Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Decompositions of productivity growth into sectoral effects

  • Published:
Journal of Productivity Analysis Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

The paper provides some new decompositions of labour productivity growth and total factor productivity (TFP) growth into sectoral effects. These new decompositions draw on the earlier work of Tang and Wang (Can J Econ 37:421–444, 2004). The economy wide labour productivity growth rate turns out to depend on the sectoral productivity growth rates, real output price changes and changes in sectoral labour input shares. The economy wide TFP growth decomposition into explanatory factors is similar but some extra terms due to real input price change make their appearance in the decomposition.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. The material in this section follows Diewert (2004).

  2. These industry real output aggregates Y tn and the corresponding prices P tn are indexes of the underlying micro net outputs produced by industry n. The exact functional form for these indexes does not matter for our analysis but we assume the indexes satisfy the property that for each t and n, P tn Y tn equals the industry n nominal value added for period t.

  3. The main problem is how exactly should the aggregate period t output level, Yt, be defined? In practice, a sequence of value added output levels Yt (and the corresponding value added output price indexes Pt) will be defined by aggregating individual industry outputs (and intermediate inputs entered with negative signs) into economy wide output levels, using bilateral Laspeyres, Paasche, Fisher (1922) or other indexes as building blocks. In the “Appendix”, we use chained Fisher output indexes over the market industry volume levels Y tn with the corresponding Australian Bureau of Statistics (ABS) official industry price indexes P tn used as price weights for the Y tn . Thus, for each year t, our Fisher index product PtYt will equal the ABS sum of industry price times volumes for year t, ∑ Nn=1 P tn Y tn , which in turn is equal to Market Sector nominal value added for year t. Thus, our Yt = ∑ Nn=1 P tn Y tn /Pt and so Eq. (3) can be rewritten as Xt = Yt/Lt. We note that the ABS uses chained Laspeyres volume indexes to aggregate value added over industries to form aggregate Market Sector real value added but the resulting differences in the Yt are very small.

  4. This follows the methodological approach taken by Tang and Wang (2004, 425). As noted in the previous footnote, the aggregate output price index Pt can be formed by applying an index number formula to the industry output prices (or value added deflators) for period t, (P t1 , …, P tN ), and the corresponding real output quantities (or industry real value added estimates) for period t, (Y t1 , …, Y tN ). The application of chained superlative indexes would be appropriate in this context but again, the exact form of index does not matter for our analysis as long as PtYt equals period t aggregate nominal value added.

  5. These definitions follow those of Tang and Wang (2004, 425).

  6. Equation (5) corresponds to Eq. (2) in Tang and Wang (2004, 426).

  7. Tang and Wang (2004, 425–426) combined the effects of the real price for industry n for period t, p tn , with the industry n labour share s tLn for period t by defining the relative size of industry n in period t, s tn , as the product of p tn and s tLn ; i.e., they defined the industry n weight in period t as s tn  ≡ p tn s tLn . They then rewrote Eq. (5), Xt = ∑ Nn=1 p tn s tLn X tn , as Xt = ∑ Nn=1 s tn X tn . Thus, their analysis of the effects of the changes in the weights s tn did not isolate the separate effects of changes in industry real output prices and industry labour input shares.

  8. See Tang and Wang (2004) and de Avillez (2012) for references to this literature.

  9. We use the fact that the industry period 0 value added output shares s 0Yn sum to one.

  10. This type of effect was first noticed by Denison (1962). It is called the reallocation level effect by de Avillez (2012).

  11. On the other hand, the industry productivity growth rates γn can vary independently.

  12. De Avillez (2012) called the first term in the last line of (15) the within effect, the second term the reallocation level effect and the third term the reallocation growth effect.

  13. This derivation of (16) is due to Balk (2008) who noticed the asymmetry in (9).

  14. A similar allocation has been applied to the Bennet (1920) decomposition of a value difference, say p 1n q 1n  − p 0n q 0n , into the two terms, (½) (p 1n  + p 0n ) Δqn and (½) (q 1n  + q 0n ) Δpn, where Δqn ≡ q 1n  − q 0n and Δpn ≡ p 1n  − p 0n . The quantity change term has the decomposition (½) (p 1n  + p 0n ) Δqn = p 0n Δqn + (½) Δpn Δqn while the price change term has the decomposition (½) (q 1n  + q 0n ) Δpn = q 0n Δpn + (½) Δpn Δqn. Note that the value change can also be written as the sum of the following 3 terms: p 0n Δqn + q 0n Δpn + Δpn Δqn. Thus, ½ of the second order interaction term ΔpnΔqn is assigned to overall quantity change and the other ½ is assigned to overall price change in the Bennett decomposition of value change. We are following a similar symmetric assignment scheme in allocating higher order interaction terms to the first order terms. For more on the properties of the Bennett decomposition, see Harberger (1971), Diewert (2005) and Diewert and Mizobuchi (2009).

  15. These industry input aggregates Z tn and the corresponding price indexes W tn are indexes of the underlying micro inputs utilized by industry n. The exact functional form for these indexes does not matter for our analysis but we assume the indexes satisfy the property that for each t and n, W tn Z tn equals the industry n input cost for period t.

  16. As in Sects. 2 and 3, P tn Y tn is nominal industry n value added in period t so that Y tn is deflated (by the industry n value added price index P tn ) industry n value added. It need not be the case that P tn Y tn is equal to W tn Z tn ; i.e., it is not necessary that value added equal input cost for each industry.

  17. In either case, we assume that the product of the total economy input price index for period t, Wt, times the corresponding aggregate input quantity or volume index, Zt, is equal to total economy nominal input cost. If Laspeyres or Paasche price indexes are used throughout, then the two stage and single stage input aggregates will coincide. If superlative indexes are used throughout, then the two stage and single stage input aggregates will approximate each other closely using annual data; see Diewert (1978).

  18. Note that WtZt equals period t total economy input cost for each t.

  19. A June year is an aggregation of a rolling year of four quarters of data ending in June of the indicated year.

  20. The price and quantity (volume) series listed in Tables 3, 4, 5 and 6 were the inputs into the Fisher index number formula for each industry.

  21. The R2 for the regression turned out to be 1.0000 so we are confident that we recovered the actual hours worked by industry from our procedure (up to a factor of proportionality).

  22. Note that X tn is now defined as industry n TFP or MFP for year t (instead of labour productivity).

  23. It was not necessary to normalize the MFP levels, Xt and X tn , (as was done for the labour productivity levels) since in 1995, for each sector, the value of inputs equals the value of outputs both in real and nominal terms.

  24. However, many of the declining sectors have outputs which are difficult to measure and so measurement error may explain some of these sectoral declines in MFP.

  25. Since we have set industry input cost equal to the nominal value added output for each industry in each year, it turns out that the input cost shares s tZn are equal to the industry’s value added output share s tYn .

  26. Note also that the sum of the entries in the last columns of Tables 18-21 is equal to the entries in the first column of Table 17. This is just a check that our exact decomposition of Γt given by (A8) does in fact hold.

References

  • Australian Bureau of Statistics (2012) Estimates of industry multifactor productivity, Australia: detailed productivity estimates. Table 5260.0.55.002, Canberra: Australian Bureau of Statistics, December 7 release

  • Australian Bureau of Statistics (2013) Australian system of national accounts: gross value added by industry. Table 5204.0, Canberra: Australian Bureau of Statistics

  • Balk BM (2008) On the decomposition of aggregate productivity change into meaningful components. Unpublished paper, Rotterdam School of Management, Erasmus University, April 4 draft

  • Bennet TL (1920) The theory of measurement of changes in cost of living. J R Stat Soc 83:455–462

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • de Avillez R (2012) Sectoral contributions to labour productivity growth in Canada: does the choice of decomposition formula matter? Productivity Monitor, No. 24, Fall, pp 97–117

  • Denison EF (1962) The sources of economic growth in the United States and the alternatives before us. Committee for Economic Development, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Diewert WE (1978) Superlative index numbers and consistency in aggregation. Econometrica 46:883–900

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Diewert WE (2004) On the tang and wang decomposition of labour productivity into sectoral effects. In: Diewert WE, Balk BM, Fixler D, Fox KJ, Nakamura AO (eds) Price and productivity measurement, volume 6, Index number theory. Trafford Press, Victoria, pp 67–76

    Google Scholar 

  • Diewert WE (2005) Index number theory using differences instead of ratios. Am J Econ Sociol 64(1):311–360

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Diewert WE, Mizobuchi H (2009) Exact and superlative price and quantity indicators. Macroecon Dyn 13:335–380

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fisher I (1922) The making of index numbers. Houghton-Mifflin, Boston

    Google Scholar 

  • Harberger AC (1971) Three basic postulates for applied welfare economics: an interpretive essay. J Econ Lit 9:785–797

    Google Scholar 

  • Tang J, Wang W (2004) Sources of aggregate labour productivity growth in Canada and the United States. Can J Econ 37:421–444

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

The author thanks Bert Balk, Derek Burnell, Ricardo de Avillez, Alice Nakamura, Hiu Wei, Marshall Reinsdorf and two referees for helpful comments and gratefully acknowledges the financial support of the SSHRC of Canada.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to W. Erwin Diewert.

Appendix: Empirical application to Australian Market Sector data; 1995–2012

Appendix: Empirical application to Australian Market Sector data; 1995–2012

We apply the productivity decompositions given by (21) (for aggregate labour productivity growth) and (38) (for TFP or MFP growth) using official industry data from the Australian Bureau of Statistics (ABS) for the June years 1995–2012.Footnote 19 From Table 9 of the ABS (2012), we can obtain indexes of industry real value for the following 16 Market Sector industries:

  1. 1.

    Agriculture, forestry and fishing;

  2. 2.

    Mining;

  3. 3.

    Manufacturing;

  4. 4.

    Electricity, gas, water and waste services;

  5. 5.

    Construction;

  6. 6.

    Wholesale trade;

  7. 7.

    Retail trade;

  8. 8.

    Accommodation and food services;

  9. 9.

    Transport, postal and warehousing;

  10. 10.

    Information, media and telecommunications;

  11. 11.

    Financial and insurance services;

  12. 12.

    Rental, hiring and real estate services;

  13. 13.

    Professional, scientific and technical services;

  14. 14.

    Administrative and support services;

  15. 15.

    Arts and recreation services and

  16. 16.

    Other services.

From Tables 9 and 10 of the ABS (2012), we can obtain quality adjusted indexes of labour input and capital services for the same 16 industries for the June years 1995–2012. From Table 14 of the same publication, we obtained the input cost share of labour and capital by the 16 industries. Finally, from the ABS (2013), estimates of value added by industry in current dollars for the 16 industries were obtained. Dividing these nominal value added estimates by industry by the corresponding indexes of industry real value added gives us implicit price indexes for each industry output. These price indexes were normalized to equal 1 in 1995 and these normalized industry price indexes, P tn , are listed in Table 1 below. The industry n year t nominal value added was divided by the corresponding normalized price index P tn in order to obtain an estimate of real value added for industry n for year t, Y tn . The Y tn are listed in Table 2 below. The units of measurement are in billions of constant 1995 dollars.

Table 1 Industry value added output prices P tn 1995–2012
Table 2 Industry value added output volumes Y tn 1995–2012

We assume that value added is equal to input cost by industry so that with our estimates of nominal value added by industry and the ABS cost shares, we can obtain estimates for the value of labour input and capital services input by industry. These nominal cost values can be divided by the ABS index estimates of real labour and capital services input to give us implicit price indexes for labour and capital services by industry. These price indexes were normalized to equal 1 in 1995 and are listed in Tables 3 and 5 below as W tLn and W tKn for industry n in year t. Finally, nominal industry n labour cost in year t was divided by W tLn to give the industry n quantity of labour input in year t, Q tLn , and nominal industry n capital services cost in year t was divided by W tKn to give the industry n quantity of capital services input in year t, Q tKn . The Q tLn and Q tKn are listed in Tables 4 and 6 below.

Table 3 Industry quality adjusted wages W tLn 1995–2012
Table 4 Industry quality adjusted labour input Q tLn 1995–2012
Table 5 Industry prices of capital services W tKn 1995–2012
Table 6 Industry capital services volumes Q tKn 1995–2012

In order to calculate industry measures of Multifactor productivity, we will need estimates of aggregate input prices and quantities (or volumes) by industry. Thus, we computed chained Fisher (1922) price and quantity indexes, W tn and Z tn for industry n in year t and these indexes are listed in Tables 7 and 8 respectively.Footnote 20

Table 7 Industry input price indexes W tn 1995–2012
Table 8 Industry input volume (quantity) indexes Z tn 1995–2012

The above tables provide the data that are necessary to calculate Industry and Market Sector MFP estimates. However, in order to calculate industry and Market Sector labour productivity estimates, we will require an additional Table. From the ABS (2012), Table 9, we can obtain indexes of hours worked in the 16 industries as well as for the Market Sector. Denote these index series for year t as H t1 –H t16 and Ht. We ran an ordinary least squares regression of H on H1–H16 (with no constant term) in order to recover the actual industry hours worked by industry (up to a factor of proportionality).Footnote 21 Denote the estimated industry regression coefficients by α1–α16 and define Market Sector hours worked in year t by Lt ≡ Ht and the corresponding year t industry n measures of hours worked by L tn  ≡ αnH tn for n = 1, …, 16. The resulting measures of labour input are listed in Table 9 below. Note that for each year t, Lt = ∑ 16n=1 L t.n

Table 9 Market Sector hours worked Lt and industry hours worked L tn 1995–2012

With the above industry data listed, we can now use Eq. (2) in the main text to calculate the labour productivity level of industry n in year t, X tn as Y tn /L tn , where the Y tn are listed in Table 2 and the L tn are listed in Table 9 above. We normalize these industry labour productivity levels by dividing each X tn by X 1995n for t = 1995, … ,2012 and n = 1, …, 16. Denote the normalized industry labour productivities by X t*n  ≡ X tn /X 1995n . These normalized labour productivity estimates are listed in Table 10 below.

Table 10 Market Sector aggregate Xt* and industry labour productivity levels X t*n relative to 1995 levels: 1995–2012
Table 11 Growth rates for the Market Sector aggregate labour productivity Γt and the industry labour productivity growth rates γ tn , 1996–2012 (in percentage points)
Table 12 Contributions of industry productivity growth to aggregate labour productivity growth ΔX tn and sum of industry contributions ∑n ΔX tn , 1996–2012 (percentage points)
Table 13 Contributions of industry real output price changes to aggregate labour productivity growth Δp tn and sum of industry contributions ∑n Δp tn , 1996–2012 (percentage points)
Table 14 Contributions of changes in industry labour input shares to aggregate labour productivity growth Δs tLn and sum of industry contributions ∑n Δs tLn , 1996–2012 (percentage points)

The next step is to construct a measure of aggregate Market Sector real value added, Yt for each year t. We will use Fisher chained indexes of the industry outputs Y tn (with price weights P tn ) in order to construct the Yt. The P tn are listed in Table 1 and the corresponding Y tn are listed in Table 2. The chained Fisher Market Sector output price index that corresponds to Yt is denoted by Pt. The Pt and Yt are listed in Table 15 below. Note that these indexes satisfy the identity Yt = ∑ 16n=1 P tn Y tn /Pt for each t. With Yt and Lt defined, the year t Market Sector labour productivity level is defined as Xt ≡ Yt/Lt for t = 1995, …, 2012. We normalize these Market Sector labour productivity levels by dividing each Xt by X1995 so that Xt* ≡ Xt/X1995 for t = 1995, …, 2012. These normalized Market Sector labour productivity estimates are listed in the second column of Table 9 below.

Table 15 Market Sector MFP Xt, value added output Yt, input Zt, labour input Lt, capital services input Kt and price indexes for aggregate output, input, labour and capital

Over the 18-year period, there was a 43.7 % increase in Market Sector labour productivity. It can be seen that industries 2, 4 and 12 experienced negative labour productivity growth over the sample period.

We turn now to our decomposition of aggregate labour productivity growth into explanatory factors. For t = 1996, 1997, …, 2012, define the year t aggregate and industry rates of growth of labour productivity by the following extensions of definitions (10) and (11) to the case of many periods: Γt ≡ (Xt/Xt−1) − 1 and γ tn  ≡ (X tn /X t−1n ) − 1 for n = 1, …, 16. These aggregate and industry rates of growth of labour productivity (times 100) are listed in Table 11 below.

Thus on average, Market Sector labour productivity grew at about 2.16 % per year.

The extension of definitions (12) and (13) to the case of many time periods is ρ tn  ≡ (p tn /p t−1n ) − 1 (the rate of growth of the industry n real output price for year t) and σ tn  ≡ (s tLn /s t−1Ln ) − 1 (the rate of growth of the industry n share of total hours worked for year t) for n = 1, …, N. The real output price for industry n, p tn is defined as P tn /Pt where the industry output prices P tn are listed in Table 1 above and the Market Sector output prices Pt are listed in Table 15 below. The industry labour input shares s tLn are defined as industry n hours worked in year t L tn divided by Market Sector hours worked in year t, Lt. The Lt and L tn are listed in Table 9 above. The industry nominal value added shares of Market Sector value added are defined as s tYn  ≡ P tn Y tn /PtYt for t = 1995, …, 2012 and n = 1, …, 16. We will not list the ρ tn , σ tn and s tYn since these numbers can readily be calculated using the information in the listed Tables. The year t labour productivity contribution terms due to industry productivity growth (ΔX tn ), due to changes in industry real output prices (Δp tn ) and due to changes in industry labour input shares (Δs tLn ) are defined by (39)–(41) below

$$ \Delta {\text{X}}_{\text{n}}^{\text{t}} \equiv {\text{s}}_{\text{Yn}}^{{{\text{t}} - 1}} \gamma_{\text{n}}^{\text{t}} \left\{ { 1 + \left( {{\raise0.7ex\hbox{$1$} \!\mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {1 2}}\right.\kern-0pt} \!\lower0.7ex\hbox{$2$}}} \right)\rho_{\text{n}}^{\text{t}} + \left( {{\raise0.7ex\hbox{$1$} \!\mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {1 2}}\right.\kern-0pt} \!\lower0.7ex\hbox{$2$}}} \right)\sigma_{\text{n}}^{\text{t}} + \left( {{\raise0.7ex\hbox{$1$} \!\mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {1 3}}\right.\kern-0pt} \!\lower0.7ex\hbox{$3$}}} \right)\rho_{\text{n}}^{\text{t}} \sigma_{\text{n}}^{\text{t}} } \right\} $$
(39)
$$ \Delta {\text{p}}_{\text{n}}^{\text{t}} \equiv {\text{s}}_{\text{Yn}}^{{{\text{t}} - 1}} \rho_{\text{n}}^{\text{t}} \left\{ { 1 + \left( {{\raise0.7ex\hbox{$1$} \!\mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {1 2}}\right.\kern-0pt} \!\lower0.7ex\hbox{$2$}}} \right)\gamma_{\text{n}}^{\text{t}} + \left( {{\raise0.7ex\hbox{$1$} \!\mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {1 2}}\right.\kern-0pt} \!\lower0.7ex\hbox{$2$}}} \right)\sigma_{\text{n}}^{\text{t}} + \left( {{\raise0.7ex\hbox{$1$} \!\mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {1 3}}\right.\kern-0pt} \!\lower0.7ex\hbox{$3$}}} \right)\gamma_{\text{n}}^{\text{t}} \sigma_{\text{n}}^{\text{t}} } \right\} $$
(40)
$$ \Delta {\text{s}}_{\text{Ln}}^{\text{t}} \equiv {\text{s}}_{\text{Yn}}^{{{\text{t}} - 1}} \sigma_{\text{n}}^{\text{t}} \left\{ { 1 + \left( {{\raise0.7ex\hbox{$1$} \!\mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {1 2}}\right.\kern-0pt} \!\lower0.7ex\hbox{$2$}}} \right)\gamma_{\text{n}}^{\text{t}} + \left( {{\raise0.7ex\hbox{$1$} \!\mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {1 2}}\right.\kern-0pt} \!\lower0.7ex\hbox{$2$}}} \right)\rho_{\text{n}}^{\text{t}} + \left( {{\raise0.7ex\hbox{$1$} \!\mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {1 3}}\right.\kern-0pt} \!\lower0.7ex\hbox{$3$}}} \right)\gamma_{\text{n}}^{\text{t}} \rho_{\text{nt}}^{\text{t}} } \right\} $$
(41)

Table 12 below lists the industry productivity growth contribution terms ΔX tn (times 100) along with the year by year sum of these terms, Sumt = ∑ Nn=1 ΔX tn (times 100).

Note that the overall mean of the industry labour productivity growth rates to overall Market Sector labour productivity growth is 1.75 % points per year. The productivity growth of Industry 11 (Financial and Insurance Services) contributes the most to overall Market Sector labour productivity growth—about 0.45 % points per year. The most negative contribution comes from Industry 2 (Mining; −0.33 % points per year) followed by Industry 4 (Electricity, Gas, Water and Waste Services; −0.05 % points per year).

Table 13 below lists the industry real output price change contribution terms Δp tn (times 100) along with the year by year sum of these terms, Sumt = ∑ Nn=1 Δp tn (times 100).

Note that the overall mean of the industry contributions to overall Market Sector labour productivity growth due to changes in real industry output prices is practically zero (0.0018 % points per year). The changes in the real output prices of Industry 2 (Mining) contribute the most to overall Market Sector labour productivity growth: about 0.42 % points per year, followed by Industry 11, Finance and Insurance Services (0.11 % per year). The most negative contribution comes from Industry 3 (Manufacturing; −0.17 % points per year) followed by Industry 1 (Agriculture; −0.10 % points per year). These effects flow from increasing real output prices for Industries 2 and 11 and decreasing real output prices for Industries 1 and 3.

Table 14 below lists the industry contributions of changes in the industry share of labour input in hours to overall labour productivity growth Δs tLn (times 100) along with the year by year sum of these terms, Sumt = ∑ Nn=1 Δs tLn (times 100).

The overall mean of the industry contributions to overall Market Sector labour productivity growth due to changes in the industry shares of labour hours is substantial at 0.414 % points per year. Note that the sum of the final columns in Tables 12, 13 and 14 equals the first column in Table 11; i.e., the decomposition of overall Market Sector labour productivity growth given by (21) is exact. The changes in the labour share of Industry 2 (Mining) contribute the most to overall Market Sector labour productivity growth—about 0.51 % points per year, followed by Industries 5 and 13 (Construction and Professional, Technical and Scientific Services) at 0.16 % points per year. The most negative contribution comes from Industry 3 (Manufacturing; −0.39 % points per year) followed by Industry 1 (Agriculture; −0.12 % points per year).

An increase in labour productivity of a production unit is not a reliable guide in determining whether the efficiency of the unit has increased, since an increase in output with no change in labour input could be due to an increase in capital input. Multifactor Productivity growth takes into account the growth of all inputs and thus is a better indicator of efficiency improvement than labour productivity growth. Thus, the decomposition of MFP growth into explanatory factors should be of more interest to economic analysts.

Recall that Eq. (22) defined the industry n MFP or TFP level in period t as X tn  ≡ Y tn /Z tn where the industry output volumes Y tn are listed in Table 2 and the industry input volumes Z tn are listed in Table 8 above.Footnote 22 The corresponding industry output and input indexes were defined as P tn and W tn and are listed in Tables 1 and 7 above. As noted above, the Market Sector value added output volume indexes for period t, Yt, and the corresponding price indexes Pt were defined as chained Fisher indexes using the industry output prices and volumes, P t1 , …, P t16 and Y t1 , …, Y t16 as the input series into the index number formulae. The resulting Pt and Yt are listed in Table 15 below. The Market Sector input volume indexes for period t, Zt, and the corresponding price indexes Wt were defined as chained Fisher indexes using the industry input prices and volumes for both labour and capital, W tL1 , …, W tL16 ; W tK1 , …, W tK16 and Q tL1 , …, Q tL16 ; Q tK1 , …, Q tK16 as the input series into the Fisher index number formula (see Tables 3, 4, 5 and 6 for a listing of these labour and capital input price and quantity series). The resulting Wt and Zt are listed in Table 15 below. Note that for each year t, we have Zt = ∑ 16n=1 (W tn /Wt)Z tn  = ∑ 16n=1 w tn Z tn where the year t real input price for industry n is defined as w tn  ≡ W tn /Wt for n = 1, …, 16. Finally, the year t Market Sector MFP is defined as Xt ≡ Yt/Zt. The Xt are listed in Tables 15 and 16.Footnote 23 The industry n MFP levels, X tn  ≡ Y tn /Z tn , are listed in Table 16.

Table 16 Market Sector MFP Xt and industry MFP Levels X tn relative to 1995 levels: 1995–2012

Thus Market Sector MFP increased by 5.3 % over the sample period (and has steadily declined since hitting a peak level of 1.117 in 2004). The industries which had the highest rates of growth of MFP over the sample period were Industry 1 (Agriculture with X 20121  = 2.001) and Industry 11 (Finance and Insurance Services with X 201211  = 1.480). The industries which had absolute declines in MFP were 2 (Mining with X 20122  = 0.577), 4 (Electricity, Gas, Water and Waste Services with X 20124  = 0.640), 10 (Information, Media and Telecom Services with X 201210  = 0.996), 12 (Rental, Hiring and Real Estate Services with X 201212  = 0.540), 14 (Administrative and Support Services with X 201214  = 0.912), 15 (Arts and Recreational Services with X 201215  = 0.958) and 16 (Other Services with X 201216  = 0.952). Thus, the MFP measures paint a very different efficiency picture compared to the labour productivity measures.Footnote 24

Table 17 presents essentially the same information as is in Table 16 except in Table 17, we list the rates of growth of MFP (times 100 in order to convert into percentage points) for the Market Sector, Γt ≡ (Xt/Xt−1) − 1, and for industries 1–16, γt ≡ (X tn /X t−1n ) − 1 for n = 1, …, 16.

Table 17 Growth Rates for Market Sector MFP Γt and for the Industry MFP Growth Rates γ tn , 1996–2012 (in percentage points)

Thus the average rate of TFP growth for the Market Sector over the sample period was only 0.31 % points per year

We turn now to the decomposition of Market Sector MFP growth in year t, Γt ≡ (Xt/Xt−1) − 1, into explanatory factors; i.e., recall the decomposition (38) in the main text. The definitions of the year t industry n share of Market Sector value added, s tYn  ≡ P tn Y tn /PtYt, and the rates of growth of the industry n real output prices for year t, ρ tn  ≡ (p tn /p t−1n ) − 1, remain unchanged. The year t industry rates of MFP are defined as γ tn  ≡ (X tn /X t−1n ) − 1 for n = 1, …, 16 but of course, now the X tn are industry n levels of MFP instead of levels of labour productivity. The industry n share of Market Sector total cost in year t, s tZn , is defined as W tn Z tn /WtZt for n = 1, …, 16Footnote 25 and σ tn  ≡ s tZn /s t−1Zn is defined as the year t rate of input cost growth for industry n for t = 1996, …, 2012. The industry n real input price for year t is defined as w tn  ≡ W tn /Wt for n = 1, …, 16 and t = 1995, …, 2012 and the year t reciprocal rate of growth in these real input prices is defined as ω tn  ≡ (w t−1n /w tn ) − 1 for t = 1996, …, 2012. The extension of the decomposition terms (34)–(37) to the case of many periods is given by definitions (42)–(45) below for n = 1, …, 16 and t = 1996, …, 2012:

$$ \begin{aligned} \Delta {\text{X}}_{\text{n}}^{\text{t}} & \equiv {\text{s}}_{\text{Yn}}^{{{\text{t}} - 1}} \gamma_{\text{n}}^{\text{t}} \left\{ { 1 + \left( {{\raise0.7ex\hbox{$1$} \!\mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {1 2}}\right.\kern-0pt} \!\lower0.7ex\hbox{$2$}}} \right)\rho_{\text{n}}^{\text{t}} + \left( {{\raise0.7ex\hbox{$1$} \!\mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {1 2}}\right.\kern-0pt} \!\lower0.7ex\hbox{$2$}}} \right)\omega_{\text{n}}^{\text{t}} + \left( {{\raise0.7ex\hbox{$1$} \!\mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {1 2}}\right.\kern-0pt} \!\lower0.7ex\hbox{$2$}}} \right)\sigma_{\text{n}}^{\text{t}} + \left( {{\raise0.7ex\hbox{$1$} \!\mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {1 3}}\right.\kern-0pt} \!\lower0.7ex\hbox{$3$}}} \right)\rho_{\text{n}}^{\text{t}} \omega_{\text{n}}^{\text{t}} } \right. \\ & \quad \left. { + \left( {{\raise0.7ex\hbox{$1$} \!\mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {1 3}}\right.\kern-0pt} \!\lower0.7ex\hbox{$3$}}} \right)\rho_{\text{n}}^{\text{t}} \sigma_{\text{n}}^{\text{t}} + \left( {{\raise0.7ex\hbox{$1$} \!\mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {1 3}}\right.\kern-0pt} \!\lower0.7ex\hbox{$3$}}} \right)\rho_{\text{n}}^{\text{t}} \sigma_{\text{n}}^{\text{t}} + \left( {{\raise0.7ex\hbox{$1$} \!\mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {1 4}}\right.\kern-0pt} \!\lower0.7ex\hbox{$4$}}} \right)\rho_{\text{n}}^{\text{t}} \omega_{\text{n}}^{\text{t}} \sigma_{\text{n}}^{\text{t}} } \right\} \\ \end{aligned} $$
(42)
$$ \begin{aligned} \Delta {\text{p}}_{\text{n}}^{\text{t}} & \equiv {\text{s}}_{\text{Yn}}^{{{\text{t}} - 1}} \rho_{\text{n}}^{\text{t}} \left\{ { 1 + \left( {{\raise0.7ex\hbox{$1$} \!\mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {1 2}}\right.\kern-0pt} \!\lower0.7ex\hbox{$2$}}} \right)\gamma_{\text{n}}^{\text{t}} + \left( {{\raise0.7ex\hbox{$1$} \!\mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {1 2}}\right.\kern-0pt} \!\lower0.7ex\hbox{$2$}}} \right)\omega_{\text{n}}^{\text{t}} + \left( {{\raise0.7ex\hbox{$1$} \!\mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {1 2}}\right.\kern-0pt} \!\lower0.7ex\hbox{$2$}}} \right)\sigma_{\text{n}}^{\text{t}} + \left( {{\raise0.7ex\hbox{$1$} \!\mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {1 3}}\right.\kern-0pt} \!\lower0.7ex\hbox{$3$}}} \right)\gamma_{\text{n}}^{\text{t}} \omega_{\text{n}}^{\text{t}} } \right. \\ & \quad \left. { + \left( {{\raise0.7ex\hbox{$1$} \!\mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {1 3}}\right.\kern-0pt} \!\lower0.7ex\hbox{$3$}}} \right)\gamma_{\text{n}}^{\text{t}} \sigma_{\text{n}}^{\text{t}} + \left( {{\raise0.7ex\hbox{$1$} \!\mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {1 3}}\right.\kern-0pt} \!\lower0.7ex\hbox{$3$}}} \right)\omega_{\text{n}}^{\text{t}} \sigma_{\text{n}}^{\text{t}} + \left( {{\raise0.7ex\hbox{$1$} \!\mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {1 4}}\right.\kern-0pt} \!\lower0.7ex\hbox{$4$}}} \right)\gamma_{\text{n}}^{\text{t}} \omega_{\text{n}}^{\text{t}} \sigma_{\text{n}}^{\text{t}} } \right\} \\ \end{aligned} $$
(43)
$$ \begin{aligned} \Delta {\text{w}}_{\text{n}}^{\text{t}} & \equiv {\text{s}}_{\text{Yn}}^{{{\text{t}} - 1}} \omega_{\text{n}}^{\text{t}} \left\{ { 1 + \left( {{\raise0.7ex\hbox{$1$} \!\mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {1 2}}\right.\kern-0pt} \!\lower0.7ex\hbox{$2$}}} \right)\gamma_{\text{n}}^{\text{t}} + \left( {{\raise0.7ex\hbox{$1$} \!\mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {1 2}}\right.\kern-0pt} \!\lower0.7ex\hbox{$2$}}} \right)\rho_{\text{n}}^{\text{t}} + \left( {{\raise0.7ex\hbox{$1$} \!\mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {1 2}}\right.\kern-0pt} \!\lower0.7ex\hbox{$2$}}} \right)\sigma_{\text{n}}^{\text{t}} + \left( {{\raise0.7ex\hbox{$1$} \!\mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {1 3}}\right.\kern-0pt} \!\lower0.7ex\hbox{$3$}}} \right)\gamma_{\text{n}}^{\text{t}} \rho_{\text{n}}^{\text{t}} } \right. \\ & \quad \left. { + \left( {{\raise0.7ex\hbox{$1$} \!\mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {1 3}}\right.\kern-0pt} \!\lower0.7ex\hbox{$3$}}} \right)\gamma_{\text{n}}^{\text{t}} \sigma_{\text{n}}^{\text{t}} + \left( {{\raise0.7ex\hbox{$1$} \!\mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {1 3}}\right.\kern-0pt} \!\lower0.7ex\hbox{$3$}}} \right)\rho_{\text{n}}^{\text{t}} \sigma_{\text{n}}^{\text{t}} + \left( {{\raise0.7ex\hbox{$1$} \!\mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {1 4}}\right.\kern-0pt} \!\lower0.7ex\hbox{$4$}}} \right)\gamma_{\text{n}}^{\text{t}} \rho_{\text{n}}^{\text{t}} \sigma_{\text{n}}^{\text{t}} } \right\} \\ \end{aligned} $$
(44)
$$ \begin{aligned} \Delta {\text{s}}_{\text{Zn}}^{\text{t}} & \equiv {\text{s}}_{\text{Yn}}^{{{\text{t}} - 1}} \sigma_{\text{n}}^{\text{t}} \left\{ { 1 + \left( {{\raise0.7ex\hbox{$1$} \!\mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {1 2}}\right.\kern-0pt} \!\lower0.7ex\hbox{$2$}}} \right)\gamma_{\text{n}}^{\text{t}} + \left( {{\raise0.7ex\hbox{$1$} \!\mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {1 2}}\right.\kern-0pt} \!\lower0.7ex\hbox{$2$}}} \right)\rho_{\text{n}}^{\text{t}} + \left( {{\raise0.7ex\hbox{$1$} \!\mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {1 2}}\right.\kern-0pt} \!\lower0.7ex\hbox{$2$}}} \right)\omega_{\text{n}}^{\text{t}} + \left( {{\raise0.7ex\hbox{$1$} \!\mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {1 3}}\right.\kern-0pt} \!\lower0.7ex\hbox{$3$}}} \right)\gamma_{\text{n}}^{\text{t}} \rho_{\text{n}}^{\text{t}} } \right. \\ & \quad \left. { + \left( {{\raise0.7ex\hbox{$1$} \!\mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {1 3}}\right.\kern-0pt} \!\lower0.7ex\hbox{$3$}}} \right)\gamma_{\text{n}}^{\text{t}} \omega_{\text{n}}^{\text{t}} + \left( {{\raise0.7ex\hbox{$1$} \!\mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {1 3}}\right.\kern-0pt} \!\lower0.7ex\hbox{$3$}}} \right)\rho_{\text{n}}^{\text{t}} \omega_{\text{n}}^{\text{t}} + \left( {{\raise0.7ex\hbox{$1$} \!\mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {1 4}}\right.\kern-0pt} \!\lower0.7ex\hbox{$4$}}} \right)\gamma_{\text{nt}} \rho_{\text{n}}^{\text{t}} \omega_{\text{n}}^{\text{t}} } \right\} \\ \end{aligned} $$
(45)

The above contributions sum up exactly to the year t Market Sector MFP growth rate Γt ≡ (Xt/Xt−1) − 1; i.e., we have

$$ \Gamma^{\text{t}} = \sum\limits_{{{\text{n}} = 1}}^{ 1 6} \Delta {\text{X}}_{\text{n}}^{\text{t}} + \sum\limits_{{{\text{n}} = 1}}^{ 1 6} \Delta {\text{p}}_{\text{n}}^{\text{t}} + \sum\limits_{{{\text{n}} = 1}}^{ 1 6} \Delta {\text{w}}_{\text{n}}^{\text{t}} + \sum\limits_{{{\text{n}} = 1}}^{ 1 6} \Delta {\text{s}}_{\text{Zn}}^{\text{t}} $$
(46)

Tables 18, 19, 20 and 21 below list the industry contribution terms to overall Market Sector TFP growth defined by (42)–(45) above (times 100). The final column in each Table lists the sum over industries of the individual industry contribution terms.

Table 18 Contributions of industry MFP growth to Market Sector MFP growth ΔX tn and sum of industry contributions ∑n ΔX tn , 1996–2012 (percentage points)
Table 19 Contributions of industry real output price changes to aggregate MFP growth Δp tn and sum of industry contributions ∑n Δp tn , 1996–2012 (percentage points)
Table 20 Contributions of industry real reciprocal input price changes to aggregate MFP growth Δw tn and sum of industry contributions ∑n Δw tn , 1996–2012 (percentage points)
Table 21 Contributions of changes in industry input cost shares to aggregate MFP growth Δs tZn and sum of industry contributions ∑n Δs tZn , 1996–2012 (percentage points)

Thus the final column in Table 18 lists the sum of the industry TFP contribution terms, ∑ 16n=1 ΔX tn (times 100), the final column in Table 19 lists the sum of the real output price terms, ∑ 16n=1 Δp tn (times 100) the final column in Table 20 lists the sum of the real input price terms, ∑ 16n=1 Δw tn (times 100), and the final column in Table 21 lists the sum of the industry change in input cost share terms, ∑ 16n=1 Δs tZn (times 100). The sample averages for these four sets of terms turned out to be: 0.31, 0.003, −0.002 and 0.002. Thus, while the contribution terms Δp tn , Δw tn and Δs tZn can be fairly large for some industries n for some years t, when we sum these contribution terms over all of the industries, it turns out that the overall effect of real input and output price changes and changes in input cost shares is close to zero in each year!Footnote 26 Thus these contribution terms simply reallocate the effects of the individual industry MFP contribution terms among the industries but do not change the fact that when aggregating over industries, what counts is the first set of terms, ∑ 16n=1 ΔX tn , in the productivity growth decomposition defined by (46) above. This result is quite different from the results obtained for our decomposition of Market Sector labour productivity growth.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Diewert, W.E. Decompositions of productivity growth into sectoral effects. J Prod Anal 43, 367–387 (2015). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11123-014-0392-0

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11123-014-0392-0

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation