Skip to main content
Log in

The economics of emergency response

  • Published:
Policy Sciences Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Federal first responder funding is estimated to be $98 billion below the minimum required level over the 5 years ending in 2010. A significant portion of that shortfall can be covered by savings attained by eliminating non-public-good services, initiating public–private partnerships for meeting peak time demand in emergency situations, and contracting-out other public services. We concentrate on such savings in the context of response to false calls to police, fire, and ambulance services. Solving the false alarm problem for police, fire, and ambulance services and eliminating some non-public-good police services could release significant service-hours and 23.7–31.4% of the required additional Homeland Security (HLS) annual spending. Reducing false alarms means 88,000 police, fire, and ambulance first responders could be shifted to HLS activities.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Similar false calls including totally hoax calls beset the U.S. Coast Guard. The problem of false calls is thus even more widespread than our estimates indicate. In any event we do not include the Coast Guard in our estimates because this paper focuses on state and local services.

  2. These services incorporate insignificant externalities and are private in nature. In the case of minor accidents, traffic may be blocked for a brief period of time. However, since both cars are drivable, they may just move to the shoulder of the road. Police shedding will encourage private providers for all these services. For example, participants in the case of minor accidents may hire an investigator to assign blame. Also, existence of scope economies may encourage providers to offer a host of services, including response to burglar alarms, escorting funerals, vacation services, and more.

  3. Vector Security employed enhanced call verification among other practices to reduce the rate of false dispatches from 1.37 per system a year to 0.8 (Goldfine 2006a, p. 32). In general, central station verification is insignificant in reducing false police response since canceling a valid alarm exposes the central station to liability problems.

  4. Besides response to burglar and fire calls, other examples include gas odors, stray animals, and flooding occurrences. More specifically, when a 911 call comes in and the ambulance is dispatched, the driver does not know if it is a true emergency. Only after arriving at the scene can it be determined if a call for service is a real emergency situation. Some who lack health insurance and require non-emergency medical service use ambulances to reach the hospital, expecting not to be denied care through arrival by an ambulance.

  5. For example, Peltzman (1975) argued that making seat belts mandatory and requiring automobile makers to install other safety features may contribute to less cautious driving that in turn leads to accidents, harming innocent drivers and pedestrians as well as the risk taking drivers themselves.

  6. For example, the terrorist attacks of September 11, 2001 have led the Long Beach, CA police department to create both terrorism and special port units. These increased burdens have forced the department of 1,000 officers to reduce foot patrols and narcotics enforcement (Pomfret 2006).

  7. For example, Milwaukee, WI in 2003 had a false burglar alarm rate of 96% on 28,346 calls (Schwartz 2004). Seattle reported a 98% false alarm rate between 2001 and 2004 (Brooner 2004). Chicago experiences annually a 98% false alarm rate and Salt Lake City in 1999 had a 99.7% rate (Sampson 2001). A detailed survey of alarm owners in 3 localities in Pennsylvania has reached the same conclusion (The Hakim-Buck Study 1991). For False Fire Alarms, see NFPA 2005.

  8. They are annually about 36 million false burglar alarms (Blackstone et al. 2001) and with an average cost of about $50 per alarm call (Blackstone and Hakim 1996) cost would be $1.8 billion.

  9. Seattle WA reports that between September 2001 and December 2005, it will have spent from the City budget sources $45.5 million on HLS. Also, the Seattle P.D. created a HLS section by transferred officers from other functions within the department. It created a chemical, biological, radiological, nuclear, and explosive unit among other activities. The costs to Seattle do not include the additional security for athletic events (City of Seattle 2005). Further, William Bratton, the current police chief in Los Angeles and former chief in New York City points up the high opportunity cost of false alarms in terms of other more valuable police activities (Goldfine, 2006b, p. 46).

  10. A similar study of patrol officers in Australia found that they spend 8% of their time providing community assistance services like retrieving keys from fired employees, assisting homeowners obtain entry into their own homes when they are locked out, and delivering eviction notices to renters (CJC 1997). Checking on the welfare of individuals is a private service because most cases prove to be unfounded.

  11. Police in many small, suburban communities prefer to retain such non-public services including alarm response. Economies of scope among various police activities are more prevalent than in large cities. Managed competition where police could provide services that are private in nature as long as entry of private or other public entities is not prohibited by below cost pricing or regulatory policies is an appropriate solution.

  12. Private law enforcement competes effectively against public law enforcement in the realm of bail bond absconders (Helland and Tabarrok 2004). For a general discussion of privatization of police services, see Benson 1998.

  13. Executives for the industry could be drawn from retirees of public law enforcement agencies, further improving cooperation between the public and private sectors.

  14. For example, electrical facilities are constructed to satisfy peak load times (e.g. late afternoons in the summer).

  15. San Francisco, CA has private police officers who in effect act as public police (Benson 1998, pp. 86–87). The City of Boston, MA developed a volunteer medical organization to provide mass care in disaster situations. A detailed plan, training and exercises have been conducted to assure smooth operation when employed (Menino 2008).

  16. The nationwide cost is 2.2 million false alarms × $365 or $800 million. If $1050 is the cost per alarm, the estimated cost becomes $2.31 billion. In any event, the cost of fire department response is high. Calculations by the Philadelphia Fire Department show that in 2005 response cost was $1,053 per incident, excluding the cost of equipment (Philadelphia Fire Department 2006). Accordingly, our estimates are conservative.

  17. Our estimates do not include the existence and the social cost of injuries resulting from response to false alarms. In just one incident, six people were injured when a fire engine collided with a car while responding to a false fire alarm (Toy 1995).

  18. The cost of response to fire alarms is expected to rise in most non major cities where volunteers primarily provide all fire related service. In general, dual career families, the fact that residents often work far from home, and child care responsibilities are making it more difficult in most communities to attract non-paid volunteers, and repeated false alarms make volunteers reluctant to continuing their service (Mason 2006).

  19. This conclusion arises because at higher prices (fines) price elasticity of demand is greater.

  20. This statement requires two plausible assumptions: price elasticity of demand for false alarms exceed zero and similar demand functions exist for false fire and burglar alarms.

  21. Markets usually provide incentives to produce efficiently, including the encouragement for technological improvements. When, for example the price of energy increases, consumers are inclined to purchase energy efficient vehicles and appliances, and manufacturers have incentives to develop more energy efficient products.

  22. Firms devote substantial efforts to better their rivals in terms of new products that satisfy consumer desires (Scherer and Ross 1990, pp. 613–660). For specific work on fire sensors and control developments see Bushby 2001.

  23. Incidentally, we already witness better and faster verification in large central stations that employ improved receivers (Based on discussions with the president of Vector Security, Pittsburgh, PA).

  24. This calculation is substantiated by the experience of the Province of Ontario, Canada. The number of ambulance responses was 1.6 million in 2004 for a population of 12.4 million (Ontario Ministry of Health and Long Term Care 2005). Maintaining the same ratio of one response for every eight residents would yield 35 million ambulance responses in the U.S.

  25. Response to a false ambulance call includes two paramedics and an ambulance for an average of 1 h. We take the average paramedic salary including fringe benefits to be $50,000 a year. Ambulance response with paramedics in 2005 cost the Philadelphia Fire department $146 per incident, excluding the cost of the ambulance itself (Philadelphia Fire department 2006). Accordingly, our estimates of ambulance response are conservative.

  26. A total of 35 died as a result of ambulance accidents but only 21 white red lights were blinking and sirens were sounding (U.S. DOT 2004, p. 94). In fact some emergency response may occur without lights or sirens so our use of 21 is conservative. We shall assume that 1 out of 5 were the result of false calls.

  27. Design of neighborhoods in a way that that minimizes crime incidents has been developed by Oscar Newman (1996). Newman’s creative ideas are implemented by city planners around the world. Similar efforts could be made in reducing the costs of terrorist attacks through use of resources freed from provision of non- public goods.

  28. A similar phenomenon exists in state and local implementation of privatization ventures. A study by the Government Accounting Office (U.S. GAO 1998) that surveyed privatization implementations suggested that the most important success factor is the existing of influential mayor, governor or council members that champion the effort.

  29. The Coast Guard is also subjected to false emergency including hoax calls to which it responds. Hoax calls alone comprise 25–36% of all calls. Conservatively, there are annually ten thousand hoax calls alone at average cost of $15,000 for a total of $150 million. One search based on a false distress call in the Seattle area cost $194,587 (Spivak 2004). However, even though the Coast Guard provides emergency response, it is not part of this paper that centers on services that are under the control of local governments.

References

  • Benson, B. L. (1998). To serve and protect: Privatization and community in criminal justice. New York, NY: New York University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Blackstone, E. A., Buck, A. J., & Hakim, S. (2005). Evaluation of alternative policies to combat false emergency calls. Evaluation and Program Planning, 28, 233–242.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blackstone, E. A., & Hakim, S. (1996). Police services: The private challenge. Oakland, CA: Independent Institute.

    Google Scholar 

  • Blackstone, E. A., Hakim, S., & Spiegel, U. (2001). The economics of crying wolf. The Milken Institute Review, 3, 40–46.

    Google Scholar 

  • Brooner, J. (2004). Seattle to impose security alarm fees, citing too many false alarms. The Seattle Times, November 24, 2000 U.S. Department of Justice.

  • Buchanan, J. M. (1965). An economic theory of clubs. Economica, 32, 1–14.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bureau of Justice Statistics. (2002). Census of state and local law enforcement agencies, 2000. Bulletin of the BJS October. U.S. Department of Justice.

  • Bureau of Labor Statistics. (2004–2005a). Occupational outlook handbook. Section on security guards and gaming surveillance officers. U.S. Department of Labor.

  • Bureau of Labor Statistics. (2004–2005b). Occupational outlook handbook. Section on emergency medical technicians and paramedics. U.S. Department of Labor.

  • Bushby, S. T. (2001). Integrating fire alarm systems with building automation and control systems. Fire Protection Engineering, 11, 5–11.

    Google Scholar 

  • CBS News. (2003). Burglar alarms cops wouldn’t answer. Los Angeles, April 14. Available at:http://www.cbsnews.com/stories/2003/04/14/national/main549157.shtml . Accessed on: July 24, 2007.

  • City of Seattle. (2005). Homeland security funding and liabilities. Seattle WA: Office of City Auditor.

  • Cornes, R., & Sandler, T. (1986). The theory of externalities, public goods and club goods. Cambridge, England: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Criminal Justice Commission. (1997). The cost of first response policing. Research Paper Series 4, Brisbane, Australia.

  • Cunningham, W. C., Strauchs, J. J., & Van Meter, C. W. (1990). Private security trends, 1970 to 2000. Boston, MA: Butterworth-Heinemann.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dann, C. (2005). Life and death. Quad-city times. Rock Island, IL. May 10. Page 1T. Available at: http://www.emergencydespatch.org/articles/rockisland.htm. Accessed 30 Oct 2007.

  • Emergency Medical Services. (2005). The cost of ambulance services. Toronto, Ontario. Available at: http://www.toronto.ca/ems/overview/cost.htm. Accessed 31 Oct 2007.

  • Finley, P. J. Jr., (2001). Residential fire alarm systems: The verification and response dilemma. Emmetsburg, MD: National Fire Academy Executive Fire Officer Program.

    Google Scholar 

  • Flynn, S. (2007). The edge of disaster. New York, NY: Random House.

    Google Scholar 

  • Goldfine, S. (2006a). Bratlon’s love-hate relationship with security. Security sales and integration March, pp. 39–58.

  • Goldfine, S. (2006b). Award validates vector’s false alarm vigilance. Security sales and integration May, pp. 32–38.

  • Hakim, S., & Buck, A. J. (1992). Alarm system sales: Who buys, who doesn’t. SDM Magazine. July, pp. 74–75.

  • Hakim, S. (1995). Securing suburban homes: A study on burglar alarm effectiveness. Bethesda, MD: Alarm Industry Research and Education Foundation.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hakim, S., & Blackstone, E. A. (1996). Keeping a watchful eye on the cost of response to false alarms. Security Dealer. August, pp. 102–108.

  • Hakim, S., & Blackstone, E. A. (1997). Securing home and business: A guide to the electronic security industry. Boston, MA: Butterworth-Heinemann Publishers.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hakim, S., & Buck, A. J. (1991). Residential security: The Hakim-Buck study on suburban alarm effectiveness. Bethesda, MD: Alarm Industry Research and Education Foundation.

    Google Scholar 

  • Helland, E., & Tabarrok, A. (2004). The fugitive: Evidence on public versus private law enforcement from bail jumping. Journal of Law and Economics, 67, 93–122.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Inspector General. (1998). Medical necessity of medicare ambulance services. U.S. Department of Health and Human Services. Available at: http://oig.hhs.gov/oei/reports/oei-09-95-00412.pdf. Accessed 30 Oct 2007.

  • Johnson, R. (2002). Ambulance Wars. Michigan Privatization Report. The Macchinac Center for Public Policy, winter 12–13. Available at http://www.mackinac.org/archives/2002/mpr2002-01.pdf. Accessed 31 Oct 2007.

  • Kreps, G. A. (1998). Disaster as systemic event and social catalyst. In E. L. Quarantelli (Ed.), What is a disaster? (pp. 31–55). New York, NY: Routledge Publishers.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kreps, G. A. (2006). Facing hazards and disasters. Washington, D.C.: National Academies Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kuchler, F., & Golan, E. (1999). Assigning values to life: Comparing methods for valuing health risks. U.S. Department of Agriculture, Economic Research Service, Agricultural Economics Report No. (AER784).

  • Mason, T. (2006). Volunteer fire companies are moving toward merger. The Philadelphia Inquirer, September 5: B3.

  • McChesney, F. S. (1986). Government prohibitions on volunteer fire fighting in 19th-century America: A property rights perspective. Journal of Legal Studies, 15, 69–92.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • MDA Ambulances. (2005). MDA Ambulances: Israel’s symbol of life and hope. A report published by Magen David Adom, the Israeli chapter of the International Red Cross, Tel Aviv, Israel.

  • Mehay, S. L., & Gonzalez, R. A. (1992). Direct and indirect benefits of intergovernmental contracting for police services. In G. W. Bowman (Ed.), Privatizing the United States justice system, (pp. 67–81). Jefferson, NC: McFarland and Co. Publishers.

    Google Scholar 

  • Menino, T. M. (2008). A volunteer medical corp: The Boston experience. In S. Hakim & E. Blackstone (Eds.), Improving homeland security. Lanham, MD: Rowman and Littlefield.

  • National Fire Protection Association (NFPA). (2005). Fire departments calls. Quincy, MA.

  • National Volunteer Fire Council. (2005). NVFC 2005 Fact sheet, Washington, D.C. Available at: http://nvfc.org/files/documents/NVFC_Stats_and_Facts_Sheet_2005.pdf. Accessed 30 Oct 2007.

  • Newman, O. (1996). Creating defensible space. US Department of Housing and Urban Development, Office of Policy Development and Research. Contract No. DU100C000005967.

  • Olson, M. (1965). A logic of collective action. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ontario Ministry of Health and Long-Term Care. (2005). Emergency health services branch. Public Information. EHS Statistics. Available at: http://www.health.gov.on.ca/english/public/program/ehs/ehs_dt.html. Accessed 30 Oct 2007.

  • Parks, R., Mastrofski, S., Dejong, C., & Gray, M. K. (1999). How officers spend their time with the community. Justice Quarterly, 16, 483–517.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pastor, J. F. (2003). The privatization of police in America. Jefferson, NC: McFarland Publishers.

    Google Scholar 

  • Peltzman, S. (1975). The effect of automobile safety regulation. Journal of Political Economy, 83, 677–725.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Peltzman, S. (1976). Towards a more general theory of regulation. Journal of Law and Economics, 19, 211–240.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Perry, R. W., & Lindell, M. K. (2003). Preparedness for emergency response: Guidelines for the emergency planning process. Disasters, 27, 336–350.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Philadelphia Fire Department. (2006). Statistics for 2005 on the cost of false alarms for EMS and Fire Response, calculated by the Philadelphia Fire Department.

  • Pomfret, J. (2006). Police finding it hard to fill vacancies. Washington post. March 26. Available at: http://www.washingtonpost.com/wpdyn/content/article/2006/03/26/AR2006032600995.html. Accessed 31 Oct 2007.

  • Prendergast, J. (2003). You call, we haul. Cincinnati Inquirer. May 11. Available at: http://www.enquirer.com/editions/2003/05/11/loc_cityrescue11.html. Accessed 30 Oct 2007.

  • Quarantelli, E. L. (1986). Disaster crisis management. Preliminary Paper # 113 delivered at the International Conference on Industrial Crisis Management. New York City, September 6.

  • Raletz, A. E. (2005). False alarms plague police. Fire Departments. Saint Joseph News-Press. January 29.

  • Reason Foundation. (2006). Emergency medical services. Available at: http://www.privatization.org/database/policyissues/ems_local.html. Accessed 30 Oct 2007.

  • Romeo Observer. (2005). Pulled fire alarm results in charge. June 8. Available at: http://www.romeoobserver.com/story.asp?storyid=4663. Accessed 30 Oct 2007.

  • Rudman, W. B. (2003). Emergency responders: drastically under funded, dangerously unprepared. New York, NY: Council on Foreign Relations.

  • Salt Lake City. (2005). Personal communication with City officials. June 3.

  • Salt Lake City Fire Department. (2006). Fire alarm ordinance summary.

  • Salt Lake City Police Department. (2006). Verified response: The false alarm solution.

  • Sampson, R. (2001). False Burglar Alarms, Problem Oriented Guides for Police, No. 5. U.S. Department of Justice; Office of Community Oriented Policing Services.

  • Samuelson, P. (1954). The pure theory of public expenditures. Review of Economics and Statistics, 36, 387–389.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Scherer, F. M., & Ross, D. (1990). Industrial market structure and economic performance (3rd ed.). Boston, MA: Houghton Mifflin Company.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schwartz, A. (2004). Reason for alarm: False alarms take cops from real crimes. The milwaukee buzz. August 24. Available at: http://onmilwaukee.com/buzz/articles/wispol082404.html. Accessed 30 Oct 2007.

  • Scott, M. S., & Goldstein, H. (2005). Shifting and sharing responsibility for public safety problems. Problem oriented guides for police (POPS), U.S. Department of Justice, Office of Community Oriented Policing Services, Response Guide Series #3.

  • Spivak, W. (2004). False alarms are no joke. National Press Corps, U.S. Coast Guard Auxiliary.

  • Towns, S. (2007). The sacrifice at home. Government Technology, August.

  • Toy, V. S. (1995). Six injured when fire truck collides with car. NY Times, May 29, Metro: 25.

  • US Conference of Mayors (USCM). (2004). Second mayors. Report to the nation: Tracking HLS funds sent to the 50 state governments. Washington, DC: USCM.

  • U.S. Department of Homeland Security (2003). Office for Domestic Preparedness, 2003, Homeland security exercise and evaluation program volume I: Overview and Doctrine. Report Number NCJ199536. Available at: http://www.ncem.org/HomelandSecurity/library/HSEEPv1.pdf. Accessed 30 Oct 2007.

  • U.S. Department of Transportation, National Highway Transportation Administration. (2004). Traffic safety facts 2004. Washington, D.C.

  • U.S. Government, General Accounting Office. (1998). Privatization: Questions state and local decisionmakers used when considering privatization options. Washington, D.C. GAO/GGD-98-87.

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Andrew J. Buck.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Blackstone, E.A., Buck, A.J. & Hakim, S. The economics of emergency response. Policy Sci 40, 313–334 (2007). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11077-007-9047-6

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11077-007-9047-6

Keywords

Navigation