Skip to main content
Log in

Non-expected Route Choice Model under Risk on Stochastic Traffic Networks

  • Published:
Networks and Spatial Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

In this paper, we propose a novel non-expected route travel time (NERTT) model, which belong to the rank-dependent expected utility model. The NERTT consists of two parts, which are the route travel time distribution and the distortion function. With the strictly increasing and strictly concave distortion function, we can prove that the route travel time in the proposed model is risk-averse, which is the main focus of this paper. We show two different reduction methods from the NERTT model to the travel time budget model and mean-excess travel time model. One method is based on the properly selected distortion functions and the other one is based on a general distortion function. Besides, the behavioral inconsistency of the expected utility model in the route choice can be overcome with the proposed model. The NERTT model can also be generalized to the non-expected disutility (NED) model, and some relationship between the NED model and the route choice model based on the cumulative prospect theory can be shown. This indicates that the proposed model has some generality. Finally, we develop a non-expected risk-averse user equilibrium model and formulate it as a variational inequality (VI) problem. A heuristic gradient projection algorithm with column generation is used to solve the VI. The proposed model and algorithm are tested on some hypothetical traffic networks and on some large-scale traffic networks.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Subscribe and save

Springer+ Basic
$34.99 /Month
  • Get 10 units per month
  • Download Article/Chapter or eBook
  • 1 Unit = 1 Article or 1 Chapter
  • Cancel anytime
Subscribe now

Buy Now

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5
Fig. 6
Fig. 7
Fig. 8
Fig. 9
Fig. 10
Fig. 11
Fig. 12
Fig. 13
Fig. 14

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. In the main body of the paper, we focus on the modeling of the risk-averse route travel time, while the CPT-based route choice model does not belong to the risk-averse analysis merely ( Xu et al. 2011a, b). Therefore, we postpone the analysis of the NED and its relationship to the CPT-based route choice model in the appendix, which can demonstrate the generality of the proposed model.

  2. In this paper, we assume the probability distribution of the route travel time is continuous.

  3. Note here that the utility can be in the form of negative route travel time.

  4. The Gauss error function is defined as \( erf(x)=\frac{2}{\sqrt{\pi}}{\int}_0^x \exp \left(-{t}^2\right) dt \).

  5. In this simple case, the value of parameter α in the Wang function is 2.

  6. In this paper, we use this simple example to demonstrate the rightness of the proposed propositions. In practice, one can estimate the route travel time distribution (e.g., Westgate et al. 2016).

  7. The convergence rate is 10−7, which is achieved in 15 iterations, and we only show the three iterations for a better presentation.

  8. Wu and Nie (2011) proposed the utility-based model instead of disutility-based model. Therefore, β 1 < 0 and β 2 < 0 in their paper. While, in Yin et al. (2004), the authors also used the disutility function.

References

  • Avineri E (2006) The effect of reference point on stochastic network equilibrium. Transp Sci 40(4):409–420

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ban XJ, Ferris MC, Tang L, Lu S (2013) Risk-neutral second best toll pricing. Transp Res B Methodol 48:67–87

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bell DE (1982) Regret in decision making under uncertainty. Oper Res 30(5):961–981

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bell M (2006) Mixed route strategies for the risk-averse shipment of hazardous materials. Networks and spatial Economics 6:253–265

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Berglund P, Kwon C (2014) Robust facility location problem for hazardous waste transportation. Networks and spatial Economics 14:91–116

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bertsekas DP (1976) On the Goldstein-Levitin-Polyak gradient projection method. Automatic Control IEEE Transactions on 21(2):174–184

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brownstone D, Ghosh A, Golob TF, Kazimi C, Van Amelsfort D (2003) Driversʼ willingness-to-pay to reduce travel time: evidence from the San Diego I-15 congestion pricing project. Transp Res A Policy Pract 37(4):373–387

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chen A, Zhou Z (2010) The α-reliable mean-excess traffic equilibrium model with stochastic travel times. Transp Res B Methodol 44(4):493–513

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chen BY, Lam WH, Sumalee A, Shao H (2011) An efficient solution algorithm for solving multi-class reliability-based traffic assignment problem. Mathematical and Computer Modeling 54(5):1428–1439

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chen BY, Lam WH, Sumalee A, Li Q, Shao H, Fang Z (2013) Finding reliable shortest paths in road networks under uncertainty. Networks and spatial Economics 13:123–148

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Choquet G (1953) Theory of capacities. Annales de lʼinstitut Fourier 5(131–295):85–87

    Google Scholar 

  • Chorus CG (2014) A generalized random regret minimization model. Transp Res B Methodol 68:224–238

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chorus CG, Arentze TA, Timmermans HJ (2008) A random regret-minimization model of travel choice. Transp Res B Methodol 42(1):1–18

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Connors RD, Sumalee A (2009) A network equilibrium model with travelersʼ perception of stochastic travel times. Transp Res B 43(6):614–624

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fujii S, Kitamura R (2004) Driversʼ mental representation of travel time and departure time choice in uncertain traffic network conditions. Networks and spatial Economics 4:243–256

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gao S, Frejinger E, Ben-Akiva M (2010) Adaptive route choices in risky traffic networks: A prospect theory approach. Transportation research part C: emerging technologies, 18(5):727–740

  • Guo Z, Fan Y (2016) A Stochastic Multi-agent Optimization Model for Energy Infrastructure Planning under Uncertainty in An Oligopolistic Market. Netw Spat Econ 4. doi:10.1007/s11067-016-9336-8

  • Hall RW (1993) Non-recurrent congestion: how big is the problem? Are traveler information systems the solution? Transportation Research Part C 1(1):89–103

  • Jayakrishnan R, Tsai WK, Prashker JN, Rajadhyaksha S (1994) A faster path-based algorithm for traffic assignment. Transp Res Rec 1443:75–83

    Google Scholar 

  • Kahneman D, Tversky A (1979) Prospect theory: an analysis of decision under risk. Econometrica: Journal of the econometric society 47:263–291

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lam WHK, Shao H, Sumalee A (2008) Modeling impacts of adverse weather conditions on a road network with uncertainties in demand and supply. Transp Res B 42(10):890–910

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Li Q, Nie Y, Vallamsundar S, Lin J, Homem-de-Mello T (2016) Finding efficient and environmentally friendly paths for risk-averse freight carriers. Networks and spatial Economics 16(255):275

    Google Scholar 

  • Lo HK, Tung YK (2003) Network with degradable links: capacity analysis and design. Transp Res B 37(4):345–363

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lo HK, Luo XW, Siu BWY (2006) Degradable transport network: travel time budget of travelers with heterogeneous risk aversion. Transp Res B 40(9):792–806

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mirchandani P, Soroush H (1987) Generalized traffic equilibrium with probabilistic travel times and perceptions. Transp Sci 21(3):133–152

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nagurney A (1993) Network economics: a variational inequality approach. Kluwer Academic Publishers, Dordrecht

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Nie YM (2011) Multi-class percentile user equilibrium with flow-dependent stochasticity. Transp Res B Methodol 45(10):1641–1659

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nie Y, Wu X, Homem-de-Mello T (2012) Optimal path problems with second-order stochastic dominance constraints. Networks and spatial Economics 12:561–587

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Quiggin J (1982) A theory of anticipated utility. J Econ Behav Organ 3(4):323–343

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ramos GM, Daamen W, Hoogendoorn S (2014) A state-of-the-art review: developments in utility theory, Prospect theory and regret theory to investigate Travelersʼ behaviour in situations involving travel time uncertainty. Transp Rev 34(1):46–67

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Razo M, Gao S (2013) A rank-dependent expected utility model for strategic route choice with stated preference data. Transportation Research Part C: Emerging Technologies 27:117–130

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Recker W, Chung Y, Park J, Wang L, Chen A, Ji Z, Liu H, Horrocks M, Oh JS (2005) Considering risk-taking behavior in travel time reliability. Report No. 4110, California Partners for Advanced Transit and Highways

  • Shao H, Lam WHK, Tam ML (2006) A reliability-based stochastic traffic assignment model for network with multiple user classes under uncertainty in demand. Networks and spatial Economics 6(3/4):173–204

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sumalee A, Connors RD, Luathep P (2009) Network equilibrium under cumulative Prospect theory and endogenous stochastic demand and supply. In: Lam WHK, Wong SC, Lo HK (eds) Transportation and traffic theory 2009, golden Jubilee. Springer, New York, pp 19–38

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Szeto WY, O’Brien L, O’Mahony M (2006) Risk-averse traffic assignment with elastic demands: NCP formulation and solution method for assessing performance reliability. Networks and Spatial Economics 6(3/4):313–332

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tan Z, Yang H, Guo R (2014) Pareto efficiency of reliability-based traffic equilibria and risk-taking behavior of travelers. Transp Res B Methodol 66:16–31

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tian L, Huang H, Gao Z (2012) A cumulative perceived value-based dynamic user equilibrium model considering the Travelersʼ risk evaluation on arrival time. Networks and spatial Economics 12:589–608

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tversky A, Kahneman D (1992) Advances in prospect theory: cumulative representation of uncertainty. J Risk Uncertain 5(4):297–323

  • Uchida T, Iida Y (1993) Risk assignment: a new traffic assignment model considering the risk travel time variation. In: Daganzo CF (ed) Proceedings of the 12th international symposium on transportation and traffic theory. Elsevier, Amsterdam, pp 89–105

    Google Scholar 

  • Wang S (1995) Insurance pricing and increased limits ratemaking by proportional hazards transforms. Insurance: Mathematics and Economics 17(1):43–54

    Google Scholar 

  • Wang SS (2000) A class of distortion operators for pricing financial and insurance risks. Journal of risk and insurance 67:15–36

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wang JY, Ehrgott M, Chen A (2014) A bi-objective user equilibrium model of travel time reliability in a road network. Transp Res B Methodol 66:4–15

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wardrop JG (1952) Some theoretical aspects of road traffic research. Proceedings of the Institution of Civil Engineers Part II 1(3):325–378

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Watling D (2006) User equilibrium traffic network assignment with stochastic travel times and late arrival penalty. Eur J Oper Res 175(3):1539–1556

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Westgate BS, Woodard DB, Matteson DS, Henderson SG (2016) Large-network travel time distribution estimation for ambulances. Eur J Oper Res 252(1):322–333

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Muldowney P, Ostaszewski K, Wojdowski W (2012) The Darth Vader rule. Tatra Mt Math Publ 52:53–63

    Google Scholar 

  • Wu X (2015) Study on mean-standard deviation shortest path problem in stochastic and timedependent networks: A stochastic dominance based approach. Transportation Research Part B: Methodological 80:275–290

  • Wu X, Nie YM (2011) Modeling heterogeneous risk-taking behavior in route choice: a stochastic dominance approach. Transp Res A Policy Pract 45(9):896–915

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Xu H, Lou Y, Yin Y, Zhou J (2011a) A prospect-based user equilibrium model with endogenous reference points and its application in congestion pricing. Transp Res B 45(2):311–328

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Xu H, Zhou J, Xu W (2011b) A decision-making rule for modeling travelers′ route choice behavior based on cumulative prospect theory. Transp Res C 19(2):218–228

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Xu X, Chen A, Cheng L, Lo HK (2014) Modeling distribution tail in network performance assessment: A mean-excess total travel time risk measure and analytical estimation method. Transportation Research Part B: Methodological 66, pp. 32–49

  • Yin Y, Ieda H (2001) Assessing performance reliability of road networks under non-recurrent congestion. Transp Res Rec 1771:148–155

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Yin YF, Lam WHK, Ieda H (2004) New technology and the modeling of risk-taking behavior in congested road networks. Transp Res C 12:171–192

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zhou L, Zhong S, Ma S, Jia N (2014) Prospect theory based estimation of drivers’ risk attitudes in route choice behaviors. Accid Anal Prev 73:1–11

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zorich VA, Cooke R (2004) Mathematical analysis I. Springer Science & Business Media, Berlin

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

The authors thank the anonymous reviewers for their insightful comments and suggestions that significantly improved the quality of earlier versions of the paper. This study is supported by the National Basic Research Program of China (973 Program-No. 2012CB725405). The first author’s work is also supported by the Fundamental Research Funds for the Central Universities (Grant No. CXZZ13_0116) and by the Scientific Research Foundations of Graduate School of Southeast University (Grant No. YBJJ1344). The China Scholarship Council (CSC) provided a scholarship that supports the first author to visit Rensselaer Polytechnic Institute from 2014 to 2016. The second author is partially supported by the National Science Foundation (NSF) grant CMMI-1055555 and The Program for Professor of Special Appointment (Eastern Scholar) at Shanghai Institutions of Higher Learning via a grant to the Shanghai Maritime University. Any opinions, findings, and conclusions or recommendations expressed in this paper are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect the views of the NSF or NSFC.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Xuegang (Jeff) Ban.

Appendix

Appendix

1.1 Generalization to the disutility function

In Section 3, we discussed the NERTT model and showed the relationship of the NERTT and TTB/METT. In this appendix, we show that the NERTT can be generalized to embed a disutility function, i.e., the NED model. Note here that we can also generalize the NERTT by embed the utility function, because utility is the negative disutility, and the following discussions can be conducted in a similar way. In fact, in Appendix A.2, the relationship between the NED and the CPT-based route choice model is shown by embedding the utility function. In fact, different disutility functions can be adopted in the NED model and the relationship between the NED model and the CPT-based route choice model can be derived in a special case, which further demonstrates the generality of the NED model.

  • Definition A.1 (Non-expected disutility). The non-expected disutility is the expectation of the random disutility under an appropriate distortion of the original distribution, i.e., \( {\rho}_g\left( d(T)\right)={\int}_0^{\infty } g\left( D\left( d(t)\right)\right) dt \), where d(t) is the disutility function.

The property of the NED model can also be shown in the similar way as shown in Proposition 1. Mirchandani and Soroush (1987) introduced two different disutility functions and we summarize them as following.Footnote 8

  • Definition A.2 (Linear disutility function, LDF). For the linear disutility function d LDF , d LDF (x) = β 0 + β 1 x, β 1 > 0.

  • Definition A.3 (Exponential disutility function, EDF). For the exponential disutility function d EDF , d EDF  = β 1 exp (β 2 x + β 0), β 1 > 0, and β 2 > 0.

Here we can find the analytical form of the NED with LDF and EDF under the normally distributed route travel time, and the analytical form of NED with LDF under the log-normally distributed route travel time. However, we cannot find the analytical form of the NED with EDF under the log-normally distributed route travel time and other NEDs with other probability distributions, which can be obtained with the Monte-Carlo simulation. Therefore, the following three propositions can be reached.

  • Proposition A.1. If the route travel time follows the normal distribution, the NED with LDF is β 1(μ + ασ) + β 0.

Proof

If we choose the LDF, we can obtain the following Eq. (11),

$$ {D}_{u(T)}(t)= P\left\{{\beta}_0+{\beta}_1 T> t\right\}= P\left\{ T>\frac{t-{\beta}_0}{\beta_1}\right\}=1-\Phi \left[\frac{\frac{t-{\beta}_0}{\beta_1}-\mu}{\sigma}\right]=\Phi \left[\frac{\mu -\frac{t-{\beta}_0}{\beta_1}}{\sigma}\right] $$
(11)

Substitute Eq. (11) into the Wang function, we can get \( \begin{array}{l} g\left[{D}_{u(T)}(t)\right]=\Phi \left[{\Phi}^{-1}\left(\Phi \left[\frac{\mu -\frac{t-{\beta}_0}{\beta_1}}{\sigma}\right]\right)+\alpha \right]=\Phi \left[\frac{\mu -\frac{t-{\beta}_0}{\beta_1}}{\sigma}+\alpha \right]=\Phi \left[\frac{\mu -\frac{t-{\beta}_0}{\beta_1}+\alpha \sigma}{\sigma}\right]\\ {}=1-\Phi \left[\frac{\frac{t-{\beta}_0}{\beta_1}-\left(\mu +\alpha \sigma \right)}{\sigma}\right]={D}_Y(t)\end{array} \).

Therefore, \( \frac{Y-{\beta}_0}{\beta_1}\sim N\left(\mu +\alpha \sigma, {\sigma}^2\right) \), and \( Y\sim N\left({\beta}_1\left(\mu +\alpha \sigma \right)+{\beta}_0,{\beta}_1^2{\sigma}^2\right) \). Thus,\( {E}_g\left( u(T)\right)={\int}_0^{+\infty }{D}_Y(t) dt= E(Y)={\beta}_1\left(\mu +\alpha \sigma \right)+{\beta}_0 \), which complete the proof.

  • Proposition A.2. If the route travel time follows the normal distribution, the NED with EDF is \( {\beta}_1 \exp \left({\beta}_2\left(\mu +\alpha \sigma \right)+{\beta}_0+\frac{\beta_2^2{\sigma}^2}{2}\right). \)

Proof

If we choose the EDF, we can obtain the following Eq. (12),

$$ \begin{array}{l}{D}_{u(T)}(t)= P\left\{{\beta}_1 \exp \left({\beta}_2 T+{\beta}_0\right)> t\right\}= P\left\{ T>\frac{ \ln \left(\frac{t}{\beta_1}\right)-{\beta}_0}{\beta_2}\right\}\\ {}=1-\Phi \left[\frac{\frac{ \ln \left(\frac{t}{\beta_1}\right)-{\beta}_0}{\beta_2}-\mu}{\sigma}\right]=\Phi \left[\frac{\mu -\frac{ \ln \left(\frac{t}{\beta_1}\right)-{\beta}_0}{\beta_2}}{\sigma}\right]\end{array} $$
(12)

Substitute Eq. (12) into the Wang function, we can get \( \begin{array}{l} g\left[{D}_{u(T)}(t)\right]=\Phi \left[{\Phi}^{-1}\left(\Phi \left[\frac{\mu -\frac{ \ln \left(\frac{t}{\beta_1}\right)-{\beta}_0}{\beta_2}}{\sigma}\right]\right)+\alpha \right]=\Phi \left[\frac{\mu -\frac{ \ln \left(\frac{t}{\beta_1}\right)-{\beta}_0}{\beta_2}}{\sigma}+\alpha \right]\\ {}=\Phi \left[\frac{\mu -\frac{ \ln \left(\frac{t}{\beta_1}\right)-{\beta}_0}{\beta_2}+\alpha \sigma}{\sigma}\right]=1-\Phi \left[\frac{\frac{ \ln \left(\frac{t}{\beta_1}\right)-{\beta}_0}{\beta_2}-\left(\mu +\alpha \sigma \right)}{\sigma}\right]={D}_Y(t)\end{array} \).

Therefore, \( \frac{ \ln \left(\frac{Y}{\beta_1}\right)-{\beta}_0}{\beta_2}\sim N\left(\mu +\alpha \sigma, {\sigma}^2\right) \), and \( \ln \left(\frac{Y}{\beta_1}\right)\sim N\left({\beta}_2\left(\mu +\alpha \sigma \right)+{\beta}_0,{\beta}_2^2{\sigma}^2\right) \). Thus, \( {E}_g\left( u(T)\right)={\int}_0^{+\infty }{D}_Y(t) dt= E(Y)={\beta}_1 E\left(\frac{Y}{\beta_1}\right)={\beta}_1 \exp \left({\beta}_2\left(\mu +\alpha \sigma \right)+{\beta}_0+\frac{\beta_2^2{\sigma}^2}{2}\right) \), which complete the proof.

  • Proposition A.3. If the route travel time follows the lognormal distribution, the NED with LDF is \( {\beta}_1 \exp \left(\mu +\alpha \sigma +\frac{\sigma^2}{2}\right)+{\beta}_0. \)

Proof

If we choose the EDF, we can obtain the following Eq. (13),

$$ {D}_{u(T)}(t)= P\left\{{\beta}_0+{\beta}_1 T> t\right\}= P\left\{ T>\frac{t-{\beta}_0}{\beta_1}\right\}=1-\Phi \left[\frac{ \ln \left(\frac{t-{\beta}_0}{\beta_1}\right)-\mu}{\sigma}\right]=\Phi \left[\frac{\mu - \ln \left(\frac{t-{\beta}_0}{\beta_1}\right)}{\sigma}\right] $$
(13)

Substitute Eq. (13) into the Wang function, we can get \( \begin{array}{l} g\left[{D}_{u(T)}(t)\right]=\Phi \left[{\Phi}^{-1}\left(\Phi \left[\frac{\mu - \ln \left(\frac{t-{\beta}_0}{\beta_1}\right)}{\sigma}\right]\right)+\alpha \right]=\Phi \left[\frac{\mu - \ln \left(\frac{t-{\beta}_0}{\beta_1}\right)}{\sigma}+\alpha \right]\\ {}=\Phi \left[\frac{\mu - \ln \left(\frac{t-{\beta}_0}{\beta_1}\right)+\alpha \sigma}{\sigma}\right]=1-\Phi \left[\frac{ \ln \left(\frac{t-{\beta}_0}{\beta_1}\right)-\left(\mu +\alpha \sigma \right)}{\sigma}\right]={D}_Y(t)\\ {}\end{array} \).

Therefore, \( \ln \left(\frac{Y-{\beta}_0}{\beta_1}\right)\sim N\left(\mu +\alpha \sigma, {\sigma}^2\right) \). Thus, we can get \( {E}_g\left( u(T)\right)={\int}_0^{+\infty }{D}_Y(t) dt= E(Y)={\beta}_1 E\left(\frac{Y-{\beta}_0}{\beta_1}\right)+{\beta}_0={\beta}_1 \exp \left(\mu +\alpha \sigma +\frac{\sigma^2}{2}\right)+{\beta}_0 \), which complete the proof.

1.2 Relationship between the NED and the CPT-based route choice model

In this subsection, we continue to show the relationship between the NED model and the CPT-based route choice model.

  • Proposition A.4. Given a reference point t 0, \( {\rho}_g\left( d(T)\right)={\int}_0^{\infty } g\left( D\left( d(t)\right)\right) dt \) can be written as \( {\rho}_g\left( d(T)\right)={\int}_0^{t_0} g\left( D\left( d(t)\right)\right) dt+{\int}_{t_0}^{+\infty } g\left( D\left( d(t)\right)\right) dt \). If the distortion function \( g(x)=\frac{x^{\gamma}}{{\left({x}^{\gamma}+{\left(1- x\right)}^{\gamma}\right)}^{\raisebox{1ex}{$1$}\!\left/ \!\raisebox{-1ex}{$\gamma $}\right.}} \) and the utility function \( d(t)=\left\{\begin{array}{cc}\hfill {\left({t}_0- t\right)}^{\beta_0}\hfill & \hfill t\le {t}_0\hfill \\ {}\hfill -{\beta}_1{\left( t-{t}_0\right)}^{\beta_2}\hfill & \hfill t>{t}_0\hfill \end{array}\right. \) are adopted, we can get the CPT-based route choice model in Xu et al. (2011a).

Proof of proposition A.4 can be found in Tversky and Kahneman (1992) and Connors and Sumalee (2009), which is omitted here. From proposition A.4, we can see that given the reference point, the NED model is decomposed into the sum of two NED models restricted on a smaller travel time interval. This helps to show the relationship between NED model and the CPT-based route choice model. If there is no reference point and the disutility function is d(t) = t, the difference between the (special) CPT-based route choice model and the NERTT model is the distortion function, which shows travelers’ decision weights for the probabilities.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Ji, X., Ban, X.(., Li, M. et al. Non-expected Route Choice Model under Risk on Stochastic Traffic Networks. Netw Spat Econ 17, 777–807 (2017). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11067-017-9344-3

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11067-017-9344-3

Keywords

Navigation