Abstract
This paper examines the response of income concentration in the US to the occurrence of major systemic banking crises since the beginning of the twentieth century. In doing so, the paper analyzes the shape of the upper income tail as well as the national income shares accruing to different groups within the richest decile. The findings suggest that systemic banking crises reduce income concentration within the top decile of the US pre–tax and transfers income distribution, and more generally, that the effect is highly heterogeneous across different top income groups. While the richest income group loses ground, the lower half of the top decile appears to gain in relative terms. However, evidence suggests that the estimated short-term effect of market forces stemming from banking crises can be relatively small in magnitude and even temporary in nature, as it may be quickly reabsorbed. These findings lend indirect support to the idea that only substantial changes in government policies and institutional frameworks can bring about radical changes in income distribution.
This is a preview of subscription content, access via your institution.
Notes
Note that in the case of an ex ante approach, even the ‘crisis on’ values of the top shares would be unknown and represented in expectation form. However, this approach can be useful exclusively in a context of hypothetical macro policy evaluation as discussed in Pesaran and Smith (2012) and Pesaran and Smith (2016).
This transformation is valid under the assumption of stationarity of gi.
Contractions and recessions start at the peak of a business cycle and end at the trough. The NBER identifies business cycles based on quarterly data. Data downloaded from http://www.nber.org/cycles.html in November 2017.
In order to be more precise, one could associate different marginal tax rates with different tax units using micro data and the TAXSIM simulator elaborated by the National Bureau of Economic Research. However, this could be done only from 1960 on and using micro data (see Saez (2004)).
References
Almeida, V.: Income Inequality and Redistribution in the Aftermath of the 2007-2008 Crisis: The U.S Case. Mimeograph, Paris School of Economics (2017)
Alvaredo, F., Atkinson, A.B., Piketty, T., Saez, E.: The top 1 percent in international and historical perspective. J. Econ. Perspect. 27(3), 3–20 (2013)
Atkinson, A.B.: Pareto and the upper tail of the income distribution in the UK: 1799 to the present. Economica 84(334), 129–156 (2017)
Atkinson, A.B., Lakner, C.: Capital and Labor: The Factor Income Composition of Top Incomes in the United States, 1962–2006. Working Paper 8268, World Bank (2017)
Atkinson, A.B., Morelli, S.: Inequality and Banking Crises: a First Look. Report, International Labour Organisation (2010)
Atkinson, A.B., Morelli, S.: Economic Crises and Inequality. Technical Report HDRP-2011-06 Human Development Report Office (HDRO), United Nations Development Programme (UNDP) (2011)
Atkinson, A.B., Piketty, T., Saez, E.: Top incomes in the long run of history. J. Econ. Lit. 49(1), 3–71 (2011)
Ball, L.D.F., Leigh, D., Loungani, P.: The Distributional Effects of Fiscal Consolidation. Working Paper WP/13/151, International Monetary Fund (2013)
Barro, R.J., Ursúa, J.F.: Stock-Market Crashes and Depressions. Working Paper 14760, National Bureau of Economic Research (2009)
Beach, C.: Cyclical impacts on the personal distribution of income. In: Berg, S.V. (ed.) Annals of Economic and Social Measurement, Volume 5, number 1 (pp. 33–56). National Bureau of Economic Research (1976)
Beach, C.: Cyclical sensitivity of aggregate income inequality. Rev. Econ. Stat. 59(1), 56–66 (1977)
Blank, R.M.: Disaggregating the effect of the business cycle on the distribution of income. Economica 56(222), 141–163 (1989)
Blank, R.M., Blinder, A.S.: Macroeconomics, Income Distribution, and Poverty. Working Paper 1567, National Bureau of Economic Research (1985)
Blinder, A., Esaki, H.: Macroeconomic activity and income distribution in the postwar United States. Rev. Econ. Stat., 604–609 (1978)
Bolt, J., Inklaar, R., de Jong, H., van Zanden, J.L.: Rebasing Maddison: New income comparisons and the shape of long-run economic development. GGDC Research Memorandum, 174 (2018)
Bordo, M., Eichengreen, B., Klingebiel, D., Martinez-Peria, M.S.: Is the crisis problem growing more severe?. Econ. Policy 16(32), 51–82 (2001)
Bordo, M.D., Meissner, C.M.: Does inequality lead to a financial crisis?. J. Int. Money Financ. 31(8), 2147–2161 (2012)
Boyd, J.H., De Nicolò, G., Loukoianova, E.: Banking crises and crisis dating: Theory and evidence. Working Paper WP/09/141, International Monetary Fund (2009)
Cerra, V., Saxena, S.C.: Growth dynamics: the myth of economic recovery. Am. Econ. Rev. 98(1), 439–457 (2008)
Cravino, J., Levchenko, A.A.: The distributional consequences of large devaluations. Amer. Econ. Rev. 107(11), 3477–3509 (2017)
Curry, T., Shibut, L.: The cost of the savings and loan crisis: truth and consequences. FDIC Bank. Rev. 13(2), 26–35 (2000)
Dolls, M., Fuest, C., Peichl, A.: Automatic stabilizers and economic crisis: US vs Europe. J. Public Econ. 96(3), 279–294 (2012)
Farr, L., Vella, F.: Macroeconomic conditions and the distribution of income in Spain. Labour 22(3), 383–410 (2008)
Furman, J., Stiglitz, J.E.: Economic consequences of income inequality. In: Income Inequality: Issues and Policy Options–Proceedings of a Symposium Sponsored by the Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City (pp. 221–263) (1998)
Gorodnichenko, Y., Kueng, L., Silvia, J., Coibion, O.: Innocent bystanders? monetary policy and inequality in the U.S. IMF Working Papers (2012)
Guvenen, F., Kaplan, G., Song, J.: How risky are recessions for top earners?. Amer. Econ. Rev. 104(5), 148–53 (2014a)
Guvenen, F., Ozkan, S., Song, J.: The nature of countercyclical income risk. J. Polit. Econ. 122(3), 621–660 (2014b)
Hendry, D.F.: Dynamics Econometrics. Oxford University Press, Oxford (1995)
Jäntti, M., Jenkins, S.P.: The impact of macroeconomic conditions on income inequality. J. Econ. Inequal. 8(2), 221–240 (2010)
Jenkins, S.P., Brandolini, A., Micklewright, J., Nolan, B.: The Great Recession and Its Consequences for Household Incomes in 21 Countries. In: Jenkins, S.P., Brandolini, A., Micklewright, J., Nolan, B. (eds.) The Great Recession and the Distribution of Household Income. Oxford University Press, Oxford (2013)
Jordà, O., Schularick, M., Taylor, A.M.: When credit bites back. J Money, Credit Banking 45(s2), 3–28 (2013)
Jordà, O., Schularick, M., Taylor, A.M.: Leveraged bubbles. J Monetary Econ. 76, S1–S20 (2015). Supplement Issue: November 7-8, 2014 Research Conference on Asset Price Fluctuations and Economic Policy
Kaplan, S.N., Rauh, J.: Wall Street and Main Street: what contributes to the rise in the highest incomes?. Rev. Financ. Stud. 23(3), 1004–1050 (2010)
Kirschenmann, K., Malinen, T., Nyberg, H.: The risk of financial crises: is there a role for income inequality?. J. Int. Money Financ. 68, 161–180 (2016)
Laeven, L., Valencia, F.: Systemic banking crises: A new database. Working Paper WP/08/1224, International Monetary Fund (2008)
Laeven, L., Valencia, F.: Resolution of Banking Crises: The Good, the Bad, and the Ugly. Working Paper WP/10/146, International Monetary Fund (2010)
Metcalf, C.E.: The size distribution of personal income during the business cycle. Am. Econ. Rev. 59(4), 657–668 (1969)
Mishkin, F.S., White, E.W.: US Stock Market Crashes and Their Aftermath: Implications for Monetary Policy. MIT Press, Cambridge (2003)
Morelli, S.: Banking Crises in the US: The Response of Top Income Shares in a Historical Perspective. Working Paper 359, Centre for Studies in Economics and Finance (2014)
Morelli, S., Atkinson, A.B.: Inequality and crises revisited. Economia Politica 32(1), 31–51 (2015)
Morelli, S., Smeeding, T., Thompson, J.: Post-1970 trends in within-country inequality and poverty. Handbook of Income Distribution, Volume 2, Elsevier. Atkinson and Bourguignon eds. (2015)
Neal, T.: Using panel co-integration methods to understand rising top income shares. Econ. Rec. 89(284), 83–98 (2013)
Nolan, B.: Unemployment and the size distribution of income. Economica 53 (212), 421–445 (1986)
Nolan, B.: Cyclical fluctuations in factor shares and the size distribution of income. Rev. Income Wealth 33(2), 193–210 (1987)
North, D.C.: Understanding the Process of Economic Change. Princeton University Press, Princeton (2005)
Parker, J.A., Vissing-Jorgensen, A.: Who bears aggregate fluctuations and how?. Am. Econ. Rev. 99(2), 399–405 (2009)
Parker, J.A., Vissing-Jorgensen, A.: The Increase in Income Cyclicality of High-Income Households and its Relation to the Rise in Top Income Shares. Working Paper 16577, National Bureau of Economic Research (2010)
Parker, S.C.: Opening a can of worms: the pitfalls of time-series regression analyses of income inequality. Appl. Econ. 32(2), 221–230 (2000)
Paul, P.: Historical Patterns of Inequality and Productivity around Financial Crises. Working Paper 2017-23, Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco (2017)
Pesaran, M.H., Smith, R.P.: Counterfactual analysis in macroeconometrics: An empirical investigation into the effects of quantitative easing. Working Paper 3879, CESifo Group Munich (2012)
Pesaran, M.H., Smith, R.P.: Counterfactual analysis in macroeconometrics: an empirical investigation into the effects of quantitative easing. Res. Econ. 70(2), 262–280 (2016)
Philippon, T., Reshef, A.: Skill Biased Financial Development: Education, Wages and Occupations in the U.S. Financial Sector. Working Paper 13437, National Bureau of Economic Research (2007)
Philippon, T., Reshef, A.: Wages and human capital in the US finance industry: 1909–2006. Quarterly J Econ. 127(4), 1551–1609 (2012)
Piketty, T., Saez, E.: Income inequality in the United States, 1913–1998. Quarterly J Econ. 118(1), 1–41 (2003)
Piketty, T., Saez, E.: The evolution of top incomes: a historical and international perspective. Amer. Econ. Rev. 96(2), 200–205 (2006)
Piketty, T., Saez, E.: Top incomes and the Great Recession: Recent evolutions and policy implications. IMF Econ. Rev. 61(3), 456–478 (2013)
Piketty, T., Saez, E., Stantcheva, S.: Optimal taxation of top labor incomes: a tale of three elasticities. Amer. Econ. J.: Econ. Policy 6(1), 230–71 (2014)
Piketty, T., Saez, E., Zucman, G.: Distributional national accounts: Methods and estimates for the United States data appendix. Q. J. Econ. 133(2), 553–609 (2018)
Reinhart, C.M.: This Time is Different Chartbook: Country Histories on Debt, Default, and Financial Crises. Working Paper 15815, National Bureau of Economic Research (2010)
Reinhart, C.M., Rogoff, K.: This Time is Different: Eight Centuries of Financial Folly. Princeton University Press, Princeton (2009)
Reinhart, C.M., Rogoff, K.S.: This Time is Different: A Panoramic View of Eight Centuries of Financial Crises. Working Paper 13882, National Bureau of Economic Research (2008)
Roine, J., Vlachos, J., Waldenström, D.: The long-run determinants of inequality: what can we learn from top income data?. J. Public Econ. 93(7), 974–988 (2009)
Romer, C.D., Romer, D.H.: Does monetary policy matter? a new test in the spirit of Friedman and Schwartz. In: NBER Macroeconomics Annual 1989, vol. 4, pp 121–184. MIT Press (1989)
Saez, E.: Reported incomes and marginal tax rates, 1960-2000: Evidence and policy implications. In: Tax Policy and the Economy, vol. 18, pp 117–174. MIT Press (2004)
Saez, E., Slemrod, J., Giertz, S.H.: The elasticity of taxable income with respect to marginal tax rates: a critical review. J. Econ. Lit. 50(1), 3–50 (2012)
Saez, E., Zucman, G.: Wealth inequality in the United States since 1913: evidence from capitalized income tax data. Quarterly J. Econ. 131(2), 519–578 (2016)
Sialm, C.: Tax changes and asset pricing. Am. Econ. Rev., 1356–1383 (2009)
Slemrod, J.: Tax Progressivity and Income Inequality. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge (1996)
Slemrod, J.: Does Atlas Shrug?: The Economic Consequences of Taxing the Rich. Harvard University Press, Cambridge (2000)
Thompson, J., Smeeding, T.M.: Country Case Study - USA. In: Jenkins, S.P., Brandolini, A., Micklewright, J., Nolan, B. (eds.) The Great Recession and the Distribution of Household Income, pp 202–233. Oxford University Press, Oxford (2013)
Thurow, L.C.: Analyzing the American income distribution. Am. Econ. Rev. 60 (2), 261–269 (1970)
Author information
Authors and Affiliations
Corresponding author
Additional information
This paper draws from a longer working paper version available as CSEF working paper N359. This current abridged version greatly benefited from the comments of the editor Cecilia Garcia-Penalosa and of two anonymous referees whose contributions were highly appreciated. I am deeply indebted to Tony Atkinson and warmly thank Sudhir Anand, Valentina Barca, Banu Demir, Mauro Caselli, Carolyn Fisher, Osea Giuntella, Brian Nolan, Felix Pretis, Mike Veall, David Vines and Daniel Waldenström for comments and suggestions on earlier versions of the paper.
Appendices
Appendix A: Methods and data
1.1 Detailed derivation of the impulse response functions
As described in the text, for every income group i under investigation, I define the information set at time t as \(\boldsymbol {\digamma }_{T}=\{{g^{i}_{t}}, X_{t}, BC_{t}\}\) for every t = (T, T − 1, T − 2, ...). I also define the set of ‘crisis off’ values as \(\boldsymbol {{\Theta }}^{0}_{T+s}=\{B{C^{0}_{T}}= 0,BC^{0}_{T + 1}= 0,..., BC^{0}_{T+s}= 0\}\), assuming that the banking crisis lasts for s + 1 years and begins at year T, where s = (0, 1, ... , S). I recall that the total impact of crisis on the inequality indicator under investigation (\(I_{T+h}^{G}\)) can be written as follows:
where \(g^{i}_{T+h}\) is the actual growth rate of the inequality indicatorFootnote 1 under analysis and \(E\{g^{i}_{T+h}/\boldsymbol {\digamma }_{T},\boldsymbol {{\Theta }}^{0}_{T+h}\}\) represents the objective of the estimation, namely the value of the growth rate of the inequality index under the condition of no crisis, which depends on the empirical specification. One can rewrite model (1) as follows:Footnote 2
and
The counterfactual can now be subtracted from \(g^{i}_{i,t}\) in order to obtain the realization of the IRF at the h’th period following the shock.
It is clear that one can ignore the last two terms only by assuming that the error term, the convariates and the whole set of parameters do not change with the occurrence of the crisis. Under these strict invariance assumptions, one obtains the following formula:
Under the invariance assumptions described above, the derivation of the realizations of the impulse response functions (IRFs) is straightforward.
As an illustration, I derive the first three realizations for the growth rate (this justifies the superscript G) of the inequality index under investigation for a specific income group i:
By cumulating those responses over time (for every year j > 0) one obtains the dynamic cumulated impact on the level of the index for every income group i, indicated as \(I^{L}_{i,j}\).
1.2 Data on stock market crashes, economic recessions, and currency crises
Data on currency crises are taken from Bordo et al. (2001) up to 1970 and from Laeven and Valencia (2010) thereafter. The currency crises identified occur in 1933, 1960, 1971, and 1985.
I further reconstructed information about stock market crashes based on the dates listed in Mishkin and White (2003) where the two authors, taking 1929 and 1987 as benchmarks, identify stock market crashes when an overall nominal decline of minimum 20% in the stock market index is recorded. The recent 2007 crash also fully qualifies as a market crash according to this criteria. Crash identification varies depending on the index used (Dow Jones, S&P500 or NASDAQ) and depending on the time window used to record a decline in share price. Using weekly data for the Dow Jones, only 1929 and 1987 are identified as crashes. Using a three-month window, crashes are identified in 1907, 1930–1932 and 1987 with Dow Jones, while S&P500 also identifies 1929 and NASDAQ 1987, among others. Using a one-year window and the Dow Jones, one could identify, among others, 1904, 1914, 1915, 1930–33 and 1988. S&P500 identifies 1907, 1917, and 1930–33. With the use of NASDAQ, one can also add 1984 as a crash year. Even though the analysis of Mishkin and White stops in early 2000, it is easy to check that the 12-month window would certainly list the year 2008 as a ‘crash’ year; Dow Jones went down more than 20% from the peak of October 2007 to July 2008 and by more than 50% to March 2009. In the end, and taking the work of Mishkin and White (2003) as a benchmark, I have identified the onset of 12 stock market crashes episodes: 1917, 1920, 1929, 1937, 1940, 1946, 1962, 1969, 1973, 1990, 2000, and 2007.
Finally, based on the official recording of the US economic cycles by the National Bureau of Economic Research (NBER), I record 17 contraction episodes.Footnote 3 More precisely, I record the following years as the onset year of an economic contraction: 1913, 1918, 1923, 1926, 1929, 1937, 1945, 1948, 1953, 1957, 1960, 1970, 1974, 1980, 1990, 2001, 2008.
1.3 Data on top marginal tax rates
Data on top marginal tax rates are taken from Sialm (2009) up to 2008. The top marginal tax rate is associated with the richest fractile (the Top 0.01%). Instead, for the income group at the bottom of the top decile (the Top 10–Top 5%) I make use of the marginal tax rate for income ranging from $100,000 to $250,000 (US 2008 dollars) always reported in Sialm (2009). The marginal tax rate for income higher than $250,000 is associated with the top decile (the Top 10%) as a whole.Footnote 4 In 2013, the top marginal tax rate increased back to its 1993 level (39.6%) for incomes above $400,000 (US 2012 dollars) and I use this information to update the series on marginal tax rates up to 2015 (no changes occur between 2008 and 2012 or between 2013 and 2015). In particular, I assume that the 2013 proportional change of marginal tax rates associated with the Top 10% and the Top 10–Top 5% is the same as that for the top marginal tax rate.
Appendix B: Tables and graphs
The impulse response to US banking crises on the levels of the Top 0.01% share. Models with no time trend and with additional regressors. Notes: The figure shows the impact of systemic banking crises on top 0.01% income share. The estimates of the dynamic effects are obtained from the estimation of ADL model using the growth rate of the top income share coefficient and general crisis dummy variables. Both panels use an empirical specification which is different from the baseline model (1). Panel a excludes the time trend from the model (1). Panel b, instead, augments model (1) with two additional regressors: the percentage change of the marginal net-of-tax rates and the average real world GDP per capita growth rate (excluding the US). The estimated parameters of the model served to calculate the Impulse Response Functions. The standard errors are derived using bootstrapping with 100 replications
The impulse response to different macroeconomic crises on the levels of the US Top 0.01% Share. Notes: The figure shows the impact of a variety of macroeconomic crises on the Top 0.01% income share. Macroeconomic crises include systemic banking crises (the baseline), stock market crashes, currency crises, and economic recessions. The estimates of the dynamic effects are obtained from the estimation of ADL model (1) using the growth rate of the top income share coefficient and general crisis dummy variables and time trend. The estimated parameters of the model served to calculate the Impulse Response Functions. The standard errors are derived using bootstrapping with 100 replications. We do not include stock market crashes episodes which coincide with the systemic banking crises or a world war (e.g., 1917, 1929, and 2007 crashes are excluded). Similarly, we do not include economic recessions episodes which coincide with the systemic banking crises or a world war (e.g., 1918, 1929, 1945, and 2008 recessions are excluded)
The impulse response to different macroeconomic crises on the levels of the US Top 1% wealth share. Notes: The figure shows the impact of systemic banking shocks, stock market crashes, currency crises, and economic recessions on the US Top 1% of nation net personal wealth. The estimates of the dynamic effects are obtained from the estimation of ADL model (1) using the growth rate of the top income share coefficient and general crisis dummy variables and time trend. The estimated parameters of the model served to calculate the Impulse Response Functions. The standard errors are derived using bootstrapping with 100 replications. The source of the data on the Top 1% wealth share is Saez and Zucman (2016). We do not include stock market crashes episodes which coincide with the systemic banking crises or a world war (e.g., 1917, 1929, and 2007 crashes are excluded). Similarly, we do not include economic recessions episodes which coincide with the systemic banking crises or a world war (e.g., 1918, 1929, 1945, and 2008 recessions are excluded)
Rights and permissions
About this article
Cite this article
Morelli, S. Banking crises in the US: the response of top income shares in a historical perspective. J Econ Inequal 16, 257–294 (2018). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10888-018-9387-9
Published:
Issue Date:
DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10888-018-9387-9
Keywords
- Systemic banking crises
- Top income shares
- US
- ADL
- Time series
- Impulse responses
- Pareto coefficient