Abstract
A growing body of research examines the political sources of economic inequality in the United States. A second literature examines the political consequences of who votes. The current study contributes to both literatures by examining the influence of income bias in voter turnout on income inequality in the American states from 1980 to 2010. I use power resources theory and research demonstrating growing partisan polarization across income levels as theoretical foundations. Using time-series and cross-sectional analysis, I find that states with greater income bias in turnout have higher levels of income inequality than states with greater parity in voter turnout across income levels, findings that are robust across various model specifications. The implications of these findings for our understanding of economic inequality, low-income voter turnout, and state electoral laws are discussed.
Similar content being viewed by others
Notes
While some research finds little differences across income levels on many policy issues (especially when comparing high- and middle-income citizens), important differences are found in welfare and tax policy preferences between high- and middle-income citizens on one hand and low-income citizens on the other (Enns and Wlezien 2011; Soroka and Wlezien 2008).
As Langer (1999) notes, the Gini estimates based on Census survey data like the American Community Survey Reports produces estimates of income inequality that are less reliable than estimates based on decennial Census data, especially for states with smaller populations and, consequently, smaller sample sizes. Likewise, as both Langer (1999) and Kelly and Witko (2012) point out, these state-level Gini estimates are based on pre-tax and post-transfer income, while we would ultimately prefer post-tax and post-transfer estimates. However, overall, Langer (1999) concludes that “the battery of validity and reliability tests demonstrate that we can have confidence in using these measures” (62).
The Voter Supplement File asks respondents to identify their income level using a 14-point ordinal scale. Using the national sample, I identify the cut points on this 14-point scale that correspond to roughly the top 5th and the bottom 5th of the distribution for the national sample. For all years examined the smallest sample size is for the bottom 5th of the distribution for the 1990 Connecticut sample, with a sample of 99. Several other states tend to have smaller samples including Maine, Delaware, Nevada, and Hawaii. However, for most state/years samples for the bottom and top quintiles are well over 100.
The current paper considers income bias in turnout that compares turnout rates of the top of the income distribution with turnout rates of the bottom of the distribution. It is possible, however, that turnout bias between (1) the middle and the bottom of the income distribution and (2) the top and the middle of the income distribution also influence state income inequality. These possibilities are examined and reported in the online Appendix B.
Statistical Abstracts of the United States can be found here: www.census.gov/compendia/statab/.
Following Erikson et al. (2002), I use David Mayhew’s list of important laws updated through 2012 (http://davidmayhew.commons.yale.edu/datasets-divided-we-govern/). Laws are coded 0 if they are ideologically ambiguous, +1 if they are liberal, −1 if they are conservative, +2 if they are exceptionally important and liberal, and −2 if they are exceptionally important and conservative.
While taking the first difference of a non-stationary variable does not guarantee that it will be stationary (Banerjee et al. 1994), tests reveal that the first differenced Gini indexes are stationary.
Analysis of median lag length shows that the long-term effect is largely limited to two lags. Income bias in turnout in the November 2000 election may influence income inequality in 2005 and 2006 but does not have a sizeable influence beyond then.
Analysis examining the influence of high-income turnout with middle-income turnout, also reported in the online Appendix B, produces findings inconsistent across fixed and random effects models.
References
Abramowitz, A. I., & Saunders, K. L. (2008). Is polarization a myth? Journal of Politics, 70(2), 542–555.
Al-Samarrie, A., & Miller, H. P. (1967). State differential in income concentration. American Economic Review, 57(1), 59–72.
Alt, J., & Lowry, R. (1994). Divided government, fiscal institutions, and budget deficits: Evidence from the states. American Political Science Review, 88(4), 974–991.
Avery, J. M., & Peffley, M. (2005). Voter registration requirements, voter turnout, and welfare eligibility policy: Class bias matters. State Politics and Policy Quarterly, 5(1), 47–67.
Banerjee, A., Dolado, J., Galbraith, J. W., & Hendry, D. F. (1994). Co-integration, error-correction, and the econometric analysis of non-stationary data. New York: Oxford University Press.
Barreto, M. A., Nuno, S. A., & Sanchez, G. R. (2009). The disproportionate impact of voter-ID requirements on the electorate—new evidence from Indiana, PS. Political Science and Politics, 42(1), 111–116.
Barrilleaux, C., & Davis, B. C. (2003). Explaining states-level variations in levels and change in the distribution of income in the United States, 1978-1990. American Politics Research, 31(3), 280–300.
Bartels, L. M. (2008). Unequal democracy: The political economy of the new gilded age. New York: Russell Sage Foundation.
Beck, N., & Katz, J. N. (1995). What to do (and not to do) with time-series cross-sectional data. American Political Science Review, 89(3), 634–647.
Bennett, S. E., & Resnick, D. (1990). The implications of nonvoting for democracy in the United States. American Journal of Political Science, 34(3), 771–802.
Berinsky, A. (2005). The perverse consequences of electoral reform in the United States. American Politics Research, 33(4), 471–491.
Bernstein, R. A., Chada, A., & Montjoy, R. (2003). Cross-state bias in voting and registration over-reporting in the Current Population Surveys. State Politics and Policy Quarterly, 3(4), 367–386.
Berry, W. D., Ringquist, E. J., Fording, R. C., & Hanson, R. L. (1998). Measuring citizen and government ideology in the American states, 1960-93. American Journal of Political Science, 42(1), 327–348.
Bhatti, Y., & Erikson, R. S. (2011). How poorly and the poor represented in the U.S. Senate? In P. K. Enns & C. Wlezien (Eds.), Who gets represented? (pp. 223–246). New York: Russell Sage Foundation.
Bollen, K. A., & Jackman, R. W. (1985). Political democracy and the size distribution of income. American Sociological Review, 50(4), 438–457.
Bradley, D., Huber, E., Moller, S., Nielsen, F., & Stephens, J. D. (2003). Distribution and redistribution in postindustrial democracies. World Politics, 55(2), 193–228.
Butler, R., Hutchison, M., & Krueger, B. (2012). The new American nonvoter. In: Presented at the 2012 meeting of the New England Political Science Association, Portsmouth, NH.
Citrin, J., Schickler, E., & Sides, J. (2003). What if everyone voted? Simulating the impact of increased turnout in Senate elections. American Journal of Political Science, 47(1), 75–90.
Cutler, D. M., & Katz, L. F. (1991). Macroeconomic performance and the disadvantaged. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 2, 1–74.
De Boef, S., & Keele, L. (2008). Taking time seriously. American Journal of Political Science, 52(1), 184–200.
Ellis, C. R., Ura, J. D., & Ashley-Robinson, J. (2006). The dynamic consequences of nonvoting in American national elections. Political Research Quarterly, 59(2), 227–233.
Enns, P. K., & Wlezien, C. (2011). Group opinion and the study of representation. In P. K. Enns & C. Wlezien (Eds.), Who gets represented? (pp. 1–25). New York: Russell Sage Foundation.
Erikson, R. S., MacKuen, M. B., & Stimson, J. (2002). The macro polity. New York: Cambridge University Press.
Esping-Andersen, G., & Myles, J. (2009). Economic inequality and the welfare state. In W. Salverda, B. Nolan, & T. M. Smeeding (Eds.), The Oxford handbook of economic inequality (pp. 664–693). New York: Oxford University Press.
Fellowes, M. C., & Rowe, G. (2004). Politics and the new American welfare state. American Journal of Political Science, 48(2), 362–373.
Flavin, P. (2012a). Income inequality and policy representation in the American states. American Politics Research, 40(1), 29–59.
Flavin, P. (2012b). Does higher voter turnout among the poor lead to more equal policy representation? Social Science Journal, 49(4), 405–412.
Freund, E., & Morris, I. L. (2005). The lottery and income inequality in the states. Social Science Quarterly, 86, 996–1012.
Galbraith, J. K., & Hale, J. T. (2008). State income inequality and presidential election turnout and outcomes. Social Science Quarterly, 89(4), 887–901.
Garand, J. C. (1985). Partisan change and shifting expenditure priorities in the American states. American Politics Quarterly, 13(4), 355–392.
Garand, J. C. (2010). Income inequality, party polarization, and roll-call voting in the U.S. Senate. Journal of Politics, 72(4), 1109–1128.
Gilens, M. (2005). Inequality and democratic responsiveness. Public Opinion Quarterly, 69(5), 778–796.
Gilens, M. (2009). Preference gaps and inequality in representation. PS: Political Science and Politics, 42(2), 335–341.
Gilens, M. (2012). Affluence and influence: Economic inequality and political power in America. Princeton: Princeton University Press.
Gilens, M., & Page, B. I. (2014). Testing theories of American politics: Elites, interest groups, and average citizens. Perspectives on Politics, 12, 564–581.
Griffin, J. D., & Newman, B. (2005). Are voters better represented? Journal of Politics, 67(4), 1206–1227.
Griffin, J. D., & Newman, B. (2008). Minority report: Evaluating political equality in America. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Hacker, J. S., & Pierson, P. (2010). Winner-take-all politics: Public policy, political organization, and the precipitous rise of top incomes in the United States. Politics and Society, 38(2), 152–204.
Hajnal, Z., & Trounstine, J. (2005). Where turnout matters: The consequences of uneven turnout in city politics. Journal of Politics, 67(2), 515–535.
Heathcote, J., Perri, F., & Violante, G. L. (2010). Unequal we stand: An empirical analysis of economic inequality in the United States, 1967-2006. Review of Economic Dynamics, 13(1), 15–51.
Hetherington, M. (2001). Resurgent mass partisanship: The role of elite polarization. American Political Science Review, 95(3), 619–631.
Hicks, Alexander., Friedland, Roger., & Johnson, Edwin. (1978). Class power and state policy: The case of large business corporations, labor unions and governmental redistribution in the American states. American Sociological Review, 43(3), 302–315.
Highton, B. (1997). Easy registration and voter turnout. Journal of Politics, 59(2), 565–575.
Highton, B. (2005). Self-reported versus proxy-reported voter turnout in the Current Population Survey. Public Opinion Quarterly, 69(1), 113–123.
Highton, B., & Wolfinger, R. E. (2001). The political implications of higher turnout. British Journal of Political Science, 31(1), 179–192.
Hill, K. Q., & Leighley, J. E. (1992). The policy consequences of class bias in state electorates. American Journal of Political Science, 36(2), 351–365.
Hood, M. V., Kidd, Q., & Morris, I. L. (2001). The key issue: Constituency effects and southern senators’ roll-call voting on civil rights. Legislative Studies Quarterly, 26(4), 599–621.
Kelly, N. J. (2009). The politics of income inequality in the United States. New York: Cambridge University Press.
Kelly, N. J., & Witko, C. (2012). Federalism and American inequality. Journal of Politics, 74(2), 414–426.
Korpi, W. (1983). The democratic class struggle. London: Routledge and Kegan Paul.
Korpi, W. (2006). Power resources and employer-centered approaches in explanations of welfare states and varieties of capitalism. World Politics, 58(2), 167–206.
Langer, L. (1999). Measuring income distribution across space and time in the American states. Social Science Quarterly, 80(1), 55–67.
Langer, L. (2001). The consequences of state economic development strategies on income distribution in the American states, 1976 to 1994. American Politics Research, 29(4), 392–415.
McCarty, N., & Pontusson, J. (2009). The political economy of inequality and redistribution. In W. Salverda, B. Nolan, & T. M. Smeeding (Eds.), The Oxford handbook of economic inequality (pp. 665–692). New York: Oxford University Press.
McCarty, N., Poole, K. T., & Rosenthal, H. (2006). Polarized America: The dance of ideology and unequal riches. London: MIT Press.
Moller, S., Huber, E., Stephens, J. D., Bradley, D., & Nielson, F. (2003). Determinants of relative poverty in advanced capitalist democracies. American Sociological Review, 68(1), 22–51.
Newman, K. S., & O’Brien, R. L. (2011). Taxing the poor: Doing damage to the truly disadvantaged. Berkeley: University of California Press.
Page, B. I., & Jacobs, L. R. (2009). Class war? What Americans really think about economic inequality. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Piven, F. F., & Cloward, R. A. (1988). Why American don’t vote. New York: Pantheon Books.
Piven, F. F., & Cloward, R. A. (2000). Why Americans still don’t vote and why politicians want it that way. Boston: Beacon.
Radcliff, B., & Saiz, M. (1998). Labor organization and public policy in the American states. Journal of Politics, 60(1), 113–125.
Rigby, E., & Springer, M. J. (2011). Does electoral reform increase (or decrease) political equality? Political Research Quarterly, 64(2), 420–434.
Rigby, E., & Wright, G. C. (2013). Political parties and representation of the poor in the American states. American Journal of Political Science, 57(3), 552–565.
Sides, J., Schickler, E., & Citrin, J. (2008). If everyone had voted, would Bubba and Dubya have won? Presidential Studies Quarterly, 38(3), 521–539.
Solt, F. (2008). Economic inequality and democratic political engagement. American Journal of Political, 52(1), 48–60.
Solt, F. (2010). Does economic inequality depress electoral participation? Testing the Schattschneider hypothesis. Political Behavior, 32(2), 285–301.
Soroka, S. N., & Wlezien, C. (2008). On the limits to inequality in representation. PS: Political Science and Politics, 41(2), 319–327.
Soroka, S. N., & Wlezien, C. (2010). Degrees of democracy: Politics, public opinion, and policy. New York: Cambridge University Press.
Stephens, J. D. (1979). The transition from capitalism to socialism. London: Macmillian.
Stimson, J. (1985). Regression in space and time: A statistical essay. American Journal of Political Science, 29(4), 914–947.
Stonecash, J. M., Brewer, M. D., & Mariani, M. D. (2002). Diverging parties: Social change, realignment, and political polarization. Boulder, CO: Westview Press.
Ura, J. D., & Ellis, C. R. (2008). Income, preferences, and the dynamics of policy responsiveness. PS: Political Science and Politics, 41(4), 785–794.
Western, B., & Rosenfeld, J. (2011). Unions, norms, and the rise in U.S. wage inequality. American Sociological Review, 76(4), 513–537.
Wilson, S. E., & Butler, D. M. (2007). A lot more to do: The sensitivity of time-series cross-sectional analysis to simple alternative specifications. Political Analysis, 15(2), 101–123.
Acknowledgments
An earlier version of this paper was presented at the 2014 meeting of the Midwest Political Science Association. I am grateful to Skylar Davidson for research assistance and Jeff Fine, Twyla Blackmond Larnel, Joal Lieske, Mark Peffley, Ramya Vijaya, the editors, and five reviewers for helpful comments on earlier drafts. All remaining errors are the author’s alone.
Author information
Authors and Affiliations
Corresponding author
Electronic supplementary material
Below is the link to the electronic supplementary material.
Rights and permissions
About this article
Cite this article
Avery, J.M. Does Who Votes Matter? Income Bias in Voter Turnout and Economic Inequality in the American States from 1980 to 2010. Polit Behav 37, 955–976 (2015). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11109-015-9302-z
Published:
Issue Date:
DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11109-015-9302-z