Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

The political-economy of conflicts over wealth: why don’t the rabble expropriate the rich?

  • Published:
Public Choice Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

The most striking feature of liberal democracies is the coexistence of large inequalities of wealth with a roughly egalitarian distribution of voting power. So far most attempts to explain this have asked ‘why don’t the poor form a coalition to expropriate the rich?’ This paper argues that this is not necessarily the best way to interpret the problem and attempts to provide an alternative unified political-economic model that is more consistent with standard assumptions about voting. This is done by studying what would happen if every possible coalition could form in a wealth distribution game. Among the main findings is that, if the marginal contribution of every individual to production is increasing sufficiently, there is a stable distribution of the product. This may include the egalitarian distribution. If individuals are not so valuable there is no stable distribution.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

References

  • Aumann, R., & Kurz, M. (1977). Power and taxes. Econometrica, 45, 1137–1161.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Aumann, R., & Kurz, M. (1978). Power and taxes in a multi-commodity economy. Journal of Public Economics, 9, 139–161.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dalton, R. J. (2000). The decline of part identifications. In R. J. Dalton & M. P. Wattenberg (Eds.), Parties without partisans (pp. 9–36). Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Downs, A. (1957). An economic theory of democracy. New York: Harper and Row.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gramsci, A. (1971). Prison notebooks. New York: International Publishers.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gunn, J. (1988). Jeremy Bentham and the public interest. In J. Lively (Ed.), Modern political theory from Hobbes to Marx Key debates. London: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hamilton, A., Madison, J., & Jay, J. (1961). The federalist papers. New York: New American Library.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hausken, K. (2005). Production and conflict models versus rent seeking models. Public Choice, 123, 59–93.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hayek, F. (1973). Economic freedom and representative government. London: London Institute for Policy Studies.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hirshleifer, J. (1995). Anarchy and its breakdown. Journal of Political Economy, 103(1), 27–52.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ichiishi, T. (1983). Game theory for economic analysis. New York: Academic Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Miliband, R. (1969). The state in capitalist society. New York: Basic Books.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mueller, D. (2003). Public choice III. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Peck, R. (1986). Power and linear income taxes: an example. Econometrica, 54, 87–94.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Peleg, B., & Sudholter, P. (2003). Introduction to the theory of cooperative games. Netherlands: Kluwer.

    Google Scholar 

  • Przeworski, A. (1990). The state and the economy under capitalism. Chur: Harwood Academic Publishers.

    Google Scholar 

  • Przeworski, A. (2005). Democracy as an equilibrium. Public Choice, 123, 253–273.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Putterman, L. (1996). Why have the rabble not redistributed wealth? In J. Roemer (Ed.), Property relations, incentives and welfare (pp. 359–389). New York: St. Martin’s Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ray, D., & Vohra, R. (1999). A theory of endogenous coalition formation. Games and Economic Behaviour, 26, 286–336.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Roemer, J. (1985). Rationalizing revolutionary ideology. Econometrica, 53, 85–108.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Roemer, J. (1999). The democratic political economy of progressive income taxation. Econometrica, 67, 1–19.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Roine, J. (2006). The political economy of not paying taxes. Public Choice, 126, 107–134.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schumpeter (1975). Capitalism socialsim and democracy. New York: Harper.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tullock, G. (1967). The welfare costs of tariffs, monopolies and theft. Western Economic Journal, 5, 224–232.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tullock, G. (1971). The charity of the uncharitable. Western Economic Journal, 9, 379–392.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wallerstein, M. (1996). Comment. In J. Roemer (Ed.), Property relations, incentives and welfare (pp. 390–393). New York: St. Martin’s Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ward, B. (1961). Majority rule and allocation. The Journal of Conflict Resolution, 5, 379–89.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Alex Coram.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Coram, A. The political-economy of conflicts over wealth: why don’t the rabble expropriate the rich?. Public Choice 136, 315–330 (2008). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-008-9298-6

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-008-9298-6

Keywords

Navigation