Skip to main content
Log in

Cite this article

Abstract

I develop an intra-firm theory of group design and teamwork in the presence of peer effects. The purpose is to understand the interlinkages between intra-firm group formation and the extent of wage dispersion within the firm. Given a set of heterogeneous workers, the manager faces the challenge of allocating workers into endogenous groups (or teams) to maximize total profits. The optimal allocation features locational proximity between workers with similar productivity levels. I discuss the implications of this allocation on intra-firm wage outcomes. The main idea is that the wage paid to a single worker is determined by the productivity levels of the teammates as well as the worker’s own productivity. This means that team composition is critical to understanding the within-firm productivity and wage differentials. I show that intra-firm wage dispersion is more pronounced when workers are more alike within each team and more different across the teams. I provide numerical exercises designed to illustrate how the model’s predictions change as the key parameters are varied. One striking result is that a rise in the correlation between education and productivity (this can be interpreted as hiring workers with vocational education) leads to a decline in wage inequality within the firm. I also show that changes in the dispersion of worker efficiency lead to non-monotonic effects on within-firm wage inequality.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Institutional subscriptions

Fig. 1
Fig. 2

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. For expositional purposes, the worker is a “she” and the manager is a “he” throughout the paper.

  2. The concept of positive spillover externalities in the workplace is not new and goes back to Marshall (1890). Lazear and Shaw (2007) provide evidence that the incidence of teamwork has been steadily increasing over time.

  3. The luck component can be interpreted as an independent idiosyncratic shock that affects the worker’s output.

  4. Formally speaking, the terms “sorting” and “selectivity” can be best understood by comparing the population and within-team distributions of productivity. Specifically, the gap between within-team versus population-level average productivities describes the degree of sorting. Similarly, the gap between within-team versus population level variance of productivity describes the degree of selectivity. These two terms jointly define the structure of teamwork within the firm. See the relevant section for a much more detailed description of these two terms.

  5. Section 4 presents the details of this result as well as further results from additional comparative statics exercises.

  6. A contextual effect means that the social influence comes from the group-level characteristics. It is endogenous because the group formation is determined within the model. See Manski (1993, 2000) for a more precise definition of the related concepts.

  7. See Tinbergen (1956), Rosen (1974), and Ekeland et al. (2002, 2004).

  8. Similar ideas can be found in the urban economics literature under the topic of “agglomeration economies”. See, for example, Fujita (1989). This idea is also prevalent in residential sorting models [see Ioannides 2011 for a review].

  9. This is tangentially related to the “homophily principle.” In other words, the similarities between individuals make them more likely to form social groups within each other. See McPherson et al. (2001), Marmaros and Sacerdote (2006), and Currarini et al. (2009) for further reading.

  10. Heckman selection-correction procedure develops a framework to deal with non-randomly selected samples from the population and removes the associated biases [see Heckman 1979]. The theoretical model developed in this paper embeds a Heckman selection argument, because the problem of non-random sorting of more productive workers into more productive teams is a clear case of self-selection. Thus, the tools developed by Heckman can be used to analyze the patterns of sorting and selectivity within the firm.

  11. Lazear (1989), Drago and Garvey (1998), and Carpenter et al. (2010) argue that increased team-level pay differences might reduce cooperation within teams. But I abstract from such strategic complexities.

  12. See also Milgrom (1988) and Milgrom and Roberts (1990).

  13. Lallemand et al. (2009) provide an excellent review of the related literature. See also Gibbons and Waldman (1999).

  14. See, e.g., Camerer (2003), Fehr and Schmidt (2006), Bartling and von Siemens (2010), and Bose et al. (2010).

  15. The manager plays the role of a social planner aiming to optimally allocate workers across teams within the firm. Other than this role, there is not a formal managerial body or a CEO in the model that decides on operational issues within the firm.

  16. See Ross and Yinger (1999) for an extensive review of the related literature.

  17. This resembles the selectivity (or the control functions) idea due to Heckman (1979).

  18. This will be linked to higher and more unequally distributed wages in Section 3.

  19. Notice that the group-level variances are compressed when \(\delta\) goes up. But this compression does not produce a mean-preserving spread. The fact that it raises the differences in means across groups is due to the correlation imposed by the decision rule.

  20. The log-normality assumption is not critical for the qualitative nature of the results presented in this paper. However, the log-normality assumption is required to obtain analytically tractable formulas for equilibrium objects such as wages and group-level productivity levels. In particular, this assumption is extremely helpful to derive the formulas for sorting and selectivity, since the regression interpretation given in Eq. (3.12) critically relies on the normality assumption. The log-normal distribution is also used very often in economics, since various critical variables—such as income, earnings, firm size, firm productivity, human capital, and consumption—are empirically shown to be log-normally distributed. Log-normality fits to reality well in general, because it reflects the fact that “high-quality is rare.” This is also relevant within the context of the current paper. I conjecture that relaxing the log-normality assumption should not change any of the results as long as the alternative distribution comes from the exponential family—such as exponential, gamma, Pareto, Dirichlet, etc. The only requirement is that there should be a clearly right-skewed distribution with a long right-tail for the results to hold. Without log-normality, however, analytical tractability will be much harder to obtain.

  21. The idea is simple. As one moves away from the left tail, incremental improvements in x comes with increased densities of better quality worker groups. Once the mean point is past behind, the incremental improvements in x bring decreasingly smaller contributions to the group quality.

  22. For the sake of analytical tractability, I limit the dimension of the characteristics vector to be two (efficiency and education). In a more elaborate version (or in a version designed for the purpose of empirical applicability), the characteristics vector may be allowed to consist of three or more worker traits.

  23. It is also noteworthy that the effect of increasing \(\sigma _{ee}\) on wage inequality over the x horizon is irregular, i.e., a higher \(\sigma _{ee}\) raises inequality in the lower tail while it increases inequality in the upper tail in a certain interval, whereas in another interval this effect may be reversed.

  24. See Table 2 for the values of these fixed parameters.

References

  • Abowd JM, Kramarz F, Margolis D (1999) High wage workers and high wage firms. Econometrica 67:251–333

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Akerlof GA, Yellen JL (1990) The fair wage-effort hypothesis and unemployment. Q J Econ 105:255–283

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bandiera O, Barankay I, Rasul I (2005) Social preferences and the response to incentives: evidence from personnel data. Q J Econ 120:917–962

    Google Scholar 

  • Bandiera O, Barankay I, Rasul I (2010) Social incentives in the workplace. Rev Econ Stud 77:417–458

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bandiera O, Barankay I, Rasul I (2011) Team incentives: evidence from a team-level experiment, Unpublished manuscript, London School of Economics

  • Bartling B, von Siemens FA (2010) Equal sharing rules in partnerships. J Inst Theor Econ 166:299–320

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Belfield R, Marsden D (2003) Performance pay. Monitoring environments, and establishment performance. Int J Manpow 24:452–471

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bose A, Pal D, Sappington DEM (2010) Equal pay for unequal work: limiting sabotage in teams. J Econ Manag Strategy 19:25–53

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Camerer C (2003) Behavioral game theory. Princeton University Press, Princeton

    Google Scholar 

  • Card D, Heining J, Kline P (2013) Workplace heterogeneity and the rise of west German wage inequality. Q J Econ 128:967–1015

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Card D, Mas A, Moretti E, Saez E (2012) Inequality at work: the effect of peer salaries on job satisfaction. Am Econ Rev 102:2981–3003

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Carpenter J, Matthews P, Schrim J (2010) Tournaments and office politics: evidence from a real-effort experiment. Am Econ Rev 100:504–517

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cohn A, Fehr E, Herrmann B, Schneider F (2011) Social comparison in the workplace: evidence from a field experiment, Unpublished manuscript, University of Zurich

  • Currarini S, Jackson MO, Pin P (2009) An economic model of friendship: homophily. Minor Segreg Econom 77:1003–1045

    Google Scholar 

  • Dearden L, Reed H, Van Reenen J (2006) The impact of training on productivity and wages: evidence from British panel data. Oxford Bull Econ Stat 68:397–421

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Drago R, Garvey GT (1998) Incentives for helping on the job: theory and evidence. J Labor Econ 16:1–25

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Eeckhout J, Kircher P (2011) Identifying sorting—in theory. Rev Econ Stud 78:872–906

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ekeland I, Heckman JJ, Nesheim L (2002) Identifying hedonic models. Am Econ Rev Pap Proc 92:304–309

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ekeland I, Heckman JJ, Nesheim L (2004) Identification and estimation of hedonic models. J Political Econ 112:S60–S109

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Encinosa WE, Gaynor M, Rebitzer JB (2007) The sociology of groups and the economics of incentives: theory and evidence on compensation systems. J Econ Behav Organ 62:187–214

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Farrell J, Scotchmer S (1988) Partnerships. Q J Econ 103:279–298

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fehr E, Schmidt KM (2006) The economics of fairness, reciprocity and altruism: experimental evidence and new theories. In: Kolm SC, Ythier JM (eds) Handbook of the economics of giving, altruism, and reciprocity, vol 1. Elsevier, Amsterdam, pp 615–691

    Google Scholar 

  • Fujita M (1989) Urban economic theory: land use and city size. Cambridge University Press, New York

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Gibbons R, Waldman M (1999) A theory of wage and promotion dynamics inside firms. Q J Econ 114:1321–1358

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Goux D, Maurin E (1999) Persistence of interindustry wage differentials: a reexamination using matched worker-firm panel data. J Labor Econ 17:492–533

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gruetter M, Lalive R (2009) The importance of firms in wage determination. Labour Econ 16:149–150

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hamilton BH, Nickerson JA, Owan H (2003) Team incentives and worker heterogeneity: an empirical analysis of the impact of teams on productivity and participation. J Polit Econ 111:465–497

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Heckman JJ (1979) Sample selection bias as a specification error. Econometrica 47:153–161

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hibbs DA, Locking H (2000) Wage dispersion and productive efficiency: evidence for Sweden. J Labor Econ 18:755–782

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ichino A, Maggi G (2000) Work environment and individual background: explaining regional shirking differentials in a large Italian firm. Q J Econ 115:1057–1090

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ioannides YM (2008) Full solution of an endogenous sorting model with contextual and income effects, Unpublished manuscript, Tufts University

  • Ioannides YM (2011) Neighborhood effects and housing. In: Benhabib J, Bisin A, Jackson MO (eds) Handbook of social economics. Elsevier, New York, pp 1281–1340

    Google Scholar 

  • Kandel E, Lazear EP (1992) Peer pressure and partnerships. J Polit Econ 100:801–817

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lallemand T, Plasman R, Rycx F (2009) Wage structure and firm productivity in Belgium. In: Lazear EP, Shaw KL (eds) The structure of wages: an international comparison. University of Chicago Press, Chicago, pp 179–215

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Lazear EP (1989) Pay inequality and industrial politics. J Polit Econ 87:1261–1284

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lazear EP (1998) Personnel economics for managers. Wiley, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Lazear EP, Rosen S (1981) Rank-order tournaments as optimum labor contracts. J Polit Econ 89:841–864

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lazear EP, Shaw KL (2007) Personnel economics: the economist view of human resources. J Econ Perspect 21:91–114

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ledford GE, Lawler EE, Mohrman SA (1995) Reward innovations in fortune 1000 companies. Compens Benefits Review 27:76–80

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Levine DI (1991) Cohesiveness. Productivity, and wage dispersion. J Econ Behav Organ 15:237–255

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Manski CF (1993) Identification of endogenous social effects: the reflection problem. Rev Econ Stud 60:531–542

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Manski CF (2000) Economic analysis of social interactions. J Econ Perspect 14:115–136

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Marmaros D, Sacerdote B (2006) How do friendships form? Q J Econ 121:79–119

    Google Scholar 

  • Marshall A (1890) Principles of economics. Macmillan, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Mas A, Moretti E (2009) Peers at work. Am Econ Rev 99:112–145

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McLaughlin K (1988) Aspects of tournaments models: a survey. J Labor Econ 15:403–430

    Google Scholar 

  • McPherson M, Smith-Lovin L, Cook JM (2001) Birds of a feather: homophily in social networks. Ann Rev Sociol 27:415–444

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Milgrom P (1988) Employment contracts, influence activities, and efficient organisation design. J Polit Econ 96:42–60

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Milgrom P, Roberts PJ (1990) Rationalizability, learning, and equilibrium in games with strategic complementarities. Econometrica 58:1255–1277

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nesheim L (2001) Equilibrium sorting of heterogeneous consumers across locations: theory and empirical implications, Ph.D. thesis, University of Chicago

  • Prat A (2002) Should a team be homogeneous? Eur Econ Rev 46:1187–1207

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rosen S (1974) Hedonic prices and implicit markets: product differentiation in pure competition. J Polit Econ 82:34–55

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ross SL, Yinger J (1999) Sorting and voting: a review of the literature on urban public finance. In: Mills ES, Cheshire P (eds) Handbook of regional and urban economics. Elsevier, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Sala H, Silva JI (2012) Labor productivity and vocational training: evidence from Europe. J Product Anal 40:31–41

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tinbergen J (1956) On the theory of income distribution. Weltwirtschaftliches Arch 77:155–175

    Google Scholar 

  • Tumen S (2011) Essays on endogenous social effects, Ph.D. thesis, University of Chicago

  • Tumen S (2012) Fertility decisions and endogenous residential sorting. Reg Sci Urban Econ 42:78–87

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

I thank Iwan Barankay, Jesper Sorensen, Yossi Spiegel, Peter Thompson, seminar participants at the Central Bank of the Republic of Turkey, and the participants of the 2012 Turkish Economic Association conference in Izmir for useful comments. I am particularly grateful to William Greene (the editor), an Associate Editor, and an anonymous referee for extremely helpful suggestions. The views expressed here are of my own and do not necessarily reflect those of the Central Bank of the Republic of Turkey. All errors are mine.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Semih Tumen.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and Permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Tumen, S. A theory of intra-firm group design. J Prod Anal 45, 89–102 (2016). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11123-015-0452-0

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11123-015-0452-0

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation