Skip to main content
Log in

Government Size, Trade Openness, and Output Volatility: A Case of fully Integrated Economies

  • Research Article
  • Published:
Open Economies Review Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Government is often considered the safe sector of an open economy that provides households with insurance against external risk exposure. Among highly integrated economies, however, households should be able to exploit common financial markets to insure themselves. In this paper we examine the relationship between government size, trade openness, and output volatility across fully integrated economies using Japan’s regional income accounting and public finance data. The contributions of the government- and market-based insurances to inter-regional risk sharing are also estimated. The empirical results reveal some unique aspects of the state-market interactions under full economic integration with vertical fiscal imbalance.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Subscribe and save

Springer+ Basic
$34.99 /Month
  • Get 10 units per month
  • Download Article/Chapter or eBook
  • 1 Unit = 1 Article or 1 Chapter
  • Cancel anytime
Subscribe now

Buy Now

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Rodrik (2011) highlights the complementarity between market and state as an essential feature of the process of economic globalization.

  2. See Svaleryd and Vlachos (2002) for evidence on positive interdependence between trade liberalization and financial market development.

  3. An implicit assumption is that governments at the local level can function similarly to governments at the national level in provision of insurance and risk-sharing means. Nonetheless, we also note that the findings of this study may not be readily generalizable at the international level because the unique features of Japan’s fiscal system may not be shared by a fiscal union of sovereign states.

  4. It should be noted that, as Alesina and Wacziarg (1998) acknowledges, their account and Rodrik’s are not necessarily mutually exclusive.

  5. For evidence on Wagner’s law, see Abizadeh and Gray (1985), Ram (1987), and Brückner et al. (2012) among others.

  6. Differences in political accountability and electoral system can also generate variation in government size across countries (Persson and Tabellini 1999). However, for the intra-Japan investigation, they are unlikely to play a chief role.

  7. A recent study by Collard et al. (2017) uses a standard New-Keynesian model with multiple shocks to find that the relationship between volatility and government size can be non-monotonic, and hence, it may not be restricted to be negative. Specifically, the relationship can turn positive when government size exceeds a threshold so that the volatility amplification emanating from expenditure shocks dominates the volatility mitigation on other shocks.

  8. An important exception is the intra-US investigation of Fatás and Mihov (2001).

  9. See, for instance, Bordo et al. (2013).

  10. The prefectures are listed in Table 7 in the data Appendix. Within a prefecture there are municipalities (i.e. cities, towns, and villages) as smaller administrative units. For the remainder of this paper, the prefectural and municipal governments combined are referred to as the local government.

  11. See Ministry of Internal Affairs and Communications (2014) for details.

  12. Specifically, 32% of the income and alcohol tax revenue, 34% of the corporate tax revenues, 29% of the consumption tax revenue, and 25% of the tobacco tax revenue are used as a fund.

  13. The main usages of the NTD include social welfare payment, compulsory educational expenses, child-rearing support, recovery and reconstruction from earthquakes, and ordinary construction work expenses. The allocative decisions are made by the corresponding ministries within the central government.

  14. Consequently, both the local government consumption and investment expenditures contain the transfer payment as a financial source.

  15. Brückner and Tuladhar (2013) provides an empirical assessment of the spillover effects of local government spending in Japan.

  16. See Ministry of Internal Affairs and Communications (2014) for details.

  17. See Persson and Tabellini (1996) for more general analyses of moral hazard in a fiscal federation with two levels of government.

  18. While the Annual Report contains both nominal and real data, the real series have an advantage of being free from possible cross-prefectural difference in relative price of government purchases. We thus use the real data.

  19. The independent local revenue consists mostly of the prefectural and municipal tax revenues including those on the inhabitant tax, enterprise tax, local consumption tax, real estate acquisition tax, automobile tax, and fixed asset tax.

  20. We additionally run panel regressions to provide the estimates in the Appendix.

  21. The following prefectural GDP accounting identities hold: GDP ≡ private final consumption + government final consumption + gross capital formation (GCF) + export − import; GCF ≡ gross fixed capital formation (GFCF) + inventory changes; GFCF ≡ Gross fixed (GF) private capital formation + GF public capital formation (GFPCF); and GFPCF ≡ GF residential capital formation + GF business equipment capital formation + GF government capital formation.

  22. It is not possible to measure the extent of openness to international trade by prefecture because no data are available. Japan is among the countries that are least open to international trade with the trade-to-GDP ratio of only 24% on average for 1996–2009. The openness for inter-prefectural trade is far greater at approximately 133%. These suggest that trade vis-à-vis other prefectures has more significant implications for the prefectural economies and governments.

  23. For robustness, we also used the 2006–2007 averages for the dependent variable to remove possible effects of the 2008 world financial crisis. The results turn out to be qualitatively very similar, and hence, they are not reported to conserve space.

  24. Specifically, we divide the data into three sub-periods of 1996–2000, 2001–2005, and 2006–2009. The independent and dependent variables are measured, respectively, by the averages of the first three years and the following years of each sub-period to avoid endogeneity. The resulting panel (of three periods by forty-seven prefectures) is used for the estimations.

  25. The idea of the specialization index comes initially from Krugman (1991). The index he proposed uses the sectoral shares in employment rather than output and the absolute values instead of squares. We rely on the output data because the corresponding data on sectoral employment are not available. Kalemli-Ozcan et al. (2003) uses (2) to assess the extents of specialization within manufactures by limiting k to be manufacturing sub-sectors and defining y i to be total manufacturing output. In our intra-Japan context, products and services other than manufactures can also be tradable. Thus, we consider all sectors for k.

  26. In particular, access to integrated financial markets can have significant implications. In the international context, Kimakova (2009) finds that richer financially open economies tend to have smaller governments. Thus, our results are in part consistent with and complementary to the findings of the previous international studies, despite the apparent differences in the trade openness effect estimates.

  27. These component figures are available only in nominal series. Therefore, we take their ratios to the nominal GDP and deflate them by the prefectural GDP deflators.

  28. For implications of fiscal spending shocks in a monetary union, see Bénétrix and Lane (2010).

  29. The intra-US investigation of Fatás and Mihov (2001) avoids this endogeneity problem because their measure of the state government size is determined federally without endogenous responses to the state output fluctuations.

  30. The exercises conducted in section 5 do not require the sectoral output data. Thus, we report the estimates on the full sample including Okinawa prefecture.

  31. In addition to those cited in the main text, see Atkeson and Bayoumi (1993), von Hagen (1993), Bayoumi and Masson (1995), and Sørensen and Yosha (1998). von Hagen (2000) provides an excellent review of the literature.

  32. The European commission (1977) reports equally high or even higher estimates for France, Germany, and Italy.

  33. Kalemli-Ozcan et al. (2003) also estimates for 1975–1993 that about 97% of the idiosyncratic shocks in Japan are insured. While the contribution of capital market is estimated 21.6%, the breakdown between the fiscal and credit channels are not specified. Also, van Wincoop (1995) compares the risk sharing in Japan to that across the OECD countries via the metric of consumption correlations.

  34. The year specific constant term in (5) absorbs the effects that are common to all prefectures but vary by year.

  35. It is interesting to observe that our estimate also closely matches the share of debt in Japan’s total international assets estimated by Rogoff and Tashiro (2014).

References

  • Abizadeh S, Gray J (1985) Wagner’s law: a pooled time-series cross- section comparison. Natl Tax J 88:209–218

    Google Scholar 

  • Alesina A, Wacziarg R (1998) Openness, country size and government. J Public Econ 69:305–321

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Asdrubali P, Sørensen BE, Yosha O (1996) Channels of interstate risk sharing: United States 1963-1990. Q J Econ 111:1081–1110

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Atkeson A, Bayoumi T (1993) Do private capital markets insure regional risk? Evidence from the United States and Europe. Open Econ Rev 4:303–324

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Backus DK, Kehoe PJ, Kydland FE (1992) International real business cycles. J Polit Econ 100(4):745–775

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baldwin R, Harrigan J (2011) Zeros, quality, and space: trade theory and trade evidence. American Economic Journal: Microeconomics 3:60–88

    Google Scholar 

  • Bayoumi T, Masson PR (1995) Fiscal flows in the United States and Canada: lessons for monetary union in Europe. Eur Econ Rev 39:253–274

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Benarroch M, Pandey M (2012) The relationship between trade openness and government size: does disaggregating government expenditure matter? J Macroecon 34:239–252

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bénétrix A, Lane PR (2010) Fiscal shocks and the sectoral composition of output. Open Econ Rev 21:335–350

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bordo MB, Jonung L, Markiewicz A (2013) A fiscal union for the euro: some lessons from history. CESifo Economic Studies 59:449–488

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brückner M, Tuladhar A (2013) Local government spending multipliers and financial distress: evidence from Japanese prefectures. Economic Journal 124:1279–1316

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brückner M, Chong A, Gradstein M (2012) Estimating the permanent income elasticity of government expenditures: evidence on Wagner’s law based on oil price shocks. J Public Econ 96:1025–1035

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Collard, F, Dellas H, Tavlas G (2017) Government size and macroeconomic volatility. Economica, forthcoming

  • Easterly W, Rebelo S (1993) Fiscal policy and economic growth: an empirical investigation. J Monet Econ 32:417–458

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • European Commission (1977) Report of the study group on the role of public finance in European integration, Vol. I and II, Studies: economic and financial series A13 and B13. Brussels

  • Fatás A (1998) Does EMU need a fiscal federation? Econ Policy 13:165–203

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fatás A, Mihov I (2001) Government size and automatic stabilizers: international and intranational evidence. J Int Econ 55:3–28

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Feldstein M, Horioka C (1980) Domestic saving and international capital flows. Economic Journal 90:314–329

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • French K, Poterba J (1991) International diversification and international equity markets. Am Econ Rev 81:222–226

    Google Scholar 

  • Fujiki H, Nakakuki M (2005) Asymmetric shocks and regional risk sharing: evidence from Japan. Monetary and Economic Studies 23:31–60

    Google Scholar 

  • Furceri D, Sacchi A, Salotti S (2016) Can fiscal decentralization alleviate government consumption volatility? Open Econ Rev 27:611–636

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Galí J (1994) Government size and macroeconomic stability. Eur Econ Rev 38:117–132

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hayashi F (1986) Why is Japan’s saving rate so apparently high? In: Fischer S (ed) NBER Macroeconomics Annual 1986, vol 1. MIT Press, Cambridge, pp 147–234

    Google Scholar 

  • Heller PS, Diamond J (1990) International Comparisons of Government Expenditure Revisited: The Developing Countries, 1975–1986 Occasional Paper, n 69. International Monetary Fund, Washington, D. C.

    Google Scholar 

  • Horioka CY (2012) Are Japanese households financially healthy, and if so why? A group of seven (G7) comparison. Discussion Paper No. 859. The Institute of Economic and Social Research, Osaka University

  • Kalemli-Ozcan S, Sørensen BE, Yosha O (2003) Risk sharing and industrial specialization: regional and international evidence. Am Econ Rev 93:903–918

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kimakova A (2009) Government size and openness revisited: the case of financial globalization. Kyklos 62:394–406

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Krugman P (1991) Geography and trade. MIT Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Ministry of Internal Affairs and Communications (2014) FY2012 Settlement: white paper on local Public Finance 2014

  • Oates WE (1972) Fiscal federalism. Harcourt Brace Jovanovich, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Oates WE (1999) An essay on fiscal federalism. J Econ Lit 37:1120–1149

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Obstfeld M, Peri G (1998) Regional nonadjustment and fiscal policy. Econ Policy 13:207–259

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Persson T, Tabellini G (1996) Federal fiscal constitutions: risk sharing and moral hazard. Econometrica 64:623–646

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Persson T, Tabellini G (1999) The size and scope of government: comparative politics with rational politician. Eur Econ Rev 43:699–735

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ram R (1987) Wagner’s hypothesis in time-series and cross-section perspectives: evidence from “real” data for 115 countries. Review of Economics and Statistics 69:194–204

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ram R (2009) Openness, country size, and government size: additional evidence from a large cross-country panel. J Public Econ 93:213–218

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rodrik D (1998) Why do more open economies have bigger governments? J Polit Econ 106(5):997–1032

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rodrik D (2011) The globalization paradox. W. W. Norton& Company, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Rogoff KS, Tashiro T (2014) Japan’s exorbitant privilege. RIETI Discussion Paper Series 14-E-047. The Research Institute of Economy, Trade and Industry

  • Sala-i-Martin X, Sachs J (1992) Fiscal federalism and optimum currency areas: evidence for Europe from the United States. In: Canzoneri MB, Grilli V, Masson PR (eds) Establishing a central bank: issues in Europe and lessons from the US. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Sato M (2002) Intergovernmental transfers, governance structure and fiscal decentralization. Japanese Economic Review 53(1):55–76

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shelton CA (2007) The size and composition of government expenditure. J Public Econ 91:2230–2260

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sørensen BE, Yosha O (1998) International risk sharing and European monetary unification. J Int Econ 45:211–238

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Svaleryd H, Vlachos J (2002) Markets for risk and openness to trade: how are they related? J Int Econ 57:369–395

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tait AA, Heller PS (1982) International Comparisons of Government Expenditure Occasional Paper, n 10. International Monetary Fund, Washington, D. C.

    Google Scholar 

  • van Wincoop E (1995) Regional risk sharing. Eur Econ Rev 39:1545–1567

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • von Hagen J (1993) Monetary union and fiscal union: a perspective from fiscal federalism. In: Masson PR, Taylor MP (eds) Policy issues in the operation of currency unions. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • von Hagen J (2000) Fiscal policy and intranational risk sgaring. In: Hess GD, van Wincoop E (eds) Intra-national Macro-economics. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

The author thanks three anonymous referees of this journal for helpful comments. All remaining errors are solely of the author’s. This research was supported by JSPS KAKENHI Grant Number 25285087.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Eiji Fujii.

Appendix

Appendix

1.1 Data sources

The data used in this study are obtained from the following two sources:

  • Annual Report on Prefectural Accounts 2012 CD-ROM, Department of National Accounts, Economic and Social Research Institute, Cabinet Office, Government of Japan.

  • Regional Statistics Database, Official Statistics of Japan.

Notes

Data on the disposable income (DI) are available only in nominal figures. We convert them into real series using the prefectural GDP deflators. Also, there are a couple of prefecture-specific incidents of missing observations. First, the observations on Tokyo’s DI are missing altogether. We obtain the 2001–2009 nominal figures from Tokyo Metropolitan Government’s site (http://www.toukei.metro.tokyo.jp). These figures are then converted into real terms using Tokyo’s GDP deflator. Secondly, Aichi prefecture’s export and import are available only in nominal figures. They are also converted into real series using Aichi’s prefectural GDP deflator.

1.2 Sectors for the specialization index

The specialization index in sub-section 4.2 is constructed by using the output data on the following sectors:

  1. A.

    Industries

  1. 1.

    Agriculture, forestry and fishing

1) Agriculture, 2) Forestry, 3) Fishing

  1. 2.

    Mining

  2. 3.

    Manufacturing

1) Food products and beverages, 2) Textiles, 3) Pulp, paper and paper products, 4) Chemicals, 5) Petroleum and coal products, 6) Non-metallic mineral products, 7) Primary metal, 8) Fabricated metal products, 9) Machinery, 10) Electrical machinery, equipment and supplies, 11) Transport equipment, 12) Precision instruments, 13) Others

  1. 4.

    Construction

  2. 5.

    Electricity, gas and water supply

1) Electricity supply, 2) Gas and water supply

  1. 6.

    Wholesale and retail trade

  2. 7.

    Finance and insurance

  3. 8.

    Real estate

  4. 9.

    Transport and communications

  5. 10.

    Service activities

  1. B.

    Producers of government services

  1. 1.

    Electricity, gas and water supply

  2. 2.

    Service activities

  3. 3.

    Public administration

  1. C.

    Producers of private non-profit services to households

  1. 1.

    Service activities

1.3 Inter-prefectural distance

The inter-prefectural distance is measured by the geographical distance between the prefectural capitals using the program provided by the Geospatial Information Authority of Japan, Ministry of Land, Infrastructure, Transport and Tourism.

Table 7

Table 7 List of the prefectures

Table 8

Table 8 Determinants of government size – Panel estimates

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Fujii, E. Government Size, Trade Openness, and Output Volatility: A Case of fully Integrated Economies. Open Econ Rev 28, 661–684 (2017). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11079-017-9433-4

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11079-017-9433-4

Keywords

JEL Classifications

Navigation