Skip to main content
Log in

How Compelling is Compulsory Voting? A Multilevel Analysis of Turnout

  • Original Paper
  • Published:
Political Behavior Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

In a recent contribution to Political Behavior (30:455–467), Panagopoulos, using aggregate turnout data, shows that individuals living under compulsory voting rules are most likely to go to the polls when penalties for abstaining are both strict and routinely enforced. In this project, I expand on the work of Panagopoulos by simultaneously examining both election-level and individual-level factors. I use a broad sample of 36 countries, some with compulsory voting and some with voluntary rules, which provides a more detailed understanding of the correlates of turnout. Results indicate that the presence and severity of compulsory rules do indeed affect turnout, while personally held characteristics, including age, education, income, and political efficacy remain critical to an individual’s turnout decision calculus.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Subscribe and save

Springer+ Basic
$34.99 /Month
  • Get 10 units per month
  • Download Article/Chapter or eBook
  • 1 Unit = 1 Article or 1 Chapter
  • Cancel anytime
Subscribe now

Buy Now

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Available at http://www.cses.org/.

  2. Available at http://www.idea.int/vt/.

  3. Question wording: “Some people say that no matter who people vote for, it won't make any difference to what happens. Others say that who people vote for can make a difference to what happens. Using the scale on this card, where would you place yourself?”.

  4. Available at http://www.worldbank.org/data.

  5. Available at http://www.freedomhouse.org.

  6. Available at http://www.cses.org/download/contributions/contributionsmirror.htm.

  7. I also opt to use the effective number of electoral parties rather than the effective number of parliamentary parties (ENPP). As noted by Benoit (2002), ENPP, which accounts for representation in parliament, is directly shaped by the electoral system. Because electoral rules are accounted for in the model, using the ENPP measure would be redundant.

  8. I also calculated this value for each individual within the district in which he or she resides, which allows for some within-election variation in the p term in Eq. 1. While this is coding decision better reflects reality, missing data on district-level election returns means the number of elections in the sample drops from 60 to 47 if it is used. Nevertheless, results are substantively very similar with this coding of the variable, and the closeness of the election itself fails to achieve statistical significance.

  9. Available at http://www.idea.int/vt/.

  10. I thank an anonymous reviewer for pointing this out.

  11. My control for wealth is slightly different than Panagopoulos, who uses GDP growth rather than per capita GDP, and my measure of electoral rules is also different, as I use district magnitude and Panagopoulos uses a trichotomous variable for majoritarian, mixed, and proportional systems.

  12. Each model was estimated in Stata 11 using the xtmelogit command. A Laplacian approximation was used to facilitate convergence. On a computer with a 1.6 GHz processor and 640 MB of RAM, each model took roughly 7 h to converge.

  13. In a logistic regression with coefficient b, the odds ratio is simply exp(b).

  14. The coefficient on presidential election across each model is roughly .70: thus, the odds ratio is exp(.67) = 2.014.

References

  • Banducci, S. A., & Karp, J. A. (2009). Electoral systems, efficacy, and voter turnout. In H.-D. Klingemann (Ed.), The comparative study of electoral systems (pp. 109–134). Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Benoit, K. (2002). The endogeneity problem in electoral studies: A critical re-examination of Duverger’s mechanical effect. Electoral Studies, 21, 35–46.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bernstein, R., Chadha, A., & Montjoy, R. (2001). Overreporting voting: Why it happens and why it matters. Public Opinion Quarterly, 65, 22–44.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Birch, S. (2008). Electoral institutions and popular confidence in electoral processes: A cross-national analysis. Electoral Studies, 77, 305–320.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blais, A. (2006). What affects voter turnout? Annual Review of Political Science, 9, 111–125.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blais, A., & Carty, R. K. (1990). Does proportional representation foster voter turnout? European Journal of Political Research, 18, 167–181.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blais, A., & Dobrzynska, A. (1998). Turnout in electoral democracies. European Journal of Political Research, 33, 239–262.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bratton, M., & Van De Walle, N. (1997). Democratic experiments in Africa: Regime transitions in comparative perspective. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dalton, R. J. (2008). Citizen politics: Public opinion and political parties in advanced industrial democracies. Washington, DC: CQ Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Downs, A. (1957). An economic theory of democracy. New York: Harper Collins.

    Google Scholar 

  • Endersby, J. W., & Krieckhaus, J. T. (2008). Turnout around the globe: The influence of electoral institutions on national voter participation, 1972–2000. Electoral Studies, 27, 601–610.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Inglehart, R. (1997). Modernization and postmodernization: Cultural, economic, and political change in 43 societies. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Jackman, R. W. (1987). Political institutions and voter turnout in the industrial democracies. American Political Science Review, 81, 405–423.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jackman, S. (2001). Compulsory voting. In N. J. Smelser & P. B. Baltes (Eds.), International encyclopedia of the social and behavioral sciences. Oxford: Elesvier.

    Google Scholar 

  • Jackman, R. W., & Miller, R. A. (1995). Voter turnout in the industrial democracies during the 1980s. Comparative Political Studies, 27, 467–492.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Karp, J. A., & Brockington, D. (2005). Social desirability and response validity: A comparative analysis of overreporting voter turnout in five countries. Journal of Politics, 67, 825–840.

    Google Scholar 

  • Laakso, M., & Taagepera, R. (1979). Effective number of parties: A measure with application to western Europe. Comparative Political Studies, 12, 3–27.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lijphart, A. (1984). Democracies: Patterns of majoritarian and consensus government in twenty-one countries. New Haven: Yale University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Long, J. S., & Freese, J. (2006). Regression models for categorical dependent variables using stata. College Station: Stata Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Martin, P. S. (2003). Voting’s rewards: Voter turnout, attentive publics, and congressional allocation of federal money. American Journal of Political Science, 47, 110–127.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Norris, P. (2004). Electoral engineering: Voting rules and political behavior. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Pacek, A., & Radcliff, B. (1995). Turnout and the vote for left-of-centre parties: A cross-national analysis. British Journal of Political Science, 25, 137–143.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Palfrey, T. R., & Rosenthal, H. (1983). A strategic calculus of voting. Public Choice, 41, 7–53.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Panagopoulos, C. (2008). The calculus of voting in compulsory voting systems. Political Behavior, 30, 455–467.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Powell, G. B. (1982). Comparative democracies: Participation, stability, and violence. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Riker, W., & Ordeshook, P. C. (1968). A theory of the calculus of voting. American Political Science Review, 62, 25–42.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Selb, P., & Lachat, R. (2009). The more, the better? Counterfactual evidence on the effect of compulsory voting on the consistency of party choice. European Journal of Political Research, 48, 573–597.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Verba, S., & Nie, N. H. (1972). Participation in America: Political democracy and social equality. New York: Harper & Row.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wielhouwer, P. W. (2000). Releasing the fetters: Parties and the mobilization of the African-American electorate. Journal of Politics, 62, 206–222.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Shane Singh.

Additional information

The author would like to thank three anonymous reviewers and the editors of Political Behavior for very constructive comments. The author would also like to thank Jason Roy and Judd Thornton.

Appendix: Adjustments for Overreporting

Appendix: Adjustments for Overreporting

Table 1 makes it clear that the percentage of individuals who reported voting generally exceeds officially reported turnout. Due to faulty recollection or social desirability, individuals often incorrectly report having participated in an election (Bernstein et al. 2001; Karp and Brockington 2005). If overreporting is indeed systematic, inferences drawn from individual-level turnout data will be biased.

Survey weights are generally used to correct for oversampling in a population. For example, imagine a population is 50% female and 50% male, but a sample taken by a researcher is 25% female and 75% male. To correct for this, each observation is weighted by its true population proportion divided by its observed sample proportion. In this example, each female in the sample is weighted with a value of 2 (50%/25%) and each male a value of 2/3 (50%/75%).

To correct for discrepancies between official and reported turnout, I use data on actual and reported turnout rates (see Table 1) to apply the same weighting strategy used to correct for oversampling. For example, in the 2005 Albanian election overreporting was very pronounced, with 91.5% of individuals claiming to have voted, while official turnout was only 59.6%. To correct for this disparity, each respondent who reported voting was assigned a weight of 59.6/91.5 ≈ .652, and each individual who reported abstaining was assigned a weight of 40.4/8.5 ≈ 4.75. I applied such weights to each individual in each election in the sample, effectively making reported turnout equivalent to official turnout. I re-estimated Models 3–5 of Table 3, this time accounting for inaccurate reporting with logistic regression models that weight each individual’s contribution to the results appropriately and account for the clustering of the individuals within elections.

The results of each re-estimation are given in Table 4. There is a near uniform increase in the significance levels of the macro-level variables. This is likely because the survey-weighted models do not explicitly model election-effects and thus may overstate the impact of the election-level variables. Nevertheless, it is again shown that compulsory rules, their severity, and their enforcement, boost turnout. It is also shown in Model A2 that enforcement of compulsory rules may affect turnout independent of sanctions; the fear of getting caught staying home may boost turnout propensity independent of the penalties for abstention. Finally, age, education, income, and efficacy again maintain a strong positive effect on turnout across each model.

Table 4 The correlates of individual-level turnout (with survey weights)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Singh, S. How Compelling is Compulsory Voting? A Multilevel Analysis of Turnout. Polit Behav 33, 95–111 (2011). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11109-010-9107-z

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11109-010-9107-z

Keywords

Navigation