Skip to main content
Log in

Campaign finance reform and electoral competition

  • Original Article
  • Published:
Public Choice Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Using state senate data from 1984 through the beginning of 2002, this paper finds that campaign donation regulations clearly reduce the competitiveness in political races. This is reflected in several dimensions. Conservative estimates indicate that different donation limits are associated with anywhere from a 4 to over a 23 percentage point increase in win margins. The regulations increase the probability that only one candidate will run for office. And they increase the probability that incumbents win re-election. Campaign finance regulations also tend to reduce the number of candidates who run for office by an average of about 20 percent.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

References

  • Bauer, R.F. (2002). Soft Money Hard Law: A Guide to the New Campaign Finance, Perkins Coie LLP: Washington, D.C.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bronars, S.G., & John R. Lott, Jr. (1997). Do campaign donations alter how a politician votes? Coauthored with Steve Bronars. Journal of Law and Economics, 40(2), 317–350.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bruce, B. (1988). An analysis of congressional voting on legislation limiting congressional campaign expenditures. Journal of Political Economy, 96(5), 1005–1021.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bruce, B. (1991). The influence of ideology on congressional voting. Economic Inquiry, 29(3), 416–428.

    Google Scholar 

  • Coate, S. (2001). Political competition with campaign contributions and informative advertising. NBER Working Paper.

  • Coate, S., & Morris, S. (1995). On the form of transfers to special interests. Journal of Political Economy, 103, 1210–1235.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Crain, W.M., & Tollison, R. (1995). Campaign expenditures and political competition. Journal of Law and Economics, 19, 177–188.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Crain, W.M., & Tollison, R. (1977). Attenuated property rights and the market for governors. Journal of Law and Economics, 20, 205–212.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Crain, W.M., Donald R., Leavens, & Tollison, R. (1986). Final Voting in Legislatures American Economic Review, 76, 833–841.

    Google Scholar 

  • Crain, W.M., & Oakley, L.K. (1995). The politics of infrastructure. Journal of Law and Economics, 38, 1–18.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Daniel, K., & John, R.L. Jr. (1997). Term limits and electoral competitiveness: Evidence from California's state legislative races. Public Choice, 90, 165–184.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dick, A.R., & John R.L. Jr. (1993). Reconciling voters' behavior with legislative term limits. Journal of Public Economics, 50(1), 1–14.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grier, K. (1989). Campaign spending and senate elections, 1978–1984. Public Choice, 63, 201–220.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hersch, P.L., & McDougall, G.S. (1994). Campaign war chests as a barrier to entry in congressional races. Economic Inquiry, 630–641.

  • Hoggan, R.E. (2000). The costs of representation in state legislatures: Explaining variations in campaign spending. Social Science Quarterly, 941–956.

  • Jacobson, G. (1975). The impact of broadcast campaigning on electoral outcomes. Journal of Politics, 769–793.

  • Jacobson, G. (1978). The effects of campaign spending in congressional elections. American Political Science Review, 469–491.

  • Jacobson, G. (1980). Money in Congressional Elections, New Haven, CT.: Yale University Press.

  • Kau, J.B., Keenan, D., & Rubin, P.H. (1982). A general equilibrium model of congressional voting. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 97, 271–293.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kenny, L., & Francis, W.L. (2000). Up the Political Ladder: Career Paths in U.S. Politics, Sage: Thousand Oaks CA.

    Google Scholar 

  • Knack, S. (1995). Does ‘Motor Voter' work?: Evidence from the state-Level data. Journal of Politics, 796–811.

  • Knack, S. (1999). Drivers wanted: Motor voter and the election of 1996. Political Science & Politics.

  • Lott, J.R., Jr. (1987a). The effect of nontransferable property rights on the efficiency of political markets, some evidence. Journal of Public Economics, 32, 231–246.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lott, J.R., Jr. (1989). Explaining challengers' campaign expenditures: The importance of sunk nontransferable brand name. Public Finance Quarterly, 17(1), 108–118.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lott, J.R., Jr. (1990). An explanation for public provision of schooling: The importance of indoctrination. Journal of Law and Economics, 33, 199–232.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lott, J.R., Jr., (2000). A simple explanation for why campaign donations are increasing: The government is getting bigger. Journal of Law and Economics, 42(2), 359–393.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Milyo, J. (1997). The economics of campaign finance: FECA and the puzzle of the not very greedy grandfathers. Public Choice, 93, 245–270.

    Google Scholar 

  • Milyo, J., & Groseclose, T. (1999). The electoral effects of incumbent wealth. Journal of Law and Economics, 699–722.

  • Ornstein, N.J., Mann, T.E., & Malbin, M.J. (2002). Vital Statistics on Congress: 2001–2002, The American Enterprise Press: Washington, D.C.

  • Peltzman, S. (1976). Towards a more general theory of regulation. Journal of Law and Economics, 19(2), 211–240.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Peltzman, S. (1980). The growth of government. Journal of Law and Economics, 23(2), 209–287.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Poole, K.T., & Romer, T. (1993). Ideology, ‘Shirking,’ and representation. Public Choice, 97, 185–196.

    Google Scholar 

  • Public, C. (2002). Clean money, clean elections comparisons. Public Campaign: Washington, DC.

    Google Scholar 

  • Reed, W.R., & Schansberg, E. (1992). The behavior of congressional tenure over time: 1953–1991. Public Choice, 73, 183–203.

    Google Scholar 

  • Reed, W.R., & Schansberg, D.E. (1994). An analysis of congressional term limits. Economic Inquiry, 32, 79–91.

    Google Scholar 

  • Reed, W.R., & Schansberg, D.E. (1995). The house under term limits: What would it look like? Social Science Quarterly, 76, 699–716.

    Google Scholar 

  • Snyder, James M., Jr. (1990). Campaign contributions as investments: The U.S. House of Representatives, 1980–1986. Journal of Political Economy, 98(6), 1195–1227.

    Google Scholar 

  • Snyder, James M., Jr. (1992). Long-term investing in politicians; or, give early, give often. Journal of Law and Economics, 35, 15–44.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stratmann, T. (1991). What do campaign contributions buy?: Deciphering causal effects of money and votes. Southern Economic Journal, 57, 606–620.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stratmann, T. (1992). Are contributors rational?: Untangling strategies of political action committees. Journal of Political Economy, 100, 647–664.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stratmann, T., & Aparaicio-Castillo, F.J. (2002). Competition policy for elections: Do campaign contribution limits matter. George Mason University Working Paper.

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to John R. Lott Jr..

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Lott, J.R. Campaign finance reform and electoral competition. Public Choice 129, 263–300 (2006). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-006-9028-x

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-006-9028-x

Keywords

Navigation