Abstract
In the last decade considerable research in social sciences has focused on interpersonal trust, treating it as a remedy for most maladies modern democracies suffer from. Yet, if others act dishonestly, trust is turned into gullibility, thus mechanisms linking interpersonal trust with institutional success refer implicitly to honesty and civic morality. This paper investigates the roots of civic morality. It applies hierarchical models to data from 38 countries, and tests the individual, community and structural explanatory factors. The results of the analysis point to the relevance of an institutional dimension, both in the form of individuals’ perceptions as well as the quality of governance: confidence in political institutions and their objective quality are the strongest predictors of civic morality. At the same time, the findings show that the recently popular claims about the importance of social capital for citizens’ moral standards are largely unfounded.
Similar content being viewed by others
Explore related subjects
Discover the latest articles, news and stories from top researchers in related subjects.Notes
It should be noted here that cross-national individual-level research demonstrates a powerful self-selection effect, as people who join groups are already more trusting than the rest of the population (Stolle, 1998).
This is often called “institutional trust”, however, the significance of the distinction between trust and confidence in institutions is convincingly discussed by Hardin: “there is a widely held view that government needs the trust of citizens if it is to work well ... but the more recent view of the role of trust can make sense only if by trust is meant essentially confidence and, perhaps, some element of cooperativeness. Government might need this much if it is to gain citizen compliance with sometimes hard laws, such as those concerning taxes and conscription” (2000, p. 35, see also Offe, 1999).
It is possible that citizens perceive agency’s actions that are impartial, efficient and bring maximum benefit as legitimizing, but at the same time citizens who perceive the agency as legitimate (because, for example, they have voted it into power), will evaluate its performance more favorably. Either way, we expect a positive and reinforcing relationship between institutional performance and legitimacy, and thus a positive effect of performance and its perceptions on attitudes to compliance.
To explain circumstanced under which individuals are willing to break the rules and “quit the game”, Hibbing and Alford refer to people’s natural aversion to being “played for a sucker” (Hibbing & Alford, 2004).
While the argument about the causality of the link between cultural variables and institutional characteristics has not been definitely resolved, there is a growing body of literature supporting a “top-down” approach. See Freitag, 2006; Letki and Evans, 2005; Muller and Seligson, 1994; Rose-Ackerman, 2001a.
The sample of countries used results from the combination the availability of empirical indicators and a democratic character of a given country. Since some of the questions used were politically sensitive, data collected in countries without at least minimal guarantees of the freedom of speech could not be considered reliable. Therefore, only countries scoring 0 or higher on the Polity index were included in the final analysis.
The regions are based on the WVS sampling design, where random selection of sampling points was carried out, with a number of points being drawn from all administrative regional units after stratification by region and degree of urbanization. Therefore, 392 regions in this paper represent the existing administrative units.
See http://www.worldbank.org/data/.
Principal Investigators: Monty G. Marshall and Keith Jaggers, Project Director: Monty G. Marshall, Founding Director: Ted Robert Gurr. See http://www.cidcm.umd.edu/inscr/polity/.
See http://www.worldbank.org/wbi/governance/data.html.
The coding of all questions was reversed and “don’t know” answers were recoded to the middle of the scale (6). As a result, “always justifiable” was coded “1” and “never justifiable” was coded “11”.
A similar index using data from 1990 edition of the World Values Survey was called an “index of civic cooperation” by Knack and Keefer (1997). I believe that the index captures values (honesty) and attitudes (respect for law) rather than behavior, and while these values and attitudes may have a positive influence on cooperation, they do not necessary imply any cooperative activities. Therefore, I call it an “Index of Civic Morality”.
The question asked whether the respondent is an active or inactive member. However, preliminary analysis showed that pooling these two categories together does not produce results different than keeping them separately, therefore respondents were divided into two main groups: members and non-members.
Coding of the scale was reversed, so that “none at all” was coded as 1, and “don’t know” answers were recoded into the middle of the scale. Principal component analysis of those 6 items detected one dimension, explaining 51.8% of the total variance; the Cronbach’s Alpha for this scale is .684. For details, see Table 4 in the Appendix.
Education was coded into tree categories: “lower” (up to the level of elementary and basic vocational education), “medium” (secondary and intermediate education) and “upper” (higher education). For income, national income variables were recoded into three categories: “lower”, “middle” and “upper” so that each category would comprise of the third of the sample (Inglehart, Basanez, & Menendez Moreno, 1998).
Variable referring to religiosity captures frequency of participation in religious services and ranges from “never” (1) to more than once a week (7).
On the basis of his analysis of social capital Seligson argues convincingly that including established Western democracies in cross-national analysis often results in a serious bias and overestimation of the significance of tested relationships (Seligson, 2002).
Data entries for all indicators come from the year preceding the year in which survey was conducted in a given country. If the data for this specific year was unavailable, it was replaced by the earlier available entry. Entries for each country have been presented in Table 5 in the Appendix.
In the present sample of countries Moldova has the lowest level of unemployment, which is more likely to indicate slow pace of economic reforms than a particularly effective economy.
For the detailed information on the project, see http://www.worldbank.org/wbi/governance/index.html.
The proportion of total variance explained by variation at particular levels is also an estimate of intra-cluster correlations at these levels, which in this case are .073 at the country level and .152 at the regional level. This further confirms that there is asignificant degree of clustering within countries and regions, which should not be ignored.
Whether these variables are entered individually or as a “block” has no effect on the results.
The −2*log-likelihood decreased from 195528.600 (model 3.1) to 195347.200 (model 3.2), a difference of 181.4. This difference can be regarded as a χ2 value with 3 degrees of freedom (three new parameters), and as such it is highly statistically significant.
References
Anderson, C. J., & Tverdova, Y. V. (2003). Corruption, political allegiances, and attitudes toward government in contemporary democracies. American Journal of Political Science, 47, 91–109.
Bohnet, I., Frey, B. S., & Huck, S. (2001). More order with less law: On contract enforcement, trust, and crowding. American Political Science Review, 95, 131–144.
Braithwaite, V., & Braithwaite, J. (2001). An evolving compliance model for tax enforcement. In: N. Shover, & J. P. Wright (Eds.), Crimes of privilege. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Brehm, J., & Rahn, W. (1997). Individual-level evidence for the causes and consequences of social capital. American Journal of Political Science, 41, 999–1023.
Bryk, A. S., & Raudenbush, S. W. (1993). Hierarchical linear models: Applications and data analysis methods. Newbury Park: Sage.
Espinal, R., Hartlyn, J., & Kelly, J. M. (2006). Performance still matters. Explaining trust in government in the dominican republic. Comparative Political Studies, 39, 200–223.
Freitag, M., (2006). Bowling the state back in: Political institutions and the creation of social capital. European Journal of Political Research, 45, 123–152.
Fukuyama, F. (1995). Trust. The social virtues and the creation of prosperity London: Hamish Hamilton.
Hardin, R. (1993). The street-level epistemology of trust. Politics & Society, 21, 505–529.
Hibbing, J. R., & Alford, J. R. (2004). Accepting authoritative decisions: Humans as wary cooperators. American Journal of Political Science, 48, 62–76.
Huysseune, M., (2003). Institutions and their impact on social capital and civic culture: The case of Italy. In: M. Hooghe, & D. Stolle (Eds.), Generating social capital: Civil society and institutions in comparative perspective. New York: Palgrave Macmillan.
Inglehart, R. (1999). Trust, well-being and democracy. In: M. E. Warren (Ed.), Democracy and trust. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Inglehart, R., Basanez, M., & Menendez Moreno, A. (1998). Human values and beliefs: A cross-cultural sourcebook: Political, religious, sexual, and economic norms in 43 societies. Findings from the 1990–1993 World values survey. Ann Arbor, MI: University of Michigan Press.
Jackman, R. W., & Miller, R. A. (1998). Social capital and politics. Annual Review of Political Science, 1, 47–73.
Katz, L., Levitt, S. D., & Shustorovich, E. (2003). Prison conditions, capital punishment, and deterrence. American Law and Economics Review, 5, 318–343.
Knack, S., & Keefer, P. (1997). Does social capital have an economic payoff? A cross-country investigation. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 62, 1251–1288.
Kotkin, S., & Sajó, A. (Eds.), (2002). Political corruption in transition. A sceptic’s handbook. Budapest: CEU Press.
Letki, N., & Evans, G. (2005). Endogenizing social trust: Democratisation in east-central Europe. British Journal of Political Science, 35, 515–529.
Levi, M. (1997). Consent, dissent, and patriotism. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Levi, M. (1998). A state of trust. In: V. Braithwaite, & M. Levi (Eds.), Trust and governance. New York: Russell Sage Foundation.
Levi, M., & Stoker, L. (2000). Political trust and trustworthiness. Annual Review of Political Science, 3, 475–507.
Lind, E. A., & Tyler, T. R. (1988). The social psychology of procedural justice. New York: Plenum Press.
Marsh, C. (2000). Social capital and democracy in Russia. Communist and Post-Communist Studies, 33, 183–199.
McAllister, I. (1999). The economic performance of governments. In: P. Norris (Ed.), Critical citizens : Global support for democratic government. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Muller, E. N., & Seligson, M. A. (1994). Civic culture and democracy: The question of causal relationships. American Political Science Review, 88, 635–652.
Murphy, K. (2004). The role of trust in nurturing compliance: A study of accused tax avoiders. Law and Human Behavior, 28, 187–209.
Newton, K., & Norris, P. (2000). Confidence in public institutions: Faith, culture or performance?. In: S. J. Pharr, & R. D. Putnam (Eds.), Disaffected democracies: What’s troubling the trilateral countries? Princeton: Princeton University Press.
Offe, C. (1999). How can we trust our fellow citizens? In: M. Warren (Ed.), Democracy and trust. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Orviska, M., & Hudson, J. (2002). Tax evasion, civic duty and the law abiding citizen. European Journal of Political Economy, 19, 83–102.
Paxton, P. (2002). Social capital and democracy: An interdependent relationship. American Sociological Review, 67, 254–277.
Pharr, S. J., & Putnam, R. D. (Eds.), (2000). Disaffected democracies: What’s troubling the trilateral countries? Princeton: Princeton University Press.
Porta, R. L., Lopez-de-Silanes, F., Shleifer, A., & Vishny, R. (1999). The quality of government. The Journal of Law, Economics, & Organization, 15, 222–279.
Putnam, R. D. (1993). Making democracy work: Civic traditions in modern Italy. Princeton: Princeton University Press.
Putnam, R. D. (1995a). Bowling alone: America’s declining social capital. Journal of Democracy, 6, 65–78.
Putnam, R. D. (1995b). Tuning in, tuning out: The strange disappearance of social capital in America. Political Science and Politics, 28, 664–683.
Putnam, R. D. (2000). Bowling alone. The collapse and revival of American community. New York: Simon and Schuster.
Rose-Ackerman, S. (1999). Corruption and government. Causes, consequences, and reform. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Rose-Ackerman, S. (2001a), Trust and honesty in post-socialist societies. KYKLOS, 54, 415–444.
Rose-Ackerman, S. (2001b), Trust, honesty, and corruption: reflection on the state-building process. Archives of European Sociology, XLII, 27–71.
Rothstein, B. (2000). Trust, social dillemmas and collective memories. Journal of Theoretical Politics, 12, 477–501.
Rothstein, B., & Stolle, D. (2001). Social capital and street-level bureaucracy: An institutional theory of generalized trust. Paper presented at the ESF Conference “Social capital: Interdisciplinary perspectives”. Exeter UK, September 15–20, 2001.
Rothstein, B., & Stolle, D. (2003). Social capital, impartiality and the welfare state: An institutional approach. In: M. Hooghe, & D. Stolle (Eds.), Generating social capital. Civil society and institutions in comparative perspective. New York: Palgrave Macmillan.
Scholz, J. T. (1998). Trust, taxes, and compliance. In: V. Braithwaite, & M. Levi (Eds.), Trust and governance. New York: Russell Sage Foundation.
Scholz, J. T., & Lubell, M. (1998). Trust and taxpaying: Testing the heuristic approach to collective action. American Journal of Political Science, 42, 398–417.
Seligson, M. A. (2002). The renaissance of political culture or the renaissance of the ecological fallacy? Comparative Politics, 34, 273–292.
Steenbergen, M. R., & Jones, B. S. (2002). Modeling multilevel data structures. American Journal of Political Science, 46, 218–237.
Steinmo, S. (1993). Taxation and democracy. New Haven: Yale University Press.
Stolle, D. (1998). Bowling together, bowling alone: The development of generalised trust in voluntary associations. Political Psychology, 19, 1467–1488.
Tulchin, J. S., & Espach, R. H. (Eds.), (2000). Combating Corruption in Latin America. Washington, D.C.: Woodrow Wilson Center Press.
Tyler, T. R. (1990). Why people obey the law. New Haven: Yale University Press.
Tyler, T. R. (1998). Trust and democratic governance. In: V. Braithwaite, & M. Levi (Eds.), Trust and governance. New York: Russell Sage Foundation.
Tyler, T. R. (2006). Psychological perspectives on legitimacy and legitimation. Annual Review of Psychology, 57, 375–400.
Uslaner, E. M. (1999a). The moral foundations of trust. New York: Cambridge University Press.
Uslaner, E. M. (1999b). Morality plays. Social capital and moral behaviour in Anglo-American democracies. In: J. W. v. Deth, M. Maraffi, K. Newton, & P. F. Whiteley (Eds.), Social capital and European democracy. London: Routledge.
Acknowledgements
This paper benefited from comments by Christina W. Andrews, Geoff Evans, Christopher Garner, Sharon Gilad, Jane Green, Mark A. Kayser, Lauren McLaren, Bo Rothstein, Chris Wlezien and participants of the “Quality of Government: What It Is, How to Get It, Why It Matters” Conference, Göteborg, November 17–19, 2005. I would also like to thank the three anonymous Reviewers and the Editors for their insightful comments.
Author information
Authors and Affiliations
Corresponding author
Appendix
Appendix
Rights and permissions
About this article
Cite this article
Letki, N. Investigating the Roots of Civic Morality: Trust, Social Capital, and Institutional Performance. Polit Behav 28, 305–325 (2006). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11109-006-9013-6
Published:
Issue Date:
DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11109-006-9013-6