Journal of Economic Growth

, Volume 20, Issue 4, pp 333–363 | Cite as

Democracy, education and the quality of government

Article

Abstract

This paper looks at how the interaction between democracy and education affects the quality of government. Using various cross-sectional and dynamic panel data specifications, we show that the success of democratic institutions is closely related to the educational attainment of the population. Democratic elections do not foster the quality of government in countries with low average levels of education. Education, in turn, has a positive effect on the quality of government only in consolidated democracies.

Keywords

Education Democracy Quality of government Corruption Elections Institutions 

JEL Classification

D72 D73 H11 O43 

Notes

Acknowledgments

We would like to thank without implications Oded Galor (the editor), five anonymous referees, Graziella Bertocchi, Ennio Bilancini, Alberto Chong, Aart Kraay, Florencio López de Silanes, Torsten Persson, Giacomo Ponzetto, Prakash Singh and seminar participants at Universidad de Navarra, Università degli Studi di Roma “La Sapienza,” Università di Modena e Reggio Emilia, Université de Neuchâtel, and the Hotelling seminar (ADIS – ENS CACHAN) for useful comments and suggestions. We would also like to thank Matteo Bobba and Decio Coviello for sharing their code for the incremental OID test. The views expressed in this paper are the authors’ only and need not reflect, and should not be represented as, the views of any of the institutions that the authors are affiliated with.

Compliance with ethical standards

Conflicts of Interest

The authors declare that they have no conflict of interest.

References

  1. Acemoglu, D., Johnson, S., & Robinson, J. (2001). The colonial origins of comparative development: An empirical investigation. American Economic Review, 91(5), 1369–1401.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  2. Acemoglu, D., Johnson, S., Robinson, J., & Yared, P. (2008). Income and democracy. American Economic Review, 98(3), 808–842.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  3. Ades, A., & Di Tella, R. (1999). Rents, competition, and corruption. American Economic Review, 89(4), 982–993.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  4. Adserà, A., Boix, C., & Payne, M. (2003). Are you being served? Political accountability and quality of government. Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization, 19(2), 445–490.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  5. Alesina, A., & Giuliano, P. (2011). Family ties and political participation. Journal of the European Economic Association, 9(5), 817–839.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  6. Almond, G., & Verba, S. (1989, 1963). The civic culture: Political attitudes and democracy in five nations. Newbury Park: Sage Publication.Google Scholar
  7. Altonji, J., Elder, T., & Taber, C. (2005). Selection on observed and unobserved variables: Assessing the effectiveness of Catholic schools. Journal of Political Economy, 113(1), 151–184.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  8. Arellano, M., & Bond, S. (1991). Some tests of specification for panel data: Monte Carlo evidence and an application to employment equations. Review of Economic Studies, 58(2), 277–297.MATHCrossRefGoogle Scholar
  9. Arellano, M., & Bover, O. (1995). Another look at the instrumental variable estimation of error-components models. Journal of Econometrics, 68(1), 29–51.MATHCrossRefGoogle Scholar
  10. Banfield, E. C. (1958). The moral basis of a backward society. New York: The Free Press.Google Scholar
  11. Barro, R. J. (1973). The control of politicians: An economic model. Public Choice, 14, 19–42.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  12. Barro, R. J. (1996). Democracy and growth. Journal of Economic Growth, 1(1), 1–27.MATHMathSciNetCrossRefADSGoogle Scholar
  13. Barro, R. J. (2000). Rule of law, democracy, and economic performance. In M. Miles, et al. (Eds.), 2000 index of economic freedom. Washington: The Heritage Foundation.Google Scholar
  14. Barro, R.J. & Lee, J.-W. (2010). A new data set of educational attainment in the world, 1950–2010. NBER Working Paper No. 15902.Google Scholar
  15. Besley, T., & Burgess, R. (2002). The political economy of government responsiveness: Theory and evidence from India. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 117(4), 1415–1452.MATHCrossRefGoogle Scholar
  16. Besley, T., & Coate, S. (1997). An economic model of represenative democracy. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 112(1), 85–114.MATHCrossRefGoogle Scholar
  17. Besley, T., & Persson, T. (2011). Pillars of prosperity: The political economics of development clusters. Princeton: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
  18. Besley, T., Persson, T., & Sturm, D. (2005). Political competition and economic performance: Theory and evidence from the United States. NBER No. 11484.Google Scholar
  19. Besley, T., & Prat, A. (2006). Handcuffs for the grabbing hand? Media capture and government accountability. American Economic Review, 96(3), 720–736.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  20. Blundell, R., & Bond, S. (1998). Initial conditions and moment restrictions in dynamic panel data models. Journal of Econometrics, 87(1), 115–143.MATHCrossRefGoogle Scholar
  21. Bobba, M., & Coviello, D. (2007). Weak instruments and weak identification, in estimating the effects of education, on democracy. Economics Letters, 96(3), 301–306.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  22. Bond, S., Hoeffler, A. & Temple, J. (2001). GMM estimation of empirical growth models. CEPR Discussion Papers 3048, C.E.P.R. Discussion Papers.Google Scholar
  23. Bourguignon, F., Ferreira, F., & Menendez, M. (2007). Inequality of opportunities in Brazil. Review of Income Wealth, 53(4), 585–618.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  24. Carbone, G. (2009). The consequences of democratization. Journal of Democracy, 20(2), 123–137.MathSciNetCrossRefGoogle Scholar
  25. Caselli, F., & Morelli, M. (2004). Bad politicians. Journal of Public Economics, 71(3), 829–853.Google Scholar
  26. Cervellati, M., Fortunato, P., & Sunde, U. (2008). Hobbes to Rousseau: Inequality, institutions and development. Economic Journal, 118(531), 1354–1384.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  27. Cervellati, M., Fortunato, P., & Sunde, U. (2014). Democratization and civil liberties: The role of violence during the transition. European Economic Review, 66, 226–247.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  28. Chong, A., & Gradstein, M. (2009). Education and democratic preferences. RES Working Papers 4627, Inter-American Development Bank, Research Department.Google Scholar
  29. Djankov, S., Glaeser, E., La Porta, R., Lopez-de-Silanes, F., & Shleifer, A. (2003). The new comparative economics. Journal of Comparative Economics, Elsevier, 31(4), 595–619.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  30. Djankov, S., Glaeser, E., La Porta, R., Lopez-de-Silanes, F., & Shleifer, A. (2010). Disclosure by politicians. American Economic Journal: Applied Economics, 2, 179–209.Google Scholar
  31. Fearon, J. D. (2003). Ethnic and Cultural Diversity by Country. Journal of Economic Growth, 8(2), 195–222.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  32. Ferejohn, J. (1986). Incumbent performance and electoral control. Public Choice, 50, 5–25.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  33. Finan, F., & Schecter, L. (2009). Vote-buying and reciprocity. BREAD Working Paper No. 214.Google Scholar
  34. Fortunato, P., & Panizza, U. (2011). Democracy, education and the quality of government. POLIS Working Paper 155.Google Scholar
  35. Glaeser, E., La Porta, R., Lopez-de-Silanes, F., & Shleifer, A. (2004). Do institutions cause growth? Journal of Economic Growth, 9(3), 271–303.MATHCrossRefGoogle Scholar
  36. Glaeser, E., Ponzetto, M., & Shleifer, A. (2006). Why does democracy need education? Journal of Economic Growth, 12(2), 77–99.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  37. Hall, R.E., & Jones, C.I. (1999). Why do some countries produce so much more output per worker than others? Quarterly Journal of Economics, 114(1), 83–116.Google Scholar
  38. Huntington, S., & Nelson, J. (1976). No easy choice: Political participation in developing countries. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  39. Jaimovich, D., & Panizza, U. (2006). Procyclicality or reverse causality? RES Working Papers 4508, Inter-American Development Bank, Research Department.Google Scholar
  40. John, P., Liu, H., & Fieldhouse, E. (2010). The civic culture in Britain and America fifty years on. IPEG Paper 2010-06.Google Scholar
  41. Jowett, B. (1941). The republic by Plato. New York: The Modern Library.Google Scholar
  42. Kaufmann, D., Kraay, A., & Mastruzzi, M. (2010). The worldwide governance indicators: Methodology and analytical issues. Policy Research Working Paper Series 5430, The World Bank.Google Scholar
  43. Knack, S., & Keefer, P. (1995). Institutions and economic performance: Cross-country tests using alternative institutional measures. Economics and Politics, 7(3), 207–227.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  44. Knack, S., & Keefer, P. (1997). Does social capital have an economic payoff? A cross-country investigation. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 112(7), 1251–1288.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  45. La Porta, R., Lopez-de-Silanes, F., Shleifer, A., & Vishny, R. (1999). The quality of government. Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization, 5(1), 222–279.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  46. Mauro, P. (1995). Corruption and growth. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 3(110), 681–712.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  47. Milligan, K., Moretti, E., & Oreopoulos, P. (2004). Does education improve citizenship? Evidence from the US and the UK. Journal of Public Economics, 88(3), 1667–1695.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  48. Ostrom, E. (2006). A frequently overlooked precondition of democracy: Citizens knowledgeable about and engaged in collective action. In Geoffrey Brennan (Ed.), Preconditions of democracy, the Tampere club series (Vol. 2, pp. 75–89). Tampere: Tampere University Press.Google Scholar
  49. Ozer Balli, H., & Sørensen, B. (2013). Interaction effects in econometrics. Empirical Economics, 45(1), 583–603.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  50. Papaioannou, E., & Siouraounis, G. (2008). Democratization and growth. Economic Journal, 118, 1520–1551.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  51. Panizza, U. (2001). Electoral rules, political systems, and institutional quality. Economics and Politics, 13(3), 311–342.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  52. Panizza, U. (2009). Public administration and institutions in Latin America: Alternative view paper. In B. Lomborg (Ed.), Latin American development priorities. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
  53. Persson, T., & Tabellini, G. (2006). Democracy and development: The devil in the details. American Economic Review, 96, 319–324.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  54. Persson, T., & Tabellini, G. (2008). The growth effect of democracy: Is it heterogeneous and how can it be estimated? In E. Helpman (Ed.), Institutions and economic performance. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
  55. Persson, T., & Tabellini, G. (2009). Democratic capital: The nexus of political and economic change. American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics, 1(2), 88–126.Google Scholar
  56. Pritchett, L. (2013). The rebirth of education. Schooling ain’t learning. Washington, DC: Brooking Institutions Press.Google Scholar
  57. Przeworski, A., Alvarez, M. E., Cheibub, J. A., & Limongi, F. (2000). Democracy and development. Political institutions and well-being in the world, 1950–1990. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  58. Poutvaara, P., & Takalo, T. (2007). Candidate quality. International Tax and Public Finance, 14, 7–27.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  59. Putnam, R. (1993). Making democracy work, civic traditions in modern Italy. Princeton: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
  60. Rice, T. W., & Sumberg, A. F. (1997). Civic culture and government performance in the American states. Publius, 27(1), 99–114.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  61. Rivera-Batiz, F. (2002). Democracy, goverance and economic growth: Theory and evidence. Review of Development Economics, 6(2), 225–247.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  62. Rodrik, D., & Wacziarg, R. (2005). Do democratic transitions produce bad economic outcomes? American Economic Review, 95(3), 50–55.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  63. Roodman, D. (2009). A note on the theme of too many instruments. Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics, 71, 135–158.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  64. Shields, T. G., & Goidel, R. K. (1997). Participation rates, socioeconomic class biases, and congressional elections: A cross-validation, 1958–1994. American Journal of Political Science, 41, 683–691.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  65. Sen, A. (2000). Development as freedom. New York: Alfred A. Knopf.Google Scholar
  66. Sunde, U., Cervellati, M., & Fortunato, P. (2008). Are all democracies equally good? The role of interactions between political environment and inequality for rule of law. Economics Letters, 99(3), 552–556. 2008.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  67. Tabellini, G. (2010). Culture and institutions: Economic development in the regions of Europe. Journal of the European Economic Association, 8(4), 677–716.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  68. Vanhanen, T. (2003a). Democratization and power resources 1850–2000. Tampere: Department of Political Science and International Relations, Finnish Social Science Data Archive, University of Tampere.Google Scholar
  69. Vanhanen, T. (2003b). Democratization: A comparative analysis of 170 countries. London: Routledge.Google Scholar
  70. Verba, S., Schlozman, L., & Brady, H. E. (1995). Voice and equality: Civic voluntarism in American politics. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
  71. Windmeijer, F. (2005). A finite sample correction for the variance of linear efficient two-step GMM estimators. Journal of Econometrics, 126(1), 25–51.MathSciNetCrossRefGoogle Scholar
  72. Wolfinger, R., & Rosenstone, S. J. (1980). Who votes?. New Haven: Yale University Press.Google Scholar

Copyright information

© Springer Science+Business Media New York 2015

Authors and Affiliations

  1. 1.United Nations Conference on Trade and Development (UNCTAD)GenevaSwitzerland
  2. 2.Université de NeuchâtelNeuchâtelSwitzerland
  3. 3.Department of International EconomicsThe Graduate Institute of International and Development StudiesGeneve 21Switzerland
  4. 4.Centre for Economic Policy ResearchLondonUK

Personalised recommendations