Abstract
The requirement of bottom-up action from all the countries to deal with climate change makes it necessary to analyze the factors influencing policy adoption. This article contributes to the policy literature by shedding light on the conditions, which incentivize countries to adopt more climate mitigation policies. The theoretical argument builds on the integrated approaches to study policy diffusion, which include both internal and external determinants as explanations for the adoption of policies. While previous applications typically operationalize the latter by regional proximity, this study highlights the added value of network dependencies capturing political and cooperative interactions across countries. The article finds that the adoption of climate policies is a matter of social influence. Countries are more likely to adopt policies if they cooperate with countries that have adopted more climate policies and are in a similar structural position to countries that are active in climate protection. This article not only is an important theoretical contribution to the policy literature but also enriches our methodological and empirical understanding of climate policy diffusion.
This is a preview of subscription content, access via your institution.
Notes
Mitigation policies usually relate to energy demand, supply, transportation, energy efficiency measures, reducing emissions from deforestation and forest degradation in developing countries (REDD +), etc.
See IPCC (2007), Chapter 11 for a more detailed discussion on this issue (https://www.ipcc.ch/publications_and_data/ar4/wg3/en/ch11.html).
Adaptation is a process by which individuals, communities and countries attempt to deal with the consequences of climate change, usually on a local level (Hasson et al. 2010).
Compare Leenders (2002) for an encompassing presentation of network autocorrelation models.
Compare Eq. 1: ADOPTit = f (INTit = (Mit + Rit + ADOPTit−1) + EXTit = (PROXi + NETit)).
An example of such a flagship or framework law will be Bulgaria’s Climate Change Mitigation Act. The act puts forward the principles of state policy for climate change, the rules relating to emissions trading and the modalities for financing green projects Nachmany et al. (2014).
Compare: Notre Dame's Environmental Change Initiative (ND-ECI) (2015). Notre Dame Global Adaptation Index (ND-GAIN) Available online: URL: http://index.gain.org/ranking/vulnerability.
The vulnerability component measures the extent to which a country is susceptible to the adverse effects of climate change. Specifically, it captures a country’s exposure to climate hazards, its sensitivity to climate impacts, and its adaptive capacity.
Compare ‘Appendix 4’ where we control for time-varying vulnerability indicators. The results do not change.
Data on CO2 emissions, fossil fuel consumption, and party governments are taken from the Quality of Government Standard Dataset 2018 (Teorell et al. 2018).
In addition to these models, in 'Appendix 4', we present a number of robustness checks. We estimated a number of models testing other covariates, variable combinations, interaction effects, and models using different time slices. Overall, our results are robust across these models.
Marrakech Accords. Available at: http://unfccc.int/cop7/.
References
Abbott, A., & DeViney, S. (1992). The welfare state as transnational event: Evidence from sequences of policy adoption. Social Science History, 16(02), 245–274. https://doi.org/10.1017/S0145553200016473.
Bates, D., Mächler, M., Bolker, B., & Walker, S. (2015). Fitting linear mixed-effects models using lme4. Journal of Statistical Software. https://doi.org/10.18637/jss.v067.i01.
Bättig, M. B., & Bernauer, T. (2009). National institutions and global public goods. Are democracies more cooperative in climate change policy? International Organization, 63(02), 281–308. https://doi.org/10.1017/s0020818309090092.
Beck, N., Gleditsch, K. S., & Beardsley, K. (2006). Space is more than geography: Using spatial econometrics in the study of political economy. International Studies Quarterly, 50, 27–44.
Bennett, C. J. (1991). What is policy convergence and what causes it? The British Journal of Political Science, 21(02), 15. https://doi.org/10.1017/S0007123400006116.
Bernauer, T. (2013). Climate change politics. Annual Review of Political Science, 16, 421–448.
Bernstein, S., & Cashore, B. (2012). Complex global governance and domestic policies. Four pathways of influence. International Affairs, 88(3), 85–604. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1468-2346.2012.01090.x.
Berry, F. S., & Berry, W. D. (1990). State lottery adoptions as policy innovations. An event history analysis. The American Political Science Review, 84(2), 395–415. https://doi.org/10.2307/1963526.
Berry, F. S., & Berry, W. D. (2007). Innovation and diffusion models in policy research. In P. Sabatier (Ed.), Theories of the policy process. Boulder: Westview Press.
Berry, F. S., & Berry, W. D. (2014). Innovation and diffusion models in policy research. In P. A. Sabatier & C. M. Weible (Eds.), Theories of the policy process (3rd ed., pp. 307–362). Boulder, CO: Westview Press.
Biesenbender, S., & Tosun, J. (2014). Domestic politics and the diffusion of international policy innovations. How does accommodation happen? Global Environmental Change, 29, 424–433. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.gloenvcha.2014.04.001.
Braun, D., & Gilardi, F. (2006). Taking ‘Galton’s problem’ seriously. Journal of Theoretical Politics, 18(3), 298–322. https://doi.org/10.1177/0951629806064351.
Canon, B. C., & Baum, L. (1981). Patterns of adoption of tort law innovations: An application of diffusion theory to judicial doctrines. American Political Science Review, 75(04), 75–987. https://doi.org/10.2307/1962297.
Chyzh, O. (2016). Dangerous liaisons. Journal of Peace Research, 53(3), 409–423. https://doi.org/10.1177/0022343316629605.
Clémençon, R. (2016). The two sides of the Paris climate agreement. The Journal of Environment & Development, 25(1), 3–24. https://doi.org/10.1177/1070496516631362.
Dimitrov, R. (2010). Inside Copenhagen. The state of climate governance. Global Environmental Politics, 10(2), 18–24.
Dolšak, N. (2001). Mitigating global climate change: Why are some countries more committed than others? Policy Studies Journal, 29(3), 414–436. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1541-0072.2001.tb02102.x.
Dolšak, N. (2009). Climate change policy implementation. A cross-sectional analysis. Review of Policy Research, 26(5), 51–570.
Dolšak, N. (2013). Climate change policies in the transitional economies of Europe and Eurasia. The role of NGOs. Voluntas, 24(2), 382–402. https://doi.org/10.1007/s11266-012-9260-6.
Dorussen, H., & Ward, H. (2010). Trade networks and the Kantian peace. Journal of Peace Research, 47(1), 29–42. https://doi.org/10.1177/0022343309350011.
Du Robiou Pont, Y., Jeffery, M. L., Gütschow, J., Rogelj, J., Christoff, P., & Meinshausen, M. (2017). Equitable mitigation to achieve the Paris Agreement goals. Nature Climate Change, 7(1), 38–43. https://doi.org/10.1038/nclimate3186.
Dunlap, R. E., McCright, A. M., & Yarosh, J. H. (2016). The political divide on climate change: Partisan polarization widens in the U.S. Environment: Science and Policy for Sustainable Development, 58(5), 4–23. https://doi.org/10.1080/00139157.2016.1208995.
Eisenack, K., Edenhofer, O., & Kalkuhl, M. (2012). Resource rents. The effects of energy taxes and quantity instruments for climate protection. Energy Policy, 48, 159–166. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.enpol.2012.05.001.
Elkins, Z., & Simmons, B. (2005). On waves, clusters, and diffusion. A conceptual framework. The ANNALS of the American Academy of Political and Social Science, 598(1), 3–51. https://doi.org/10.1177/0002716204272516.
Fankhauser, S., Gennaioli, C., Collins, M. (2014). Domestic dynamics and international influence: What explains the passage of climate change legislation. Centre for Climate Change Economics and Policy (Working Paper No. 175). http://www.lse.ac.uk/GranthamInstitute/wp-content/uploads/2014/05/Wp156-Domestic-dynamics-and-international-influence-what-explains-the-passage-of-climate-change-legislation.pdf. Accessed 23 Mar 2017.
Franzese, R. J., & Hays, J. C. (2007). Spatial econometric models of cross-sectional interdependence in political science panel and time-series-cross-section data. Political Analysis, 15(02), 140–164. https://doi.org/10.1093/pan/mpm005.
Gilardi, F. (2005). The institutional foundations of regulatory capitalism: The diffusion of independent regulatory agencies in Western Europe. The ANNALS of the American Academy of Political and Social Science, 598(1), 4–101. https://doi.org/10.1177/0002716204271833.
Gilardi, F. (2010). Who learns from what in policy diffusion processes? American Journal of Political Science, 54(3), 50–666.
Gilardi, F. (2012). Transnational diffusion. Norms, ideas, and policies. In T. Risse & B. Simmons (Eds.), Handbook of International Relations (pp. 453–477). Thousand Oaks: SAGE Publications.
Gilardi, F., & Füglister, K. (2008). Empirical modeling of policy diffusion in federal states. The dyadic approach. Swiss Political Science Review, 14(3), 13–450.
Graham, C. R., Woodfield, W., & Harrison, J. B. (2013). A framework for institutional adoption and implementation of blended learning in higher education. The Internet and Higher Education, 18, 4–14. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.iheduc.2012.09.003.
Grantham Research Institute, London School of Economics. (2016). Global climate legislation database. http://www.lse.ac.uk/GranthamInstitute/Legislation. Checked on 12/28/2016.
Gray, V. (1973). Innovation in the States: A Diffusion Study. American Political Science Review, 67(04), 1174–1185. https://doi.org/10.2307/1956539.
Haim, D. A. (2016). Alliance networks and trade. Journal of Peace Research, 53(3), 72–490. https://doi.org/10.1177/0022343316630938.
Hardin, G. (1968). The tragedy of the commons. Science, 162(3859), 1243–1248. https://doi.org/10.1126/science.162.3859.1243.
Hasson, R., Löfgren, Å., & Visser, M. (2010). Climate change in a public goods game: Investment decision in mitigation versus adaptation. Ecological Economics, 70(2), 331–338. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ecolecon.2010.09.004.
Hirschi, C. (2008). Event data analysis applied to environmental policy. In 104th Annual Meeting of the American Political Science Association, Boston, MA, 28–31 August 2008.
Hirschi, C. (2009). Intervening against apartheid. The South Africa Policy of the United States, West Germany, Sweden and Switzerland, 1977–1996. University of Zürich, Zürich.
Holzinger, K., & Knill, C. (2005). Causes and conditions of cross-national policy convergence. Journal of European Public Policy, 12(5), 775–796. https://doi.org/10.1080/13501760500161357.
IPCC. (2007). Climate change 2007. In Core Writing Team, R.K. Pachauri, & A. Reisinger (Eds.), Synthesis report. Contributions of working groups I, II, and III to the fourth assessment report of the intergovernmental panel on climate change, Geneva, Switzerland.
Jänicke, M. (2005). Trend-setters in environmental policy: The character and role of pioneer countries. European Environment., 15(2), 129–142. https://doi.org/10.1002/eet.375.
Jochem, E., & Madlener, R. (2003). The forgotten benefits of climate change mitigation: Innovation, technological leapfrogging, employment, and sustainable development. Paris: OECD Workshop on the Benefits of Climate Policy: Improving Information for Policy Makers.
Jordan, A. J., Huitema, D., Hildén, M., van Asselt, H., Rayner, T. J., Schoenefeld, J. J., et al. (2015). Emergence of polycentric climate governance and its future prospects. Nature Climate Change, 5(11), 977–982. https://doi.org/10.1038/NCLIMATE2725.
Jordan, A., Wurzel, R., Zito, A. R., & Brückner, L. (2005). European govnernance and the transfer of ‘new’ environmental policy instruments (NEPIs) in the European Union. In A. Jordan (Ed.), Environmental policy in the European Union. Actors, institutions, and processes (2nd ed., pp. 317–335). Sterling, VA: Earthscan.
Kammerer, M., & Hirschi, C. (2015). Policy networks and belief systems. The drivers of cooperation in international climate change politics 2001–2014. In Conference Proceeding, MPSA Chicago, April 2015.
Karch, A. (2007). Emerging issues and future directions in state policy diffusion research. State Politics & Policy Quarterly, 7(1), 54–80. https://doi.org/10.1177/153244000700700104.
Keohane, R. O. (1984). After hegemony. Cooperation and discord in the world political economy. Princeton, N.J: Princeton University Press.
Kern, K., Jörgens, H., & Jänicke, M. (2001). The diffusion of environmental policy innovations: A contribution to the globalisation of environmental policy. Discussion Paper FS II 01 - 302, Wissenschaftszentrum Berlin für Sozialforschung, Berlin.
Knill, C., & Liefferink, D. (2007). Environmental politics in the European Union. Policy-making, implementation and patterns of multi-level governance. Manchester, New York, N.Y: Manchester Univ Press Palgrave.
Knill, C., Shikano, S., & Tosun, J. (2014). Explaining environmental policy adoption: A comparative analysis of policy developments in twenty-four OECD countries. In A. Duit (Ed.), State and environment. The comparative study of environmental governance (pp. 3–80). Cambridge, MA: MIT Press (American and comparative environmental policy).
Leenders, R. (2002). Modeling social influence through network autocorrelation. Constructing the weight matrix. Social Networks, 24(1), 1–47. https://doi.org/10.1016/s0378-8733(01)00049-1.
Leifeld, P., & Cranmer, S. J. (2016). Temporal and cross-sectional network autocorrelation models (TNAM). ftp://cran.r-project.org/pub/R/web/packages/tnam/tnam.pdf. Checked on 12/30/2016.
Liefferink, D., Arts, B., Kamstra, J., & Ooijevaar, J. (2009). Leaders and laggards in environmental policy: A quantitative analysis of domestic policy outputs. Journal of European Public Policy, 16(5), 677–700. https://doi.org/10.1080/13501760902983283.
Madden, N. J. (2014). Green means stop: Veto players and their impact on climate-change policy outputs. Environmental Politics, 23(4), 570–589. https://doi.org/10.1080/09644016.2014.884301.
Maoz, Z., Kuperman, R. D., Terris, L., & Talmud, I. (2006). Structural equivalence and international conflict. A social networks analysis. Journal of Conflict Resolution, 50(5), 664–689. https://doi.org/10.1177/0022002706291053.
Marin, A., & Wellman, B. (2011). Social network analysis: An introduction. In J. Scott & P. J. Carrington (Eds.), The Sage handbook of social network analysis. London: Thousand Oaks.
Massey, E., Biesbroek, R., Huitema, D., & Jordan, A. (2014). Climate policy innovation: The adoption and diffusion of adaptation policies across Europe. Global Environmental Change, 29, 434–443. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.gloenvcha.2014.09.002.
Matisoff, D. C. (2008). The adoption of state climate change policies and renewable portfolio standards. Regional diffusion or internal determinants? Review of Policy Research, 25(6), 527–546. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1541-1338.2008.00360.x.
Matisoff, D. C., & Edwards, J. (2014). Kindred spirits or intergovernmental competition? The innovation and diffusion of energy policies in the American states (1990–2008). Environmental Politics, 23(5), 795–817. https://doi.org/10.1080/09644016.2014.923639.
Meseguer, C., & Gilardi, F. (2009). What is new in the study of policy diffusion? Review of International Political Economy, 16(3), 27–543. https://doi.org/10.1080/09692290802409236.
Mohrenberg, S. (2017). Studying policy diffusion with stochastic actor-oriented models. In B. Hollstein, W. Matiaske, & K.-U. Schnapp (Eds.), Networked governance. New research perspectives (pp. 163–188). Cham, s.l.: Springer.
Mozumder, P., Flugman, E., & Randhir, T. (2011). Adaptation behavior in the face of global climate change: Survey responses from experts and decision makers serving the Florida Keys. Ocean and Coastal Management, 54(1), 37–44. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ocecoaman.2010.10.008.
Nachmany, M., Fankhauser, S., Townshend, T., Collins, M., Landesman, T., Matthews, A., et al. (2014). The GLOBE Climate legislation study: A review of climate change legislation in 66 countries (4th ed.). London: GLOBE International and Grantham Research Institute, London School of Economics.
Nemet, G. F., Holloway, T., & Meier, P. (2010). Implications of incorporating air quality co-benefits into climate change policymaking. Environmental Research Letters, 5, 1–9. https://doi.org/10.1088/1748-9326/5/1/014007.
Neumayer, E. (2002). Do democracies exhibit stronger international environmental commitment? A cross-country analysis. Journal of Peace Research, 39(2), 139–164. https://doi.org/10.1177/0022343302039002001.
Neumayer, E. (2003). Are left-wing party strength and corporatism good for the environment? Evidence from panel analysis of air pollution in OECD countries. Ecological Economics, 45(2), 203–220. https://doi.org/10.1016/S0921-8009(03)00012-0.
Neumayer, E., & Plümper, T. (2016). W. PSRM, 4(01), 175–193. https://doi.org/10.1017/psrm.2014.40.
Oberthür, S. & Tänzer, D. (2002). International regimes as a trigger of policy diffusion: The development of climate policies in the European Union. In F. Biermann, R. Brohm, & K. Dingwerth (Eds.), Proceedings of the 2001 Berlin Conference on the Human Dimensions of Global Environmental Change. Global Environmental Change and the Nation Sate (PIK Report, 80) (pp. 317–328).
Ostrom, E. (2012). Nested externalities and polycentric institutions: Must we wait for global solutions to climate change before taking actions at other scales? Economic Theory, 49(2), 353–369. https://doi.org/10.1007/s00199-010-0558-6.
Plümper, T., & Schneider, C. J. (2009). The analysis of policy convergence, or: How to chase a black cat in a dark room. Journal of European Public Policy, 16(7), 990–1011. https://doi.org/10.1080/13501760903226724.
Regens, J. L. (1980). State policy responses to the energy issue: An analysis of innovation. Social Science Quarterly, 61(1), 4–57.
Rogers, E. M. (1983). Diffusion of innovations. New York: Free Press.
Schrodt, P. A. (2012). Precedents, progress, and prospects in political event data. International Interactions, 38(4), 546–569. https://doi.org/10.1080/03050629.2012.697430.
Schrodt, P. A., & Gerner, D. J. (1994). Validity assessment of a machine-coded event data set for the middle east, 1982–92. American Journal of Political Science, 38(3), 825–854. https://doi.org/10.2307/2111609.
Simmons, B. A., & Elkins, Z. (2004). The globalization of liberalization. Policy diffusion in the international political economy. APSR, 98(01), 171–189. https://doi.org/10.1017/s0003055404001078.
Spash, C. L. (2016). This changes nothing: The paris agreement to ignore reality. Globalizations, 13(6), 928–933. https://doi.org/10.1080/14747731.2016.1161119.
Teorell, J., Dahlberg, S., Holmberg, S., Rothstein, B., Alvarado Pachon, N., & Svensson, R. (2018). QoG Standard Dataset 2018.
The World Bank. (2017). World development indicators. https://datacatalog.worldbank.org/dataset/world-development-indicators. Checked on 5/7/2018.
Betzold, C., Castro, P., & Weiler, F. (2012). AOSIS in the UNFCCC negotiations from unity to fragmentation. Climate Policy, 12(5), 91–613.
Blaxekjær, L. Ø., & Nielsen, T. D. (2014). Mapping the narrative positions of new political groups under the UNFCCC. Climate Policy. https://doi.org/10.1080/14693062.2014.965656.
Blühdorn, I. (2012). Introduction: International climate politics beyond the Copenhagen disaster. European Political Science, 11, 1–6.
Brenton, A. (2013). ‘Great Powers’ in climate politics. Climate Policy, 13(5), 541–546. https://doi.org/10.1080/14693062.2013.774632.
Gupta, J. (2010). A history of international climate change policy. WIREs Climate Change, 1(5), 36–653. https://doi.org/10.1002/wcc.67.
Thurston, G. D. (2013). Mitigation policy. Health co-benefits. Nature Climate change, 3(10), 863–864. https://doi.org/10.1038/nclimate2013.
Tobin, P. (2017). Leaders and laggards: Climate policy ambition in developed states. Global Environmental Politics, 17(4), 28–47. https://doi.org/10.1162/GLEP_a_00433.
Tol, R. S. J., Klein, R. J. T., & Nicholls, R. J. (2008). Towards successful adaptation to sea-level rise along Europe’s coasts. Journal of Coastal Research, 242, 432–442. https://doi.org/10.2112/07A-0016.1.
True, J., & Mintrom, M. (2001). Transnational networks and policy diffusion: The case of gender mainstreaming. International Studies Quarterly, 45(1), 27–57.
Tubi, A., Fischhendler, I., & Feitelson, E. (2012). The effect of vulnerability on climate change mitigation policies. Global Environmental Change, 22(2), 472–482. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.gloenvcha.2012.02.004.
Volden, C., Ting, M. M., & Carpenter, D. P. (2008). A formal model of learning and policy diffusion. American Political Science Review, 102(3), 319–332.
Wasserman, S., & Faust, K. (1994). Social network analysis. Methods and applications. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Wejnert, B. (2002). Integrating models of diffusion of innovations: A conceptual framework. Annual Review of Sociology, 28(1), 297–326. https://doi.org/10.1146/annurev.soc.28.110601.141051.
Wurzel, R., & Connelly, J. (Eds.). (2011). The European Union as a leader in international climate change politics. Workshop. London: Routledge.
Acknowledgements
We are grateful to Laurence Brandenberger, Paul Wagner, and our anonymous reviewers for supporting this analysis by providing valuable discussion and critique on how to improve this paper. In addition, we thank Markus Schwarzbauer for editing this text.
Funding
This work was supported by the Swiss National Science Foundation (Grant No. 137808)
Author information
Authors and Affiliations
Corresponding author
Appendices
Appendix 1: country list and coding
Country name | UN country code | Status in UNFCCC | Gain vulnerability rank | Policy adoption | |||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
t1 | t2 | t3 | t4 | ||||
United Arab Emirates | ARE | Non-Annex I | 34 | 0 | 0 | 1 | 1 |
Argentina | ARG | Non-Annex I | 44 | 1 | 5 | 0 | 3 |
Australia | AUS | Annex I | 1 | 1 | 1 | 1 | 8 |
Austria | AUT | Annex I | 17 | 1 | 2 | 0 | 5 |
Belgium | BEL | Annex I | 59 | 4 | 2 | 0 | 3 |
Bangladesh | BGD | Non-Annex I | 143 | 1 | 0 | 2 | 4 |
Bulgaria | BGR | Non-Annex I | 39 | 3 | 1 | 2 | 3 |
Belarus | BLR | Annex I | 53 | 1 | 4 | 2 | 3 |
Bolivia | BOL | Non-Annex I | 79 | 1 | 0 | 1 | 4 |
Brazil | BRA | Non-Annex I | 23 | 2 | 4 | 3 | 3 |
Canada | CAN | Annex I | 2 | 1 | 0 | 1 | 4 |
Switzerland | CHE | Annex I | 12 | 2 | 0 | 1 | 3 |
Chile | CHL | Non-Annex I | 23 | 3 | 0 | 3 | 6 |
China | CHN | Non-Annex I | 28 | 1 | 1 | 0 | 5 |
Democratic Republic of Congo | COD | Non-Annex I | 161 | 0 | 0 | 0 | 4 |
Colombia | COL | Non-Annex I | 42 | 2 | 1 | 0 | 5 |
Costa Rica | CRI | Non-Annex I | 65 | 1 | 0 | 3 | 4 |
Cuba | CUB | Non-Annex I | 82 | 1 | 1 | 1 | 0 |
Czech Rep | CZE | Annex I | 18 | 2 | 0 | 0 | 2 |
Germany | DEU | Annex I | 13 | 3 | 3 | 2 | 5 |
Denmark | DNK | Annex I | 14 | 0 | 1 | 4 | 2 |
Dominican Republic | DOM | Non-Annex I | 109 | 2 | 1 | 1 | 2 |
Algeria | DZA | Non-Annex I | 69 | 3 | 3 | 0 | 6 |
Ecuador | ECU | Non-Annex I | 74 | 0 | 0 | 1 | 4 |
Egypt | EGY | Non-Annex I | 75 | 2 | 3 | 0 | 15 |
Spain | ESP | Annex I | 15 | 1 | 0 | 0 | 3 |
Ethiopia | ETH | Non-Annex I | 146 | 0 | 0 | 1 | 8 |
European Union | EU | Annex I | 0 | 6 | 0 | 10 | 8 |
Finland | FIN | Annex I | 10 | 2 | 1 | 0 | 4 |
France | FRA | Annex I | 9 | 1 | 2 | 1 | 5 |
Gabon | GAB | Non-Annex I | 86 | 0 | 0 | 0 | 4 |
United Kingdom | GBR | Annex I | 3 | 6 | 4 | 2 | 10 |
Ghana | GHA | Non-Annex I | 126 | 1 | 1 | 0 | 5 |
Greece | GRC | Annex I | 32 | 2 | 2 | 0 | 7 |
Grenada | GRD | Non-Annex I | 91 | 0 | 1 | 0 | 4 |
Guatemala | GTM | Non-Annex I | 119 | 1 | 0 | 1 | 2 |
Guyana | GUY | Non-Annex I | 135 | 0 | 0 | 1 | 0 |
Hungary | HUN | Annex I | 42 | 0 | 0 | 3 | 4 |
Indonesia | IDN | Non-Annex I | 87 | 0 | 3 | 8 | 9 |
India | IND | Non-Annex I | 115 | 3 | 4 | 1 | 2 |
Ireland | IRL | Annex I | 19 | 3 | 2 | 1 | 6 |
Iran (Islamic Republic of) | IRN | Non-Annex I | 53 | 1 | 1 | 2 | 4 |
Israel | ISR | Non-Annex I | 56 | 2 | 0 | 0 | 6 |
Italy | ITA | Annex I | 23 | 8 | 5 | 3 | 7 |
Jamaica | JAM | Non-Annex I | 94 | 1 | 0 | 1 | 2 |
Jordan | JOR | Non-Annex I | 101 | 1 | 0 | 0 | 2 |
Japan | JPN | Annex I | 27 | 3 | 1 | 0 | 2 |
Kazakhstan | KAZ | Non-Annex I | 30 | 1 | 2 | 1 | 1 |
Kenya | KEN | Non-Annex I | 148 | 0 | 1 | 1 | 2 |
Republic of Korea | KOR | Non-Annex I | 32 | 0 | 1 | 1 | 3 |
Kuwait | KWT | Non-Annex I | 103 | 1 | 0 | 0 | 0 |
Morocco | MAR | Non-Annex I | 91 | 0 | 0 | 2 | 6 |
Madagascar | MDG | Non-Annex I | 160 | 0 | 0 | 0 | 2 |
Maldives | MDV | Non-Annex I | 0 | 0 | 0 | 0 | 0 |
Mexico | MEX | Non-Annex I | 47 | 1 | 2 | 0 | 4 |
Myanmar | MMR | Non-Annex I | 134 | 0 | 0 | 0 | 1 |
Mongolia | MNG | Non-Annex I | 76 | 1 | 2 | 0 | 5 |
Mozambique | MOZ | Non-Annex I | 145 | 0 | 0 | 4 | 4 |
Malaysia | MYS | Non-Annex I | 31 | 0 | 1 | 0 | 4 |
Nigeria | NGA | Non-Annex I | 130 | 0 | 1 | 0 | 3 |
Netherlands | NLD | Annex I | 49 | 3 | 2 | 0 | 2 |
Norway | NOR | Annex I | 4 | 1 | 0 | 1 | 3 |
Nepal | NPL | Non-Annex I | 131 | 1 | 0 | 0 | 1 |
New Zealand | NZL | Annex I | 5 | 5 | 0 | 0 | 0 |
Pakistan | PAK | Non-Annex I | 111 | 0 | 0 | 0 | 8 |
Peru | PER | Non-Annex I | 71 | 3 | 1 | 2 | 7 |
Philippines | PHL | Non-Annex I | 95 | 1 | 2 | 3 | 6 |
Poland | POL | Annex I | 22 | 1 | 1 | 2 | 3 |
Portugal | POR | Annex I | 45 | 1 | 3 | 0 | 4 |
Romania | ROU | Annex I | 84 | 2 | 1 | 0 | 7 |
RUSSIA | RUS | Annex I | 6 | 2 | 0 | 4 | 2 |
Rwanda | RWA | Non-Annex I | 168 | 1 | 0 | 0 | 4 |
Saudi Arabia | SAU | Non-Annex I | 63 | 0 | 0 | 1 | 1 |
Singapore | SGP | Non-Annex I | 40 | 4 | 0 | 0 | 3 |
El Salvador | SLV | Non-Annex I | 118 | 0 | 2 | 0 | 2 |
Slovakia | SVK | Annex I | 37 | 1 | 3 | 2 | 8 |
Sweden | SWE | Annex I | 11 | 1 | 0 | 2 | 5 |
Thailand | THA | Non-Annex I | 70 | 0 | 2 | 1 | 7 |
Tajikistan | TJK | Non-Annex I | 102 | 0 | 1 | 1 | 1 |
Trinidad and Tobago | TTO | Non-Annex I | 66 | 0 | 2 | 0 | 3 |
Turkey | TUR | Annex I | 41 | 0 | 4 | 0 | 3 |
Tuvalu | TUV | Non-Annex I | 0 | 0 | 1 | 0 | 1 |
Tanzania | TZA | Non-Annex I | 140 | 0 | 0 | 0 | 3 |
Uganda | UGA | Non-Annex I | 166 | 1 | 1 | 0 | 1 |
Ukraine | UKR | Annex I | 50 | 3 | 1 | 0 | 1 |
United States of America | USA | Annex I | 7 | 0 | 3 | 4 | 5 |
Uzbekistan | UZB | Non-Annex I | 62 | 0 | 0 | 1 | 1 |
Venezuela | VEN | Non-Annex I | 38 | 0 | 1 | 1 | 1 |
Vietnam | VNM | Non-Annex I | 117 | 0 | 3 | 0 | 7 |
Vanuatu | VUT | Non-Annex I | 156 | 1 | 0 | 0 | 0 |
South Africa | ZAF | Annex I | 51 | 0 | 0 | 2 | 2 |
Appendix 2: coding of event types
Event types nominal | Event types | Description | Event dummy |
---|---|---|---|
Positive statement | 1 | Optimistic or emphatic comments, symbolic acts, express accord, consider policy option, acknowledge responsibility | Cooperation |
Concrete action | 2 | Consult, make or host a visit, meet, mediate, negotiate, discuss | Cooperation |
Appeal positive action | 3 | Appeal for material cooperation (economic, judicial, information), diplomatic cooperation, aid, political reform, to yield (e.g., easing sanctions, dissent), to negotiate, to settle dispute, to mediate | Cooperation |
Intend positive action | 4 | Express intends to engage in material cooperation (economic, judicial, information), diplomatic cooperation, aid, political reform, to yield (e.g., easing sanctions, dissent), to negotiate, to settle dispute, to mediate | Cooperation |
Yield cooperation | 5 | Ease sanctions, political dissent, agree on political reform | Cooperation |
Substantive cooperation | 6 | Provide aid or engage in material cooperation (economic, judicial, information, intelligence), engage in diplomatic cooperation (praise or endorse, rally support on behalf of, grant diplomatic recognition, apologize, forgive, sing agreement) | Cooperation |
Negative statement | − 1 | Decline or make pessimistic comment, deny responsibility | Conflict |
Demand cooperation | − 2 | Demand for material cooperation (economic, judicial, information), diplomatic cooperation, aid, political reform, to yield (e.g., easing sanctions, dissent), to negotiate, to settle dispute, to mediate | Conflict |
Criticize, accuse, disapprove | − 3 | Disapprove, criticize, accuse, rally opposition against, complain officially, lawsuit, find guilty or liable | Conflict |
Reject cooperation, veto | − 4 | Reject material cooperation (economic, judicial, information), diplomatic cooperation, aid, political reform, plant, proposal, to yield (e.g., easing sanctions, dissent), to negotiate, to settle a dispute, to mediate. Defy norms, laws, and to veto | Conflict |
Threaten | − 5 | Threaten to reduce or stop aid, with sanctions, boycott, embargo, with political dissent or repression, to halt negotiations or mediation. Give ultimatum | Conflict |
Substantial conflict | − 6 | Protest, strike, or boycott, engage in political dissent. Reduce relations, stop material aid, halt negotiations or mediations, impose an embargo, boycott, or strike and coerce and assault | Conflict |
Appendix 3: Time periods
T1: Negotiating the Kyoto protocol (1995–2004)
The first (t1) period is characterized by events leading to the ratification of the Kyoto protocol. The release of the first report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change’s (IPCC) in 1990 was integral to the drafting of the UNFCCC in 1992. The UNFCCC consequently came into force 2 years later during the year 1994. The predominant key principles enshrined in the Climate Convention are the North–South divide and the principle of ‘Common but Differentiated Responsibilities and Respective Capabilities (CBDR/RC).’ It distinguishes between Annex I countries (with greater historical responsibility and capability to combat climate change) and non-Annex I countries with relatively less (or no) such responsibility or capability to combat climate change (Blaxekjær and Nielsen 2014). However, the UNFCCC did not contain binding or specific targets and brought to the fore the need for a more stringent agreement. Consequently, the first Conference of Parties (COP-1) was expected to take strong action leading to the adoption of the Berlin Mandate whose focus was to promote legally binding reduction commitments intended to be adopted at COP-3 in 1997 at Kyoto (Gupta 2010). The adoption of the Berlin Mandate ultimately led to countries becoming a party to the UNFCCC and adopting what came to be known as the Kyoto protocol. The Kyoto protocol was the first internationally binding treaty that contained provisions for developed country parties to take up legally binding emissions targets for period 2008–2012. Unfortunately, enforcing the ratification was much more difficult than expected with the USA, which was a key player in the negotiations, pulling out in 2001. However, parties tried to salvage the effects of the USA pulling out of the Kyoto protocol during the negotiations in Bonn in 2001 leading to the adoption of the Marrakech accords.Footnote 11 The Marrakech Accords set the rules for implementing the Kyoto protocol and detailed the flexibility mechanisms such as the Joint Implementation (JI), Emissions Trading and Clean Development Mechanisms (Betzold et al. 2012). This hallmark phase in the climate policy architecture ends with the entering into force of the Kyoto protocol on February 16, 2005.
T2: Implementing the Kyoto protocol (2005–2007)
During the second period (t2), the most important issues were to implement the Kyoto protocol and to negotiate its successor. With respect to the institutional framework conditions, two important milestones must be mentioned: (1) the adoption of the Bali Road Map in 2007, which paved the way for a post-2012 agreement, and (2) the release of the IPCC’s Fourth Assessment Report in 2007, which brought the climate change issue on top of the international agenda. It instilled great enthusiasm among the parties ahead of COP 15 in Copenhagen with respect to agreeing on a new international legally binding agreement and a second commitment period of the Kyoto protocol. This period is also significant due to the fact that the CDM witnessed a growth and increasing focus on adaptation-related issues (Gupta 2010).
T3: Post-bali enthusiasm (2008–2009)
The high expectations in the run-up to the Copenhagen (COP-15) summit are an important characteristic of period three (t3). However, they remained unfulfilled due to the parties failing to agree on a legally binding follow-up agreement to the Kyoto protocol. With the Copenhagen Accord, the parties only submitted non-binding emission reduction to be implemented at a later point in time. In general, this phase started with high political and public attention toward the climate change issue because of the release of the fourth IPCC report and former US Vice-President and environmentalist Al Gore winning the Nobel Peace Prize in 2007. It, unfortunately, ended with disappointment over the ‘Copenhagen disaster’ (Blühdorn 2012). Similar to the previous phase, the static North–South divide between countries positions remained, with developing countries and emerging economies seeing themselves as having little (or no) responsibility as well as the capability to combat climate change.
T4: Toward a new agreement (2010–2015)
Period 4 (t4) spans from 2010 to 2015. It started with the adoption of the Cancun Agreements in 2010, which advanced important mechanisms such as the Green Climate Fund, the Technology Mechanism, and the Cancun Adaptation Framework. Despite the failure of the Copenhagen conference in 2009, countries continued negotiating with the goal to achieve a legally binding international treaty that is applicable to all parties and comes into effect from 2020. Negotiations on the design of the agreement mainly took place under the Ad hoc Working Group on the Durban Platform for Enhanced Action (ADP). Its main goals were to achieve progress toward implementing clear mitigation contributions by all parties and assisting parties to adapt to a changing climate (Blaxekjær and Nielsen 2014). The time after COP-15 brought a proliferation of institutions and arrangements under the umbrella of the UNFCCC. Moreover, it also called for a reinterpretation and questioning of the UNFCCC key principles, as well as a rearrangement of country groups (Blaxekjær and Nielsen 2014; Brenton 2013). The divide now remained between three main antagonistic camps. The emerging powers stuck to the key principle of CBDR/RC and the North–South divide. They demanded that industrialized countries must carry the heavier burden, as they are historically responsible and are comparatively more capable in combatting climate change. Alongside a broad range of vulnerable (least) developing countries, the EU pressed for sharp emission reductions and called for joint action of all involved countries. In this perspective, all parties must take action and adopt national contributions. The USA and other developed nations such as Russia and Canada were more reluctant to accept legally binding emission reductions. However, due to the new bottom-up approach, where each country now adopts its own legally binding contributions in contrast to the top-down formulated targets of the Kyoto protocol, negotiations finally led to the Paris Agreement being adopted in 2015.
Appendix 4: Robustness checks
In the following, we present a number of robustness checks. Table 5 presents the parameter estimates (presented as coefficients) with standard errors in parentheses for a number of pooled models, i.e., negative binomial regression models that do not control for period fixed effects. Model 1 includes all internal determinants. Model 2 also comprises the same region variable that operationalizes regional proximity. The results are robust to those presented in the paper. Model 3 includes instead of the ND-Gain vulnerability Index two different vulnerability indicators, namely the percentage of agricultural land and the forest area from the total land area of a country. Both variables are taken from the Quality of Governance dataset 2018. In contrast to the ND-Gain index, which reflects the same vulnerability level for all periods, these variables vary of over time. Both indicator variables are not significant just as the vulnerability variable taken from the ND-Gain index, and the model results do not change. We are therefore confident to include the ND-Gain Index into our model as an effective operationalization of country vulnerability. In Model 4, we include the network autocorrelation terms. We find that both terms are not significant and positive, whereas the Same Region variable is still significant. In Model 5 and 6, the Same Region variable is removed. Model 7 controls for the time-lagged versions of the network autocorrelation terms (i.e., NETit−1), but the estimates are not significant. Model 8 includes interaction terms for all relevant covariates interacting with the Cooperative Interaction network autocorrelation variable. These interaction terms indicate if the effects of the respective covariates (i.e., CO2 pc emissions, GDP pc, Vulnerability, and the level of democracy) interact with the intensity of cooperation between two countries. The parameter estimates related to these four interaction terms are all not significant. Finally, Model 9 controls for structural effects of the political interaction networks. In-Degree centrality (i.e., the number of political interactions reflecting the popularity of a country) and Betweenness centrality (i.e., the number of times a country is the link between a pair of countries that are themselves not interacting) are measures for the centrality a country in the political network. The larger the number the more central and powerful an actor is in the network. The terms control whether countries that are more central in the political network adopt more climate policies. The Cliques term captures whether countries that are closely connected in subgroups adopt more climate policies. Thus, all these network statistics test whether the structural position of a country in a political network affects its policy adoption behavior. However, the variables are all not significant.
Table 6 presents the results for the fixed effects models with the exact same model setup. The results are more or less unchanged.
Finally, Table 7 presents the results for different periods with the exact same model setup. For this purpose, we created a version of the dataset with only two periods. In the alternative dataset, the first phase spans from 1995 to 2009 and reflects the developments prior to the Copenhagen summit. The second phase (2010–2015) covers the negotiations ultimately leading to the adoption of the Paris Agreement. We decided to split the dataset into these two phases, as the failure of the Copenhagen summit in 2009 remarked an important hallmark of international climate change politics and we expect different causalities for the later period. In fact, the presented results underpin this assumption. The outcomes show no significant effects for most of the independent variables. In particular, the typical internal determinants explaining climate policy adoption, such as the level of democracy, GDP, or population size do not matter anymore. Instead, countries that have adopted more policies prior to Copenhagen (Policy Adoption t−1) more often also adopted new policies later on. We also find that countries with high per capita emissions have adopted fewer policies. With respect to the autocorrelation terms, we see that in the two period setup countries adopt more policies if they have interacted (Cooperative Interactions) in the past (t−1) with others that have adopted more policies. This means that cooperation prior to Copenhagen affected the policy adoption behavior after Copenhagen.
Appendix 5: marginal effects

Rights and permissions
About this article
Cite this article
Kammerer, M., Namhata, C. What drives the adoption of climate change mitigation policy? A dynamic network approach to policy diffusion. Policy Sci 51, 477–513 (2018). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11077-018-9332-6
Published:
Issue Date:
DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11077-018-9332-6
Keywords
- Climate change
- Social network analysis
- Policy diffusion
- Cooperation
- Temporal network autocorrelation model