Premature deindustrialization

Abstract

I document a significant deindustrialization trend in recent decades that goes considerably beyond the advanced, post-industrial economies. The hump-shaped relationship between industrialization (measured by employment or output shares) and incomes has shifted downwards and moved closer to the origin. This means countries are running out of industrialization opportunities sooner and at much lower levels of income compared to the experience of early industrializers. Asian countries and manufactures exporters have been largely insulated from those trends, while Latin American countries have been especially hard hit. Advanced economies have lost considerable employment (especially of the low-skill type), but they have done surprisingly well in terms of manufacturing output shares at constant prices. While these trends are not very recent, the evidence suggests both globalization and labor-saving technological progress in manufacturing have been behind these developments. The paper briefly considers some of the economic and political implications of these trends.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in to check access.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5
Fig. 6
Fig. 7

Notes

  1. 1.

    The bulk of R&D and patents originates from manufacturing. In Europe, for example, close to two-thirds of business R&D spending is done in manufacturing even though the sector is responsible for only 14–15 % of employment and value added in aggregate (Veugelers 2013, p. 8).

  2. 2.

    These numbers come from Timmer et al. (2014), which is the principal data source I will use in the paper.

  3. 3.

    See also Amirapu and Subramanian (2015), who document premature deindustrialization within Indian states.

  4. 4.

    The term seems to have been first used by Dasgupta and Singh (2006), although Kaldor (1966) made much earlier reference to early deindustrialization in the British context. I am grateful to Andre Nassif for the Kaldor reference.

  5. 5.

    This echoes the concern in the voluminous literature on the Dutch disease, that developing countries with comparative advantage in primary products would experience a squeeze on manufacturing as they open up to trade. See Corden (1984), van Wijnbergen (1984), and Sachs and Warner (1999).

  6. 6.

    The only exception is West Germany, for which there are no data after 1991 and constant-price series are at 1991 prices. Since all my regressions include country fixed effects, this difference in base year will be absorbed into the fixed effect for the country.

  7. 7.

    I am grateful to Jesus Felipe for making these data available to me.

  8. 8.

    These differences are statistically significant. The 95% confidence intervals for log incomes at which manufacturing shares peak, computed using the delta method, are as follows: manemp [8.45, 8.97]; nommva [8.79, 9.58], and realmva [10.16, 12.27]. The confidence interval for manemp (and nommva) does not overlap that for realmva. The series for manemp and nommva easily pass the Lind and Mehlum (2010) test for the presence of an inverse U-relationship in log GDP per capita, while realmva fails it because the extremum occurs outside the observed income range.

  9. 9.

    An alternative, and more efficient form of estimation would be to introduce periodXgroup dummies in a single, global regression. However, the results in Tables 4-6 suggest considerable heterogeneity in the estimated coefficients on population and income terms across groups. So allowing these coefficients to vary seems worth the price of potentially reduced power. Since the period dummies in the group-specific regressions are estimated tightly for the most part, the loss in efficiency does not appear to make much practical difference.

  10. 10.

    For a similar chart, see Felipe and Rhee 2014.

  11. 11.

    Amirapu and Subramanian (2015) present similar charts, using industrial employment data from the World Development Indicators.

  12. 12.

    For models of industrialization with increasing returns and inter-industry linkages, see also Rodríguez-Clare (1996), Venables (1996), and Rodrik (1996).

  13. 13.

    I assume that manufactures are the only goods that are traded. In reality, many services are also traded, and the share that crosses national borders has increased over time. Still, even though services dominate the domestic economy, they amount to less than a quarter of global trade. For measurement and other issues posed by trade in services, see World Trade Organization (WTO 2010).

  14. 14.

    Baumol and Bowen (1965) and Baumol (1967) are the classic works that looked at the consequences of lower productivity growth in services relative to manufactures.

  15. 15.

    Matsuyama (2009) shows that cross-country results have to be interpreted with caution when economies are globally integrated. In particular, faster productivity gains need not be correlated with more rapid decline in manufacturing across countries, even if productivity change is globally responsible for manufacturing’s decline. See also Uy et al. (2013) which develops a model with productivity and trade cost shocks under various assumptions about demand, and uses it to explain South Korea’s pattern of structural change. The authors find that non-homothetic demand, more rapid productivity growth in manufacturing, and the decline in manufacturing trade costs do a good job of explaining structural change, with the exception of the decline in manufacturing after 1990.

  16. 16.

    Aid inflows operate similarly to resource booms in so far as they drive up the price of non-traded goods, and reduce the relative price of manufactures. For an examination of these issues in the Sub-Saharan African and Latin American contexts, respectively, see Rajan and Subramanian (2011) and Palma (2014).

  17. 17.

    I am grateful to an anonymous referee who suggested the closed-economy analogy.

  18. 18.

    Young (November 2013 and forthcoming) raises some important questions about gaps in inter-sectoral productivity and in manufacturing versus nonmanufacturing productivity growth, arguing that these gaps may be due to selection based on unobserved worker skills. To the extent that manufacturing is more productive because it employs the more capable workers, it loses its “specialness.” In particular, more labor absorption in manufacturing would not raise economy-wide productivity, as marginal workers drawn into manufacturing would be of the lower-productivity type. Even if selection effects are present, however, it is not clear they can explain why manufacturing industries that are further away from the frontier experience more rapid labor productivity growth (as in Rodrik 2013). A recent paper by Franck and Galor (2015) suggests early industrialization may have adverse long-run effects, within a country: these authors find that regions in France that adopted industrial technology earlier eventually ended up with lower incomes and human capital levels. It is not clear what the implications of such results to growth patterns across countries are, however. France is a post-industrial country, and the cross-region findings are conditional on industrialization and within-country convergence having taken place.

  19. 19.

    A full welfare evaluation of the trends discussed in this paper must take into account other effects in addition to the foregone productivity gains due to premature deindustrialization. For developing countries that are net importers of manufactures, the global reduction in the relative price of manufactures due to technological progress in advanced countries represents a terms-of-trade benefit and a (static) welfare gain. (For developing countries that are net exporters of manufactures, there is a corresponding terms-of-trade loss.) The fall in manufacturing prices may also reduce the cost of capital-goods in developing countries, and thereby spur investment. Where private investment is sub-optimal due to credit-market or other failures, this would represent an additional source of welfare gain. It is in principle possible to attach some quantitative magnitudes for representative countries to each one of these effects, using the results here and in Rodrik (2013). However, such an effort would take this paper too far afield, and I leave it to future work.

  20. 20.

    It is possible that these trends will be reversed, as manufacturing migrates from Asia to low-wage countries. Anecdotal evidence (e.g. the rise of Chinese manufacturing investment in countries such as Ethiopia and Rwanda) as well as some of the more systematic evidence in McMillan et al. (2014) suggest that manufacturing may have a renewal of sorts in Sub-Saharan Africa. But the fact that we rarely see double humps in the manufacturing curve should make us skeptical of this eventuality.

  21. 21.

    On Africa, for example, see African Center for Economic Transformation (2014), which emphasizes the need for productive diversification and structural transformation if recent growth rates are to be sustained.

  22. 22.

    I show in Rodrik (2014) that the vast majority of the countries that experienced growth rates of 4.5 percent or more for at least three decades are those that underwent rapid industrialization. The list is composed essentially of two categories of countries: some in the European periphery during the 1950s and 1960s (e.g., Spain, Portugal, Israel), and some in East Asia since the 1960s (e.g., South Korea, Taiwan, Malaysia). The exceptions are some small, but resource-rich countries (e.g., Botswana, Oman, Equatorial Guinea), many of which experienced reversals eventually. In that paper, I propose a framework that distinguishes between two channels of growth, with overlapping but distinct requirements: a “fundamentals” channel that relies on the accumulation of economy-wide skills and institutional capabilities, and a “structural transformation” channel that relies on industrialization. I argue that slow-to-moderate growth is possible with the former, but that rapid convergence requires the latter.

References

  1. Acemoglu, D., & Robinson, J. (2009). Economic origins of dictatorship and democracy. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  2. African Center for Economic Transformation. (2014). Africa Transformation Report, 2014. Accra, Ghana.

  3. Amirapu, A., & Subramanian, A. (2015). Manufacturing or services? An indian illustration of a development dilemma. Washington, DC: Center for Global Development and Peterson Institute.

    Google Scholar 

  4. Baumol, W. J. (1967). Macroeconomics of unbalanced growth: The anatomy of urban crisis. The American Economic Review, 57(3), 415–426.

    Google Scholar 

  5. Baumol, W. J., & Bowen, W. G. (1965). On the performing arts: The anatomy of their economic problems. The American Economic Review, 55(1/2), 495–502.

    Google Scholar 

  6. Buera, F. J., & Kaboski, J. P. (2009). Can traditional theories of structural change fit the data? Journal of the European Economic Association, 7(2—-3), 469–477.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  7. Corden, W. M. (1984). Booming sector and Dutch disease economics: Survey and consolidation. Oxford Economic Papers, New Series, 36(3), 359–380.

    Google Scholar 

  8. Dasgupta, S., & Singh, A. (2006). Manufacturing, services and premature deindustrialization in developing countries: A Kaldorian analysis. UNU-WIDER, United Nations University Research Paper, No. 2006/49.

  9. de Vries, K., Timmer, M. P., & de Vries, G. J. (2013). Structural transformation in Africa: Static gains, dynamic losses, GGDC research memorandum GD-136. Groningen Growth and Development Centre, University of Groningen.

  10. Felipe, J., Mehta, A., & Rhee, C. (2014). Manufacturing matters... but it’s the jobs that count. Asian Development Bank Economics Working Paper Series, No. 420.

  11. Foellmi, R., & Zweimuller, J. (2008). Structural change. Engel’s consumption cycles and Kaldor’s facts of economic growth. Journal of Monetary Economics, 55, 1317–1328.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  12. Franck, R., & Galor, O. (2015). Is industrialization conducive to long-run prosperity? Brown University, unpublished paper.

  13. Kaldor, N. (1966). Causes of the slow rate of economic growth of the United Kingdom: An inaugural lecture. Cambridge (England): Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  14. Lawrence, R. Z., & Edwards, L. (2013). US Employment deindustrialization: Insights from history and the international experience. Peterson Institute for International Economics, Policy Brief No. PB13-27.

  15. Lind, J. T., & Mehlum, H. (2010). With or without u? Theappropriate test for a U-shaped relationship. OxfordBulletin of Economics and Statistics, 72(1), 109–118.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  16. Maddison, A. (2009). Statistics on World Population, GDP and Per Capita GDP, 1-2008 AD. Available at http://www.ggdc.net/maddison/oriindex.htm.

  17. Matsuyama, K. (1992). Agricultural productivity, comparative advantage, and economic growth. Journal of Economic Theory, 58(2), 317–334.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  18. Matsuyama, K. (2009). Structural change in an interdependent world: A global view of manufacturing decline. Journal of the European Economic Association, 7(2—-3), 478–486.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  19. Margaret, M., & Rodrik, D. (2011). Globalization, structural change, and economic growth. In M. Bachetta & M. Jansen (Eds.), Making globalization socially sustainable. Geneva: International Labor Organization and World Trade Organization.

    Google Scholar 

  20. McMillan, M., Rodrik, D., & Verduzco-Gallo, Í. (2014). Globalization, structural change, and productivity growth, with an update on Africa. World Development, 63, 11–32.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  21. Mukand, S., & Rodrik D. (2015). The political economy of liberal democracy. Unpublished paper.

  22. Ngai, L. R., & Pissarides, C.A. (2004). Structural change in a multi-sector model of growth. Center for Economic Performance, London School of Economics.

  23. Nickell, S., Redding, S., & Swaffield, J. (2008). The uneven pace of deindustrialization in the OECD. Center for Economic Performance, London School of Economics.

  24. Palma, J. G. (2014). Industrialization, ‘premature’ deindustrialization and the Dutch disease. Revista NECAT, 3(5), 7–23.

    Google Scholar 

  25. Rodríguez-Clare, A. (1996). The division of labor and economic development. Journal of Development Economics, 49(1), 3–32.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  26. Rodrik, D. (1996). Coordination failures and government policy: A model with applications to East Asia and Eastern Europe. Journal of International Economics, 40(1–2), 1–22.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  27. Rodrik, D. (2013). Unconditional convergence in manufacturing. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 128(1), 165–204.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  28. Rodrik, D. (2014). The past, present, and future of economic growth. In F. Allen, et al., Towards a better global economy: Policy Implications for Citizens Worldwide in the 21st Century. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

  29. Sachs, J. D., & Warner, A. M. (1999). The big push, natural resource booms and growth. Journal of Development Economics, 59(1), 43–76.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  30. Timmer, Marcel P., de Vries, G.J., & de Vries, K. (2014). “Patterns ofStructural Change in Developing Countries,” Groningen Growth andDevelopment Center Research Memorandum 149.

  31. Timmer, M. P. (Ed.). (2014). The world input-output database (WIOD): Contents, sources and methods. WIOD Working Paper Number 10.

  32. Uy, T., Yi, K.-M., & Zhang, J. (2013). Structural change in an open economy. Journal of Monetary Economics, 60(6), 667–682.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  33. van Wijnbergen, S. (1984). The ‘dutch disease’: A disease after all?’. The Economic Journal, 94(373), 41–55.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  34. Venables, A. J. (1996). Trade policy, cumulative causation, and industrial development. Journal of Development Economics, 49(1), 179–197.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  35. Veugelers, R. (Ed.). (2013). Manufacturing Europe’s future. Brussels: Bruegel.

  36. World Trade Organization (2010). Measuring trade in services. Geneva: WTO.

  37. Young, A. Structural transformation, the mismeasurement of productivity growth, and the cost disease of services. American Economic Review, forthcoming.

  38. Young, A. (2013). Inequality, the urban-rural gap, and migration. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 128, 1727–1785.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

I am grateful to Elias Sanchez-Eppler, Russell Morton, and Juan Obach for expert research assistance, Robert Lawrence and Arvind Subramanian for useful conversations, David Romer for comments, and Jesus Felipe for sharing his data set. Four referees have provided very constructive suggestions that led to improvements.

Author information

Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Dani Rodrik.

Appendix

Appendix

Country and variable coverage in the GGDC 10-Sector Database

Acronym Country Value added in current prices Value added in constant prices Employment by sector
Sub-Saharan Africa     
   BWA Botswana 1964–2010 1964–2010 1964–2010
   ETH Ethiopia 1961–2010 1961–2010 1961–2010
   GHA Ghana 1960–2010 1960–2010 1960–2010
   KEN Kenya 1960–2010 1964–2010 1969–2010
   MWI Malawi 1960–2010 1966–2010 1966–2010
   MUS Mauritius 1960–2010 1970–2010 1970–2010
   NGA Nigeria 1960–2010 1960–2010 1960–2011
   NGA(alt) Nigeria (2014 GDP revision) 2010–2013 2010–2013 (in 2010 prices)  
   SEN Senegal 1960–2010 1970–2010 1970–2010
   ZAF South Africa 1960–2010 1960–2010 1960–2010
   TZA Tanzania 1960–2010 1960–2010 1960–2010
   ZMB Zambia 1960–2010 1965–2010 1965–2010
North Africa     
   EGY Egypt 1960–2013 1960–2012 1960–2012
   MOR Morocco 1970–2012 1960-2012 1960–2012
Asia     
   CHN China 1952–2011 1952–2010 1952–2011
   HKG Hong Kong 1970–2011 1974–2011 1974–2011
   IND India 1950–2012 1950–2012 1960–2010
   IDN Indonesia 1966–2012 1960–2012 1961–2012
   JPN Japan 1953–2011 1953–2011 1953–2012
   KOR South Korea 1953–2011 1953–2011 1963–2011
   MYS Malaysia 1970–2011 1970–2011 1975–2011
   PHL Philippines 1971–2012 1971–2012 1971–2012
   SGP Singapore 1970–2012 1960–2012 1970–2011
   TWN Taiwan 1951–2012 1961–2012 1963–2012
   THA Thailand 1951–2011 1951–2011 1960–2011
Latin America     
   ARG Argentina 1950–2011 1950–2011 1950–2011
   BOL Bolivia 1958–2011 1950–2011 1950–2010
   BRA Brazil 1990–2011 1950–2011 1950–2011
   CHL Chile 1950–2011 1950–2011 1950–2012
   COL Colombia 1950–2011 1950–2011 1950–2010
   CRI Costa Rica 1950–2011 1950-2011 1950–2011
   MEX Mexico 1950–2011 1950–2011 1950–2012
   PER Peru 1950–2011 1950–2011 1960–2011
   VEN Venezuela 1960–2012 1950–2012 1950–2011
North America     
   USA United States of America 1947–2010 1947–2010 1950–2010
Europe     
   DEW West Germany 1968–1991 1950–1991 (1991 prices) 1950–1991
   DNK Denmark 1970–2011 1947–2009 1948–2011
   ESP Spain 1970–2011 1947–2009 1950–2011
   FRA France 1970–2011 1950–2009 1950–2011
   GBR United Kingdom 1960–2011 1949–2009 1948–2011
   ITA Italy 1970–2011 1951–2009 1951–2011
   NLD The Netherlands 1970–2011 1949–2009 1950–2011
   SWE Sweden 1970–2011 1950–2009 1950–2011

Source Timmer et al. (2014). See http://www.rug.nl/research/ggdc/data/10-sector-database

Countries included in the Socio Economic Accounts of the World Input-Output Database (WIOD)

Austria, Germany, Netherlands, Canada, China, Belgium, Greece, Poland, United States, India, Bulgaria, Hungary, Portugal, Japan, Cyprus, Ireland, Romania, South Korea, Czech Republic, Italy, Slovak Republic, Australia, Denmark, Latvia, Slovenia, Brazil, Taiwan, Estonia, Lithuania, Spain, Mexico, Turkey, Finland, Luxembourg, Sweden, Indonesia, France, Malta, United Kingdom, Russia.

Source Timmer (2012), latest update available at http://www.wiod.org/protected3/data/update_sep12/SEA%20Sources_June2014.pdf.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and Permissions

About this article

Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Rodrik, D. Premature deindustrialization. J Econ Growth 21, 1–33 (2016). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10887-015-9122-3

Download citation

Keywords

  • Deindustrialization
  • Industrialization
  • Economic growth

JEL classification

  • 014