Policy Sciences

, Volume 45, Issue 2, pp 123–152 | Cite as

Overcoming the tragedy of super wicked problems: constraining our future selves to ameliorate global climate change

  • Kelly Levin
  • Benjamin Cashore
  • Steven Bernstein
  • Graeme Auld
Article

Abstract

Most policy-relevant work on climate change in the social sciences either analyzes costs and benefits of particular policy options against important but often narrow sets of objectives or attempts to explain past successes or failures. We argue that an “applied forward reasoning” approach is better suited for social scientists seeking to address climate change, which we characterize as a “super wicked” problem comprising four key features: time is running out; those who cause the problem also seek to provide a solution; the central authority needed to address it is weak or non-existent; and, partly as a result, policy responses discount the future irrationally. These four features combine to create a policy-making “tragedy” where traditional analytical techniques are ill equipped to identify solutions, even when it is well recognized that actions must take place soon to avoid catastrophic future impacts. To overcome this tragedy, greater attention must be given to the generation of path-dependent policy interventions that can “constrain our future collective selves.” Three diagnostic questions result that orient policy analysis toward understanding how to trigger sticky interventions that, through progressive incremental trajectories, entrench support over time while expanding the populations they cover. Drawing especially from the literature on path dependency, but inverting it to develop policy responses going forward, we illustrate the plausibility of our framework for identifying new areas of research and new ways to think about policy interventions to address super wicked problems.

Keywords

Wicked problems Super wicked problems Climate change Policy analysis Environmental governance Path dependency 

References

  1. Ackerman, F., & Heinzerling, L. (2004). Priceless: On knowing the price of everything and the value of nothing. New York: The New Press.Google Scholar
  2. Ainslie, G. W. (2001). Breakdown of will. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
  3. Arrow, K. J., Cropper, M. L., Eads, G. C., Hahn, R. W., Lave, L. B., Noll, R. G., et al. (1996). Is there a role for benefit-cost analysis in environmental, health, and safety regulation? Science, 272, 221–222.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  4. Arthur, W. B. (1989). Competing technologies, increasing returns, and lock-in by historical events. Economic Journal, 99(394), 116–131.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  5. Ascher, W. (2009). Bringing in the future: Strategies for farsightedness and sustainability in developing countries. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
  6. Barkin, J. S. (2006). Discounting the discount rate: Ecocentrism and environmental economics. Global Environmental Politics, 6(4), 56–72.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  7. Baumgartner, F., & Jones, B. (1993). Agendas and Instability in American Politics. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
  8. Bernstein, S., Lebow, R. N., Stein, J. G., & Weber, S. (2000). God gave physics the easy problems: Adapting social science to an unpredictable world. European Journal of International Relations, 6(1), 43–76.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  9. Betsill, M. M., & Hoffmann M. J. (2009). Constructing “Cap and Trade”: The evolution of emissions trading systems for greenhouse gases. Paper read at Paper prepared for the 2009 Open meeting of the human dimensions of global environmental change research community, at Bonn, Germany.Google Scholar
  10. Beyer, J. (2005). Not all path dependence is alike—A critique of the “implicit conservatism” of a common concept. Zeitschrift Fur Soziologie, 34(1), 5–21.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  11. Bigelow, J. (1982). A catastrophe model of organizational-change. Behavioral Science, 27(1), 26–42.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  12. California Air Resources Board. (2011). Proposed adaptive management plan for the cap-and-trade regulation. Sacremento: California Environmental Protection Agency.Google Scholar
  13. Campagnolo, I. (2007). Speech from the Throne delivered by The Honourable Iona Campagnolo, Lieutenant Governor, on the occasion of the opening of the third session, thirty-eighth parliament. Government of British Columbia, February 13 2007 [cited April 10 2010]. Available from http://www.leg.bc.ca/38th3rd/4-8-38-3.htm.
  14. Cashore, B., & Howlett, M. (2007). Punctuating which equilibrium? Understanding thermostatic policy dynamics in Pacific Northwest forest. American Journal of Political Science, 51(3), 532–551.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  15. Clemens, E. S., & Cook, J. M. (1999). Politics and institutionalism: Explaining durability and change. Annual Review of Sociology, 25, 441–466.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  16. Cowan, R. (1990). Nuclear-power reactors—A study in technological lock-in. Journal of Economic History, 50(3), 541–567.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  17. David, P. A. (1985). Clio and the economics of QWERTY. The American Economic Review, 75(2), 332–337.Google Scholar
  18. DeSombre, E. R. (2000). Domestic sources of international environmental policy: Industry, environmentalists, and US power, American and comparative environmental policy. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.Google Scholar
  19. Durrant, R. F., & Diehl, P. F. (1989). Agendas, alternatives, and public policy: Lessons from the US foreign policy arena. Journal of Public Policy, 9, 179–205.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  20. Elster, J. (2000). Ulysses unbound: Studies in rationality, precommitment, and constraints. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  21. Elster, J. (2002). Don’t burn your bridge before you come to it: Some ambiguities and complexities of precommitment. Texas Law Review, 81, 1751.Google Scholar
  22. Environmental Protection Agency. (2007). Individual Emissions.Google Scholar
  23. Ertman, T. (1997). Birth of the leviathan: Building states and regimes in medieval and early modern Europe. Cambridge, [Eng.]; New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
  24. Esty, D. C. (1994). Greening the GATT: Trade, environment, and the future (Vol. 16). Washington DC: Institute for International Economics.Google Scholar
  25. Frame, B., & Brown, J. (2008). Developing post-normal technologies for sustainability. Ecological Economics, 65(2), 225–241.Google Scholar
  26. Griffin, L. J. (1993). Narrative, event-structure analysis, and causal interpretation in historical sociology. American Journal of Sociology, 98(5), 1094–1133.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  27. Gunningham, N., & Sinclair, D. (1999). Integrative regulation: A principle-based approach to environmental policy. Law & Social Inquiry, 24(4), 853–896.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  28. Hacker, J. S. (1998). The historical logic of national health insurance: Structure and sequence in the development of British, Canadian, and US medical policy. Studies in American Political Development, 12(1), 57–130.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  29. Hacker, J. S. (2002). The divided welfare state: The battle over public and private social benefits in the United States. New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
  30. Hall, P. (1993). Policy paradigms, social learning and the state: The case of economic policy making and Britain. Comparative Politics, 25, 275–296.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  31. Hall, P. (2003). Aligning ontology and methodology in comparative politics. In J. Mahoney & D. Rueschemeyer (Eds.), Comparative historical analysis in the social sciences. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
  32. Hansen, J. (2006). Our planet’s keeper. New York: Review of Books.Google Scholar
  33. Hardin, G. (1968). The tragedy of the commons. Science, 162(3859), 1243–1248.Google Scholar
  34. Harrison, K. (2009). A tale of two taxes: The fate of environmental tax reform in Canada and the province of British Columbia. Toronto, Canada: In American Political Science Association.Google Scholar
  35. Herbig, P. A. (1991). A cusp catastrophe model of the adoption of an industrial innovation. Journal of Product Innovation Management, 8(2), 127–137.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  36. Hoffman, A. J. (2011). Talking past each other? Cultural framing of skeptical and convinced logics in the climate change debate. Organization & Environment, 24(1), 3–33.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  37. Howlett, M., & Ramesh, M. (1995). Studying public policy: Policy cycles and policy subsystems. New York: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
  38. IEA. (2011). Prospect of limiting the global increase in temperature to 2°C is getting bleaker. International Energy Agency 2011 [cited June 2011]. Available from http://www.iea.org/index_info.asp?id=1959.
  39. Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change. (2007). Summary for policymakers. In S. Solomon, D. Qin, M. Manning, Z. Chen, M. Marquis, K. B. Averyt, M. Tignor, & H. L. Miller (Eds.), Climate change 2007: The physical science basis. Contribution of working group I to the fourth assessment report of the intergovernmental panel on climate change. Cambridge, United Kingdom and New York, NY, USA: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
  40. Islas, J. (1997). Getting round the lock-in in electricity generating systems: The example of the gas turbine. Research Policy, 26(1), 49–66.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  41. Karp, L. (2005). Global warming and hyperbolic discounting. Journal of Public Economics, 89(2–3), 261–282.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  42. Kemp, R., Rip, A., & Schot, J. (2001). Constructing transition paths through the management of niches. In R. Garud & P. Karnoe (Eds.), Path dependence and creation. Mahwah, New Jersey and London: Lawrence Erlbaum Associates Inc.Google Scholar
  43. Kingdon, J. W. (1995). Agendas, alternatives, and public policies (2nd ed.). New York: HarperCollins College Publishers.Google Scholar
  44. Kysar, D. A. (2010). Regulating from nowhere: Environmental law and the search for objectivity. New Haven: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
  45. Lasswell, H. D. (1956). The decision process: Seven categories of functional analysis. College Park: Bureau of Governmental Research, University of Maryland Press.Google Scholar
  46. Lazarus, R. J. (2009). Super wicked problems and climate change: Restraining the present to liberate the future. Cornell Law Review, 94, 1153–1234.Google Scholar
  47. Levi, M. (1997). A model, a method and a map: Rational choice in comparative historical analysis. In M. I. Lichbach & A. S. Zuckerman (Eds.), Comparative politics: Rationality, culture and structure. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
  48. Levin, K., Cashore, B., Bernstein, S., & Auld, G. (2007). Playing it forward: Path dependency, progressive incrementalism, and the “super wicked” problem of global climate change. Paper presented at International studies association convention, Chicago, Il, February 28th–March 3.Lindblom, C. E. 1959. The Science of Muddling Through. Public Administration Review, 19(2), 79–88.Google Scholar
  49. Lindblom, C. E. (1959). The science of muddling through. Public Administration Review, 19(2), 79–88.Google Scholar
  50. Mahoney, J. (2000). Path dependence in historical sociology. Theory and Society, 29, 507–548.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  51. Maioni, A. (1999). Parting at the crossroads: The emergence of health insurance in the United States and Canada. New York: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
  52. March, J. G., & Olsen, J. P. (1996). Institutional perspectives on political institutions. Governance, 9(3), 247–264.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  53. Maréchal, K. (2010). Not irrational but habitual: The importance of “behavioural lock-in” in energy consumption. Ecological Economics, 69(5), 1104–1114.Google Scholar
  54. Maréchal, K., & Lazaric, N. (2010). Overcoming inertia: insights from evolutionary economics into improved energy and climate policies. Climate Policy, 10(1), 103–119.Google Scholar
  55. Marmor, T. (2007). Universal health insurance 2007: Can we learn from the past? Dissent. (Summer 2007).Google Scholar
  56. Mayhew, D. R. (2002). Electoral realignments: A critique of an American genre, The Yale ISPS series. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
  57. Meckling, J. (2011). Carbon coalitions: Business, climate politics, and the rise of emissions trading. Cambridge: MIT Press.Google Scholar
  58. Ministry of Small Business and Revenue. (2008). British Columbia carbon tax. Government of British Columbia, February 2008 [cited April 10 2010]. Available from http://www.sbr.gov.bc.ca/documents_library/notices/British_Columbia_Carbon_Tax.pdf.
  59. Mintzberg, H. (1978). Patterns in strategy formation. Management Science, 24(9), 934–948.Google Scholar
  60. Nelson, R. R., & Winter, S. G. (2002). Evolutionary theorizing in economics. The Journal of Economic Perspectives, 16, 23–46.Google Scholar
  61. Newell, P., & Paterson, M. (2010). Climate capitalism: Global warming and the transformation of the global economy. Cambridge; New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
  62. Nordhaus, W. D. (2007). To tax or not to tax: Alternative approaches to slowing global warming. Review of Environmental Economics and Policy, 1(1), 26–44.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  63. Ostrom, E. (1990). Governing the commons: The evolution of institutions for collective action. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
  64. Page, S. E. (2006). Path dependence. Quarterly Journal of Political Science, 1, 87–115.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  65. Pal, L. A. (2000). Beyond policy analysis: Public issue management in turbulent times. Scarborough, ON: ITP Nelson.Google Scholar
  66. Paterson, M. (2012). Who and what are carbon markets for? Politics and the development of climate policy. Climate Policy, 12(1), 82–97.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  67. Patomäki, H. (2006). Realist ontology for future studies. Journal of Critical Realism, 5(1), 1–31.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  68. Pegg, J. R. (2002). US Automakers trail Japanese in eco-ranking. Environmental News Service.Google Scholar
  69. Pierson, P. (2004). Politics in time: History, institutions, and social analysis. Princeton, N.J.; Oxford: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
  70. Rabe, B. G. (2009a). The aversion to direct cost-imposition: Selecting climate policy tools in the United States. Paper read at annual meeting of the American Political Science Association, September 3–6, at Toronto.Google Scholar
  71. Rabe, B. G. (2009b). The ‘impossible dream’ of carbon taxes: Is the “best answer” a political non-starter? In B. G. Rabe (Ed.), Greenhouse governance: Addressing climate change policy in the United States. Washington, D.C.: Brookings Institution Press.Google Scholar
  72. Rabin, M. (1998). Psychology and economics. Journal of Economic Literature, 36(1), 11–46.Google Scholar
  73. Raskin, P., Gallopin, G., Gutman, P., Hammond, A., & Swart, R. (1998). Bending the curve: Toward global sustainability. Stockholm, Sweden: The Stockholm Environment Institute.Google Scholar
  74. Rittel, H. W. J., & Webber, M. M. (1973). Dilemmas in a general theory of planning. Policy Sciences, 4(2), 155–169.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  75. Sabatier, P. A. (1998). Top-down and bottom-up approaches to implementation research: A critical analysis and suggested synthesis. Journal of Public Policy, 6(1), 21–48.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  76. Sen, A. K. (1977). Rational fools—Critique of behavioral foundations of economic-theory. Philosophy & Public Affairs, 6(4), 317–344.Google Scholar
  77. Simon, H. A. (1957a). Administrative behavior: A study of decision-making processes in administrative organization. New York: MacMillan.Google Scholar
  78. Simon, H. A. (1957b). Models of man, social and rational: Mathematical essays on rational human behavior in a social setting. New York: Wiley.Google Scholar
  79. Sinden, A., Kysar, D. A., & Driesen, D. M. (2009). Cost–benefit analysis: New foundations on Shifting Sand. Regulation & Governance, 3, 48–71.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  80. Strotz, R. H. (1955). Myopia and inconsistency in dynamic utility maximization. The Review of Economic Studies, 23(3), 165–180.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  81. Suchman, M. C. (1995). Managing legitimacy: Strategic and institutional approaches. Academy of Management Review, 20(3), 571–610.Google Scholar
  82. Thaler, R., & Sunstein, C. (2008). Nudge: Improving decisions about health, wealth and happiness. New Haven: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
  83. Thelen, K. (2003). How institutions evolve: Insights from comparative historical analysis. In J. Mahoney & D. Rueschemeyer (Eds.), Comparative historical analysis in the social sciences. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
  84. Tribe, L. H. (1972). Policy science: Analysis or ideology. Philosophy & Public Affairs, 2, 66–110.Google Scholar
  85. Tuohy, C. H. (1999). Accidental logics: The dynamics of change in the health care arena in the United States, Britain, and Canada. New York: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
  86. UNEP. (2011). Bridging the emissions gap: A UNEP synthesis report. Nairobi: United Nations Environment Programme.Google Scholar
  87. UNFCCC. (2011). Report of the conference of the parties on its sixteenth session, held in Cancun from 29 November to 10 December 2010. Bonn, Germany: UN Framework Convention on Climate Change.Google Scholar
  88. Unruh, G. C. (2000). Understanding carbon lock-in. Energy Policy, 28(12), 817–830.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  89. Unruh, G. C. (2002). Escaping carbon lock-in. Energy Policy, 30(4), 317–325.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  90. Verba, S. (1971). Sequence and development. In L. Binder (Ed.), Crises and sequences in political development. Princeton: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
  91. Vogel, D. (1995). Trading up: Consumer and environmental regulation in a global economy. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
  92. Walz, R. (2007). The role of regulation for sustainable infrastructure innovations: The case of wind energy. International Journal of Public Policy, 2(1), 57–88.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  93. Weaver, R. K., & Rockman, B. A. (Eds.). (1993). Do institutions matter? (Vol. 1). Washington, D.C.: The Brookings Institution.Google Scholar
  94. Webster, M. (2008). Incorporating path dependency into decision-analytic methods: An application to global climate-change policy. Decision Analysis, 5(2), 60–75.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  95. Weimer, D. L., & Vining, A. R. (2004). Policy analysis: Concepts and practice (4th ed.). Upper Saddle River, NJ: Pearson Prentice Hall.Google Scholar

Copyright information

© Springer Science+Business Media, LLC. 2012

Authors and Affiliations

  • Kelly Levin
    • 1
  • Benjamin Cashore
    • 2
  • Steven Bernstein
    • 3
  • Graeme Auld
    • 4
  1. 1.Climate and Energy ProgramWorld Resources InstituteWashingtonUSA
  2. 2.School of Forestry and Environmental StudiesYale UniversityNew HavenUSA
  3. 3.Department of Political ScienceUniversity of TorontoTorontoCanada
  4. 4.School of Public Policy and AdministrationCarleton UniversityOttawaCanada

Personalised recommendations