Abstract
In recent years, there has been remarkable progress in our understanding of policy persistence, on the one hand, and of the psychological phenomenon of underreaction, on the other. Surprisingly, there has been no attempt to use robust findings, derived from these efforts, in order to understand the nuances of policy underreaction. Policy underreaction refers to systematically slow and/or insufficient response by policymakers to increased risk or opportunity, or no response at all. This article tries to give the concept of policy underreaction a robust analytical identity by integrating cognitive, social, psychological and emotional variables in the explanation of policy underreaction and by introducing a variation across different types of contextual sources of policy persistence as explanatory variables of this phenomenon. It develops an analytical framework that revolves around two key elements of decision making in situations of risk unfolding over time: (1) policymakers’ underestimation and accurate estimation of increased risks and (2) intra- and extra-organizational sources of policy persistence. Based on these dimensions, the article identifies and illustrates four distinct modes of policy underreaction which reflect differences in the nature of implemented policy.
This is a preview of subscription content, access via your institution.
Notes
This article does not deal with situations of policy adjustment to constant risk, a reduction of risk and opportunities (such as scientific inventions).
I thank Raanan Sulitzeanu-Kenan for these formulations. Note that these formulations are equally applicable to policy overreaction, i.e., it may define any case of non-proportionate policy response, regardless of the level of activity. In this article, however, I delve into the mechanisms that generate different types of policy underreaction.
An example of the latter situation is LeBlanc et al. (2000) study which proposes that majority-rule legislatures will under-invest in public goods.
The same awareness of external constraints that exists in the case of forced underreaction exists also in a certain case of policy overreaction. In this case, rather than succumbing to constraints, policymakers deliberately ignore them, opting for overreaction no matter what. A reason for this may involve an adherence of policymakers to the Precautionary Principle, according to which even a small risk of a catastrophic outcome is enough to require a serious response (Sunstein 2007). A related explanation may be applied in cases other than worst-case scenarios, that is, when the likelihood and magnitude of risk is lower than that in worst-case scenarios (Sunstein 2007). It is based on the premises that responding to risk by policy underreaction, if perceived as such by the target populations, is not likely to change the status quo. The same outcome may be reasonably expected when policymakers respond in (what they perceive as) a proportionate manner, which may be wrongly perceived by the target populations as underreaction. By contrast, if policymakers aim at changing the status quo, policy overreaction at the core of the policy problem is likely to leave no room for interpretative error by the target populations regarding the intention of those who overreact.
A summary of Consultation in the Prime Minister’s Office, Tel Aviv, Yom Kippur, 6.10.1973, available (in Hebrew) at http://www.hativa14.org.il/?CategoryID=1040 (Accessed 16.6.2014).
References
Anderson, J. (2008). Fears that the Market Watchdog is Losing its Bite, New York Post, 8.4.2008.
Asch, S. (1952). Social psychology. New York: Prentice-Hall.
Bar-Hillel, M. (1973). On the subjective probability of compound events. Organizational Behavior and Human Performance, 9(3), 396–406.
Bar-Joseph, U. (2005). Watchman fell asleep: The surprise of Yom Kippur and its sources. New York: State University of New York Press.
Bar-Joseph, U. (2008). Strategic surprise or fundamental flaws? The sources of Israel’s military defeat at the beginning of the 1973 war. Journal of Military History, 72(2), 509–530.
Bar-Joseph, U., & Kruglanski, A. W. (2003). Intelligence failure and need for cognitive closure: On the psychology of the Yom Kippur surprise. Political Psychology, 24(1), 75–99.
Bar-Joseph, U., & McDermott, R. (2010). The Intelligence Analysis Crisis. In L. K. Johnson (Ed.), The Oxford Handbook of National Security Intelligence (pp. 359-374). Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Baumgartner, F. R., Breunig, C., Green-Pedersen, C., Jones, B. D., Mortensen, P. B., Nuytemans, M., et al. (2009). Punctuated equilibrium in comparative perspective. American Journal of Political Science, 53(3), 603–620.
Baumgartner, F. R., & Jones, B. D. (2009). Agendas and instability in American politics (2nd ed.). Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Bazerman, M. H., & Watkins, M. D. (2008). Predictable surprises: The disasters you should have seen coming, and how to prevent them. Boston, MA: Harvard Business School Press.
Boin, A., ‘t Hart, P., McConnell, A., & Preston, T. (2010). Leadership style, crisis response and blame management: The case of Hurricane Katrina. Public Administration, 88(3), 706–723.
Brändström, A., Kuipers, S., & Daléus, P. (2008). The politics of tsunami responses: Comparing patterns of blame management in Scandinavia. In A. Boin, A. McConnell, & P. ‘t Hart (Eds.), Governing after crisis: The politics of investigation, accountability and learning (pp. 114–147). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Bulkley, G., & Herrerias, R. (2005). Does the precision of news affect market underreaction? Evidence from returns following two classes of profit warnings. European Financial Management, 11(5), 603–624.
Cohen, J., Chesnick, E. I., & Haran, D. A. (1972). A confirmation of the inertial-Y effect in sequential choice and decision. British Journal of Psychology, 63, 41–46.
Comptroller, State. (2012). Report on the implementation of the National Security Council law and the handling of the Turkish Flotilla. Jerusalem: State Comptroller.
Crozier, M. (1964). The bureaucratic phenomenon. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Cunningham, L. A., & Zaring, D. T. (2009). The three or four approaches to financial regulation: A cautionary analysis against exuberance in crisis response. George Washington Law Review, 78, 39–113.
Daléus, P., & Hansén, D. (2011). Inherent ethical challenges in bureaucratic crisis management: The Swedish experience with the 2004 tsunami disaster. In L. Svedin (Ed.), Ethics and crisis management (pp. 21–36). Charlotte, NC: Information Age Publishing.
Davidoff, S. M., & Zaring, D. (2009). Regulation by deal: The government’s response to the financial crisis. Administrative Law Review, 61, 463–480.
Davis, J. (2009). Strategic warning: Intelligence support in a world of uncertainty and surprise. In L. K. Johnson (Ed.), handbook of intelligence studies (pp. 173–188). London: Routledge.
Dickert, S., & Slovic, P. (2009). Attentional mechanisms in the generation of sympathy. Judgment and Decision Making, 4(4), 297–306.
Dror, Y. (2012). The Flotilla as a “Simple Military Operation”, Haaretz, 18.6.2012, In Hebrew. http://www.haaretz.co.il/opinions/1.1733812. Accessed 16 June 2014.
Druckman, Y. (2010). Morning of Yom Kippur War: Cabinet rejects call for preemptive strike, Ynet Magazine. http://www.ynetnews.com/articles/0,7340,L-3965041,00.html. Accessed 16 June 2014.
Edelamn, M. (1977). The symbolic uses of politics. Urbana, IL: University of Illinois Press.
Fingar, T. (2011). Reducing uncertainty: Intelligence analysis and national security. Stanford: Stanford University Press.
Hacker, J. S., & Pierson, P. (2010). Drift and democracy: The neglected politics of policy inaction, Paper prepared for the 2010 meeting of the American Political Science Association, Washington, DC.
Hall, P. (1993). Policy paradigms, social learning, and the state: The case of economic policymaking in Britain. Comparative Politics, 25(3), 275–296.
Hammond, T. H. (1986). Agenda control, organizational structure, and bureaucratic politics. American Journal of Political Science, 30(2), 379–420.
Heimann, C. F. L. (1997). Acceptable risks: Politics, policy and risky technologies. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.
Helmke, G., & Levitsky, S. (2004). Informal institutions and comparative politics: A research agenda. Perspectives on Politics, 2(4), 725–740.
Hood, C. (2011). The blame game: Spin, bureaucracy, and self-preservation in government. Princeton: Princeton University Press.
Jones, B. D. (2001). Politics and the architecture of choice: Bounded rationality and governance. Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press.
Jones, B. D. (2003). Bounded rationality in political science: Lessons from public administration. Journal of Public Administration Research and Theory, 13, 395–410.
Jones, B. D., & Baumgartner, F. R. (2005a). The politics of attention: How government prioritizes problems. Chicago: The University of Chicago Press.
Jones, B. D., & Baumgartner, F. R. (2005b). A model of choice for public policy. Journal of Public Administration Research and Theory, 15, 325–351.
Kahneman, D. (2011). Thinking, fast and slow. New York: Farrar, Straus and Giroux.
King, G., Murray, C. J. L., Salomon, J. A., & Tandon, A. (2004). Enhancing the validity and cross-cultural comparability of measurement in survey research. American Political Science Review, 98, 191–207.
Knäuper, B., Kornik, R., Atkinson, K., Guberman, C., & Aydin, C. (2005). Motivational influences the underestimation of cumulative risk. Personality and Social Psychology Bulletin, 31(11), 1511–1523.
Knight, F. H. (1921). Risk, uncertainty and profit. Boston: Houghton Mifflin.
LeBlanc, W., Snyder, J., & Tripathi, M. (2000). Majority-rule bargaining and the under-provision of public investment goods. Journal of Public Economics, 75, 21–47.
Levy, J. S. (2008). Case studies: Types, designs, and the logics of inference. Conflict Management and Peace Science, 25, 1–18.
Maor, M. (2012). Policy overreaction. Journal of Public Policy, 32(3), 231–259.
Maor, M. (2014a). Policy bubbles: Policy overreaction and positive feedback. Governance, 27(3), 469–487.
Maor, M. (2014b). Policy anti-bubbles: Policy underreaction and self-sustaining processes. http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=2441670. Accessed 16 June 2014.
Maoz, Z. (2006). Defending the holy land: A critical analysis of Israel’s Security & Foreign Policy. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.
Marrin, S. (2011). Improving intelligence analysis: Bridging the gap between scholarship and practice. London: Routledge.
Marsh, D., & McConnell, A. (2010). Towards a framework for establishing policy success. Public Administration, 88(2), 564–583.
McConnell, A. (2010). Policy success, policy failure and grey areas in-between. Journal of Public Policy, 30(3), 345–362.
McConnell, A. (2011). Success? Failure? Something in-between? A framework for evaluating crisis management. Policy and Society, 30, 63–76.
McConnell, A. (2012). Public policy as inaction: The politics of doing nothing, Paper presented at the 62nd conference of the Political Studies Association Annual International Conference, Belfast, April.
Meir, G. (1975). My life. New York: G. P. Putnam’s Sons.
Meyer, J. W., & Rowan, B. (1977). Institutionalized organizations: Formal structure as myth and ceremony. American Journal of Sociology, 83(2), 340–363.
North, D. C. (1990). Institutions, institutional change and economic performance. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Nuder, P. (2008). Stolt men inte nöjd. Stockholm: Norstedts.
Oren, A. (2012). Who’s the boss? Echoes of the Yom Kippur war, Haaretz (English ed.). 14.6.2012, p. 7.
Peters, E. M., & Slovic, P. (2000). The springs of action: Affective and analytical information processing in choice. Personality and Social Psychology Bulletin, 26(12), 1465–1475.
Ritov, I., & Baron, J. (1995). Outcome knowledge, regret and omission bias. Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes, 64, 119–127.
Ross, L. (2013). Perspectives on disagreement and dispute resolution: Lessons from the lab and the real world. In E. Shafir (Ed.), The behavioral foundations of public policy (pp. 108–125). Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
Ross, L., & Nisbett, R. E. (1991). The person and the situation: Perspectives of social psychology. New York: McGraw-Hill.
Sabatier, P. A. (1988). An advocacy coalition model of policy change and the role of policy oriented learning therein. Policy Sciences, 21, 129–168.
Sakal, E. (2011). The regulars will hold? The missed opportunity to prevail in the defensive campaign in western Sinai in the Yom Kippur war. Tel Aviv: Ma’ariv Book Guild.
Simon, H. A. (1947). Administrative behavior: A study of decision-making processes in administrative organizations. New York: Macmillan.
Simon, H. A. (1957). Models of man, social and rational: Mathematical essays on rational human behavior in a social setting. New York: Wiley.
Slovic, P. (2007). “If i look at the mass i will never act”: Psychic numbing and genocide. Judgment and Decision Making, 2, 79–95.
Slovic, P. (2010). The more who die, the less we care. In E. Michael-Kerjan & P. Slovic (Eds.), The irrational economist: Decision making in a dangerous world (pp. 30–40). New York: Public Affairs Press.
Slovic, P., Peters, E., Finucane, M. L., & MacGregor, D. G. (2005). Affect, risk, and decision making. Health Psychology, 24, 35–40.
Spiegelhalter, D. (2011). Quantifying uncertainty. In L. Skinns, S. Michael, & T. Cox (Eds.), Risk (pp. 17–33). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Strömbäck, J., & Nord, L. W. (2006). Mismanagement, mistrust and missed opportunities: A study of the 2004 tsunami and swedish political communication. Media, Culture and Society, 28(5), 789–800.
Sunstein, C. R. (2007). Worst-case scenarios. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.
Sunstein, C. R. (2013). Misfearing is the problem, is cost benefit analysis the solution? In E. Shafir (Ed.), The behavioral foundations of public policy (pp. 231–244). Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
Swedish Tsunami Commission. (2005). Sweden and the Tsunami: Evaluation and Proposals. Stockholm.
‘t Hart P. (1993). Symbols, rituals and power: The lost dimensions of crisis management. Journal of Contingencies and Crisis Management, 1(1), 36–50.
‘t Hart P., Rosenthal, U., & Kouzmin, A. (1993). Crisis decision making: The centralization thesis revisited. Administration & Society, 25(1), 12–45.
Tosun, Jale. (2013). Environmental policy change in emerging market democracies—Central and Eastern Europe and Latin America compared. Toronto: University of Toronto Press.
Tsebelis, G. (2002). Veto players: How political institutions work. Princeton: Princeton University Press.
Tversky, A., & Kahneman, D. (1973). Availability: A heuristic for judging frequency and probability. Cognitive Psychology, 4, 207–232.
Tversky, A., & Kahneman, D. (1974). Judgment under uncertainty: Heuristics and biases. Science, 185, 1124–1131.
Tversky, A., & Kahneman, D. (1986). Rational choice and the framing of decisions. The Journal of Business, 59(4), 251–278.
U.S. Government Accounting Office (GAO). (2009). Financial markets regulation: Financial crisis highlights need to improve oversight of leverage at financial institutions and across system. http://www.gao.gov/products/GAO-09-739. Accessed 16 June 2014.
U.S. Securities and Exchange Commission. (2008). SEC’s Oversight of Bear Stearns and Related Entities: The Consolidated Supervised Entity Program, Report No. 446-A.
Walker, S. G., & Malici, A. (2011). U.S. presidents and foreign policy mistakes. Stanford: Stanford University Press.
Weible, C. M., Heikkila, T., deLeon, P., & Sabatier, P. A. (2012). Understanding and influencing the policy process. Policy Sciences, 45, 1–21.
Wildavsky, A. (1964). The politics of the budgetary process. Toronto: Little Brown.
Zeira, E. (2004). Myths versus reality: The October 1973 War—Failures and lessons [in Hebrew], Tel Aviv: Miskal.
Acknowledgments
Earlier versions of this article were presented at the 2013 Annual Conference of the Israeli Political Science Association, Jerusalem; the Political Science Departmental seminar, Hebrew University, Jerusalem; the 2013 International Conference on Public Policy, Grenoble, France; the 2013 Comparative Agendas Project Meeting, Antwerp, Belgium; and the CARR/LSE public policy group seminar, May 2014. I would like to thank Raanan Sulitzeanu-Kenan, Allan McConnell and numerous seminar audiences for very insightful comments. I also thank Eitan Shamir, Yossi Kuperwasser, Ran Segev, Issac Devash and Ron Tira for helpful discussions. I would also like to thank the Policy Sciences editors, and two anonymous reviewers, whose comments and suggestions helped me improve this article. The usual caveat applies.
Author information
Authors and Affiliations
Corresponding author
Rights and permissions
About this article
Cite this article
Maor, M. Policy persistence, risk estimation and policy underreaction. Policy Sci 47, 425–443 (2014). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11077-014-9203-8
Published:
Issue Date:
DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11077-014-9203-8