interest groups select issues for rating voting records of members of the U.S. Congress. Legislative Studies Quarterly, 7(3), 401–413. CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  20. Fuller, D., & Geide-Stevenson, D. (2003). Consensus among economists: revisited. Journal of Economic Education, 34(4), 369–387. CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  21. Fuller, D., & Geide-Stevenson, D. (2007). Consensus on economic issues: a survey of Republicans, Democrats and economists. Eastern Economic Journal, 33(1), 81–94. CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  22. Gai, Z. (2005). Permanent normal trade relations with China: how members of the U.S. House voted. International Review of Economics and Business, 52(2), 269–288. Google Scholar
  23. Gleason, J., & Van Scyoc, L. J. (1995). A report on the economic literacy of adults. Journal of Economic Education, 26(3), 203–210. CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  24. Groseclose, T., Levitt, S. D., & Snyder, J.M. Jr. (1999). Comparing interest group scores across time and chambers: adjusted ADA scores for the U.S. Congress. American Political Science Review, 93(1), 33–50. CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  25. Hasnat, B. Callahan, III, C. (2004). The determinants of U.S. congressional voting on the Trade and Development Act of 2000. International Journal of Business and Economics, 3(1), 35–44. Google Scholar
  26. Hinich, M. J., & Pollard, W. (1981). A new approach to spatial theory of electoral competition. American Journal of Political Science, 25(2), 323–341. CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  27. Jackson, J. E., & Kingdon, J. W. (1992). Ideology, interest group scores and legislative votes. American Journal of Political Science, 63(3), 805–823. CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  28. Kahn, H. A. (2005). Determinants of congressional support for NAFTA and Clinton’s economic package. The Journal of Developing Areas, 38(2), 143–154. CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  29. Klein, D. B., & Stern, C. (2007). Is there a free market economist in the house? The policy views of American Economic Association Members. American Journal of Economics and Sociology, 66(2), 309–334. CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  30. Krueger, A. B. (2001). Teaching the minimum wage in econ 101 in light of the new economics of the minimum wage. Journal of Economic Education, 32(3), 243–258. Google Scholar
  31. Lopez, E. J., & Sutter, D. (2004). Ignorance in congressional voting? Evidence from policy reversal on the Endangered Species Act. Social Science Quarterly, 85(4), 891–912. CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  32. Lopez, E. J., & Ramirez, C. D. (2008). Mr. Smith and the economy: The influence of economic conditions on individual legislator voting. Public Choice, 136(1–2), 1–17. CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  33. Lott, J. R. Jr., & Kenny, L. W. (1999). Did women’s suffrage change the size and scope of government? Journal of Political Economy, 107(6), 1163–1198. CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  34. Lowry, W. R., & Shipan, C. R. (2002). Party differentiation in Congress. Legislative Studies Quarterly, 27(1), 33–60. Google Scholar
  35. McCarty, N. M., Poole, K. T., & Rosenthal, H. (2006). Polarized America: the dance of ideology and unequal riches. Cambridge: MIT Press. Google Scholar
  36. Mohai, P., & Kershner, D. (2002). Race and environmental voting in the U.S. Congress. Social Science Quarterly, 83(1), 167–189. CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  37. Neumark, D., & Nizalova, O. (2004). Minimum wage effects in the longer run. National Bureau of Economic Research, NBER Working Papers: 10656. Google Scholar
  38. Neumark, D., & Wascher, W. (1995). The effects of minimum wages on teenage employment and enrollment: evidence from matched CPS surveys. National Bureau of Economic Research, NBER Working Papers: 5092. Google Scholar
  39. Ordeshook, P. C. (1976). The spatial theory of elections: a review and critique. In Budge, I., Crewe, I., & Farlie, D. (Eds.) Party identification and beyond. New York: Wiley. Google Scholar
  40. Pjesky, R., & Sutter, D. (2002). Searching for Cincinnatus: Representatives’ backgrounds and voting behavior. Atlantic Economic Journal, 30(1), 74–86. CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  41. Poole, K. T. (2007). Changing minds? Not in Congress. Public Choice, 131(3–4), 435–451. CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  42. Poole, K. T., & Rosenthal, H. (1997). Congress: a political-economic history of roll call voting. New York: Oxford University Press. Google Scholar
  43. Reeher, G. (1996). Narratives of justice: Legislators’ beliefs about distributional fairness. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press. Google Scholar
  44. Rocca, M. S., Sanchez, G. R., & Uscinski, J. (2008). Personal attributes and Latino voting behavior in Congress. Social Science Quarterly, 89(2), 392–405. CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  45. Sobel, R. (1999). Theory and evidence on the political economy of the minimum wage. Journal of Political Economy, 107(4), 761–785. CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  46. Sobel, R., & Wagner, G. A. (1998). On the determinants of congressional bill sponsorship and voting behavior. Journal of Public Finance and Public Choice, 17(2–3), 87–115. Google Scholar
  47. Snyder, J. (1992). Artificial extremism in interest group ratings. Legislative Studies Quarterly, 25(3), 319–345. CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  48. Walstad, W. B., & Rebeck, K. (2002). Assessing the economic knowledge and economic opinions of adults. The Quarterly Review of Economics and Finance, 42(5), 921–935. CrossRefGoogle Scholar

Copyright information

© Springer Science+Business Media, LLC 2010

Authors and Affiliations

  1. 1.Department of Economics and Legal StudiesRobert Morris UniversityMoon TownshipUSA
  2. 2.Department of EconomicsJames Madison UniversityHarrisonburgUSA

Personalised recommendations