Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Modern gender roles and agricultural history: the Neolithic inheritance

  • Published:
Journal of Economic Growth Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This research proposes the hypothesis that societies with long histories of agriculture have less equality in gender roles as a consequence of more patriarchal values and beliefs regarding the proper role of women in society. We test this hypothesis in a world sample of countries, in a sample of European regions, as well as among immigrants and children of immigrants living in the US. This evidence reveals a significant negative relationship between years of agriculture and female labor force participation rates, as well as other measures of equality in contemporary gender roles. This finding is robust to the inclusion of an extensive set of possible confounders, including historical plough-use and the length of the growing season. We argue that two mechanisms can explain the result: (1) societies with longer agricultural histories had a higher level of technological advancement which in the Malthusian Epoch translated into higher fertility and a diminished role for women outside the home; (2) the transition to cereal agriculture led to a division of labor in which women spend more time on processing cereals rather than working in the field.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. For examples of other research papers in which gender plays a role see Galor and Weil (1996), Klasen (2002), Miller (2008), or Doepke and Tertilt (2009, 2011).

  2. Patriarchy is defined by the dominance of males in social, economic, and political organization (Iversen and Rosenbluth 2010, p. 17).

  3. While the analyses for the world sample and the European sample are carried out on data relatively close to the present, the US data cover the periods 1850–1880, 1900–1930 and 1950–1970. The US analysis, therefore, simultaneously allow us to exploit individual level data, and permit us to evaluate the validity of our findings across time.

  4. In line with this view, Lerner (1986) associates the origin of partriarchy with the Neolithic Revolution and argues that: “sometime during the agricultural revolution relatively egalitarian societies with a sexual division of labor based on biological necessity gave way to more highly structured societies [...]. The more complex societies featured a division of labor no longer based only on biological necessity, but also on hierarchy and the power of some men over other men and all women.” Moreover, Dyble et al. (2015) provide evidence of gender equality in hunter-gathering societies and also associate the rise of gender inequality with agricutural societies in which heritable resources became important fo reproductive success.

  5. We pay special focus to these two mechanisms, though one could also posit other mechanisms e.g. related to the general rise in inequality or religion. We discuss this more below.

  6. The \(\ne \)Kade San of the Kalahari is an example of hunter-gatherers that survive without animal food, but not vegetable food (Tanaka 1976, p. 13).

  7. This denotes the situation in which a married couple settles with the wife’s family.

  8. Recent evidence from skeletons of Central European farmers in the early Neolithic suggests patrilocality, which denotes the situation in which a married couple settle with the husband’s family (Bentley et al. 2012).

  9. This is also true for most of the Americas with the main exception of Venezuela and the Caribbean where early agriculture was based on the manioc root.

  10. Tilling includes a range of activities from preparing the soil to the actual planting of seed. Timbering refers to land clearance activites. Peterson (2002, p. 110) stresses that tilling the soil with hoe, digging stick, or adze would require repetitive downward blows involving forearm flexion and extension.

  11. For the European subsamples we can plausibly interpret the transition to agriculture as a transition to cereal-based plough agriculture. The reason is that the transition to agriculture and the transition to plough agriculture practically coincide in Europe, as “agriculture and the plough originated 10–13 millennia ago in the Fertile Crescent of the Near East [...] and were introduced into Greece and southeastern Europe 8000 years ago”, Lai (2007, p. 1). Further, Fussell (1966, p. 177) notes that the plough known as a crook ard “was commonly used by farmers all over Europe from Scandinavia to the Mediterranean during the late Neolithic Age and the Bronze Age.” The European evidence is in line with the hypothesis of Alesina et al. (2013) on years of plough agriculture.

  12. This literature highlights the importance of early agricultural adoption on comparative economic development on a worldwide scale. The empirical analysis in Olsson and Hibbs (2005) supports this type of hypothesis formulated in the work of Diamond (1997). In addition, using a refined measure on the timing of the Neolithic Revolution from Putterman and Trainor (2006), Putterman (2008), Petersen and Skaaning (2010), and Bleaney and Dimico (2011) confirms the importance of early agricultural development. However, as suggested by Galor (2011) and indicated by Olsson and Paik (2012), these results seem to be explained by between-continent variation in economic development, which is also in the spirit of Diamond’s hypothesis. Our basic result is, on the other hand, strengthened when allowing for continental fixed effects in the regressions.

  13. These observations are arguably not made on pre-historic hunter-gatherers, but on those societies that did not move to agriculture. Yet, as pointed out by Marlowe (2005, p. 54), “the ethnographic record of foragers provides the only direct observations of human behavior in the absence of agriculture.”

  14. As illustrated by the case study below, gender roles are not that rigid in all hunter-gatherer societies.

  15. As noted above, Tanaka (1976) finds that the \(\ne \)Kade obtain around 81.3 % of their diet from vegetable foods. Gould (1977, p. 2) finds for the case of aborigines of Australia that “about 90 % of the time women furnish at least 80 % of food available to the group as a whole.”

  16. We obtain similar results when using probit or logit models.

  17. Andersen (2007) notes that these systems date back to 3000 BC for bride price and 200 BC for dowry and the societies in which they arose were based on agriculture. Thus, it is hardly surprising that they are less prevalent in hunter-gatherer societies.

  18. We do not report this result, but it is available upon request.

  19. Korotayev (2003) presents evidence that non-matrilocality is very likely in societies where women contribute very little to subsistence. This suggests that postmarital residence and subsistence contributions are related.

  20. Ember (1975, 1978) argued that among hunter-gatherers, patrilocality is the most common settlement pattern. This is not the line we take, as we compare marriage patterns between societies that rely on hunting or gathering to varying degrees. Yet, we want to point out that Alvarez (2004) has analyzed the sources of the data in Ember (1975), and finds that, after careful revision, bilocality is a much more common settlement pattern. This is also more in line with the direct observations of ethnologists and a relatively high level of gender equality.

  21. We use an outcome based on variable 11 in the Ethnographic Atlas. This variable indicates the location of the couple after the first years of marriage. Briffault (1927, pp. 302–303) notes that in many of the cases he observed, marriage is not permanently matrilocal, but in some cases lasts only months and in others years. The alternative variable 13 which does not record a number of years in the Atlas reveals no tendency for either marriage pattern to be more likely in hunter- gatherer societies. This suggests that these societies practice some degree of matrilocality but that it is not permanent. This is consistent with limited gender inequality.

  22. The !Kung are also referred to as Ju/’hoansi; see Kent (1995, p. 513).

  23. They are also referred to as the people from the “Dobe area” of Ngamiland, Botswana.

  24. A case study is by construction only one point, so many additional factors could have been in play. It is for example conceivable that the mentioned Bantu farmers had been influenced by e.g. Europeans and migrants with origins in the Fertile Crescent. We investigate these factors further in Sect. 6.4.

  25. This would imply that in terms of contributions to subsistence men would add more due to increased participation in harvesting with cereal based agriculture.

  26. Other plausible mechanisms exist. As pointed out by an anonymous reviewer, important consequences of sedentary agriculture were the notion of storing goods and the notion of private property. Since root crops are less portable and are more perishable, these are easier to implement with cereal crops. This is in line with the narrative in Lerner (1986), who note that men were able to have control over surplus food.

  27. While this paper mainly highlights the common effect of cereal crops, recent research suggests that the type of cereal crop may matter for cultural attitudes (Talhelm et al. 2014). In this paper, we control in some regressions for different types of cereals according to whether they are plough positive or plough negative.

  28. This is in line with the Neolithic Revolution bringing around an upper class of intellectuals and rulers which would play a role in enforcing social norms. In the Chinese case discussed below, the Neolithic Revolution arguably brought about Confucius and his followers who helped establish patriarchal values based on the pre-existing gender division of labor. Patriarchy was not invented by Confucius, as it also arose in other parts of the world.

  29. Empirically, much evidence exists which favors the demic-diffusion model, but according to Gkiasta et al. (2003), there is also evidence of the cultural-diffusion model where adoption of agriculture is due to incoming ideas rather than people.

  30. Schvaneveldt et al. (2005, p. 77) state that “Historically, gender roles and family relationships in Middle Eastern culture have been very traditional and steeped in beliefs and customs stemming from Islam.” This indicates that Middle Eastern patriarchy is not of recent date.

  31. As noted previously, this is not the only difference between hunter-gatherer and farming societies.

  32. Given the theoretical background, we note that the effect may not be so strong for the Americas given the presence of societies that moved to root-based agriculture.

  33. In particular, Pinhasi et al. (2005) provide carbon dates from various Neolithic sites in Europe. From this, we obtain average transition dates of each NUTS 2 region in ArcGIS. See also Fig. 2 for a map depicting these data.

  34. Regions follow Eurostat’s definition of regions at the NUTS 2 level, which categorizes regions based on population sizes ranging from 800,000 to 3 million.

  35. Given that income is likely to be endogenous, it is important to run regressions which exclude this variable. This is done e.g. in columns (1) and (2) in Table 4. Yet, since many studies include this variable, we decided that it is, on balance, better to show specifications which include it.

  36. The online appendix reports results from using the availability of prehistoric domesticable animals and plants as “bio geographical” instruments for the timing of the Neolithic Revolution (see Table 15A). Given that this only influences female labor force participation rates through adoption of agriculture, we can rule out that the results are driven by omitted variable or attenuation bias. It could, however, be argued that the availability of prehistoric domesticable animals is invalid as an instrument, because it is related to the adoption of animal husbandry which could lead women to spend more time closer to home taking care of animals. Nevertheless, we obtain similar results when conditioning on a measure of actual historical use of domesticated large animals from Alesina et al. (2013).

  37. These include the following variables: the economic and political development of the country in ancient times, the use of large domesticated animals, the overall agricultural suitability, the fraction of tropical and subtropical land, log GDP per capita, log GDP per capita squared, and continental fixed effects.

  38. Burton and White (1984) based this prediction on among other things a case study by Machlachlan (1983). He studied South Indian intensive farming and argued that a narrow seasonal window puts a premium on the labor of young men due to the soil preparation being physically demanding. He also argues that men gain critical farming experience while young, which then made them more efficient farm managers when older.

  39. We have also investigated whether our results are driven by, for example, the interaction between years of agriculture and historical plough-use, or the one between years of agriculture and the number of growing days per years. Including these interactions does not affect the significance of years of agriculture, and they are not significant themselves.

  40. Lerner (1986, p. 9) also links the creation of early states to gender roles and argues that they were organized in the form of patriarchy. Still, she also acknowledges that plough agriculture may have mattered as it demanded the strength of men and was not for pregnant women or lactating mothers (Lerner, p. 51).

  41. The state antiquity variable is migration adjusted. Similar results are obtained for the unadjusted variable.

  42. Ross (2009) argues that oil production rather than Islam reduces contemporary female labor market participation. In results available upon request, we demonstrate that our argument is robust to the inclusion of oil rent per capita (taken from Ross 2009).

  43. An alternative way of evaluating the importance of social inequality as a cause of gender inequality is to consider complex hunter-gatherers as found in e.g. the Pacific Northwest. According to Klein (1995), these societies have social hierarchies, though gender inequality is absent. Burchell (2006) reports evidence consistent with this by examining the extent to which men and women are buried with grave goods . Yet, Ames and Maschner (1999) found that men were more likely to be buried with grave goods.

  44. See online appendix for a list of these countries.

  45. These countries are defined from the value zero in the variable traditional plough use from Alesina et al. (2013).

  46. Boserup (1970, Chap. 1) shows that women’s participation in the agricultural workforce is substantially higher in Africa compared to Asia. Even so, there is variation within Asia, where some parts of, for example, China have quite high participation rates of women in agriculture, but still lower than what is observed in Africa. Boserup attributes this to the use of intensive agriculture with irrigation.

  47. Combining variation in suitability for growing tea and orchard cultivation across China with two post-Mao reforms that increased the value of planting tea and orchards relative to staple crops, Qian (2008) demonstrates that there is a positive, causal effect of women’s income on the survival rates of girls. This is consistent with the mechanisms that we study.

  48. It should be noted that the original dataset also includes Middle Eastern countries. However, regional data on female labor market participation are not available for these countries.

  49. This is demonstrated by the fact that \(R^{2} \) increases from 0.65 to 0.87 by the inclusion of country dummies.

  50. Similar results are obtained using non-linear probability models instead (not reported).

  51. The cereals included in this measure are wheat, rice, maize, barley, sorghum, pearl and foxtail millet, and rye. FAO classify soil suitability into the following categories very low, low, medium low, medium, medium high, high and very high. The good soil suitability measure uses soil with medium high suitability or higher. The root crops included are cassava (also known as manioc root), white yam, greater yam, yellow yam, taro, and sweet potatoes. The measure also includes white potatoes which belong to the tuber category.

  52. Table 11A in the online appendix documents evidence showing that relative root crops suitability is positive related to female labor force participation in 2000 in the cross-country sample as well.

References

  • Acemoglu, D., Johnson, S., & Robinson, J. (2002). Reversal of fortune: Geography and institutions in the making of the modern world income distribution. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 117(4), 1231–1294.

    Article  MATH  Google Scholar 

  • Alesina, A., Devleeschauwer, A., Easterly, W., Kurlat, S., & Wacziarg, R. (2003). Fractionalization. Journal of Economic Growth, 8(2), 155–194.

    Article  MATH  Google Scholar 

  • Alesina, A., Giuliano, P., & Nunn, N. (2013). On the origins of gender roles: Women and the plough. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 128(2), 469–530.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Alvarez, H. P. (2004). Residence groups among hunter-gatherers: a view of the claims and evidene for patrilocal bands. In B. Chapais & C. Berman (Eds.), Kinship behavior in primates (pp. 420–442). New York: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Altonji, J. G., Elder, T. E., & Taber, C. R. (2005). Selection on observed and unobserved variables: Assessing the effectiveness of catholic schools. Journal of Political Economy, 113(1), 151–184.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ames, K., & Maschner, H. G. (1999). Peoples of the northwest coast their archaeology and prehistory. London: Thames and Hudson.

    Google Scholar 

  • Andersen, S. (2007). The economics of dowry and brideprice. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 21(4), 151–174.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ashraf, Q., & Galor, O. (2011). Dynamics and stagnation in the malthusian epoch. American Economic Review, 101(5), 2003–2041.

    Article  PubMed Central  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  • Barro, R., & Lee, J. W. (2013). A new data set of educational attainment in the world, 1950–2010. Journal of Development Economics, 103(2013), 184–198.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bauer, J., Feng, W., Riley, N. E., & Xiaohua, Z. (1992). Gender inequality in urban China: Education and employment. Modern China, 8(3), 333–370.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bauman, H. (1928). The division of labor according to sex in African hoe agriculture. Journal of the International Institute of African Languages and Cultures, 1, 289–329.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Becker, S. O., & Woessmann, L. (2009). Was weber wrong? A human capital theory of protestant economic history. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 124, 531–596.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bellwood, P. (2005). First farmers: The origins of agricultural societies. Oxford: Blackwell Publishers.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bentley, R. A., Bickle, P., Fibiger, L., Nowell, G. M., Dale, C. W., & Hedges, R. E. M. (2012). Community differentiation and kinship among Europe’s first farmers. PNAS, 109(24), 9326–9330.

    Article  PubMed Central  CAS  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  • Bleaney, M., & Dimico, A. (2011). Biogeographical conditions, the transition to agriculture and long run growth. European Economic Review, 55, 943–954.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bray, F. (1984). Biology and biological technology: Part II: Agriculture. In J. Needham (Ed.), Science and civilization in China (Vol. 6). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Boserup, E. (1970). Woman’s role in economic development. London: George Allen and Unwin Ltd.

    Google Scholar 

  • Briffault, R. (1927). The mothers (Vol. I). London: George Allen & Unwin Ltd.

    Google Scholar 

  • Burchell, M. (2006). Gender, grave goods and status in British Columbia burials. Canadian Journal of Archaeology, 30, 251–271.

    Google Scholar 

  • Burton, M. L., & White, D. R. (1984). Sexual division of labor in agriculture. American Anthropologist, 86(3), 558–583.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Comin, D., Easterly, W., & Gong, W. (2010). Was the wealth of nations determined in 1000 BC? American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics, 2, 65–97.

    Google Scholar 

  • Diamond, J. (1987). The worst mistake in the history of the human race. Worthington: Discover.

    Google Scholar 

  • Diamond, J. (1997). Guns, germs, and steel. New York: W.W. Norton.

    Google Scholar 

  • Doepke, M., & Tertilt, M. (2009). Women’s liberation: What’s in it for men? Quarterly Journal of Economics, 124(4), 1541–1591.

    Article  MATH  Google Scholar 

  • Doepke, M., & Tertilt, M. (2011). Does female empowerment promote economic development? CEPR discussion paper no. DP8441.

  • Draper, P. (1975). !Kung women: Contrasts in sexual egalitarianism in foraging and sedentary contexts. In R. R. Reiter (Ed.), Toward and anthropology of women. New York: Monthly Review Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dyble, M., Salali, G. D., Chaudhary, N., Page, A., Smith, D., Thompson, J., et al. (2015). Sex equality can explain the unique social structure of hunter-gatherer bands. Science, 348(6236), 796–798.

    Article  CAS  PubMed  ADS  Google Scholar 

  • Ember, C. (1975). Residential variation among hunter-gatherers. Behavioral Science Research, 36, 179–220.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ember, C. (1978). Myths about hunter-gatherers. Ethnology, 17, 439–448.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ember, C. (1983). The relative decline in women’s contribution to agriculture with intensification. American Anthropologist, 85, 285–304.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Feldmann, H. (2007). Protestantism, labor force participation, and employment across countries. American Journal of Economics and Sociology, 66(4), 795–816.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fernandez, R. (2007). Women, work and culture. Journal of the European Economic Association, 5(2–3), 305–332.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fernandez, R., & Fogli, A. (2009). Culture: An empirical investigation of beliefs, work, and fertility. American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics, 1(1), 146–177.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ferraro, G. P., & Andreatta, S. (2010). Cultural anthropology: an applied approach. Belmont: Wadsworth Publishers.

    Google Scholar 

  • Friedl, E. (1975). Women and men: An anthropologist’s view. New York: Holt, Rinehart and Winston.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fussel, G. E. (1966). Ploughs and Ploughing before 1800. Agricultural History, 40(3), 177–186.

    Google Scholar 

  • Galor, O. (2011). Unified growth theory. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Galor, O., & Weil, D. N. (1996). The gender gap. Fertility, and Growth, American Economic Review, 86(3), 374–387.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gkiasta, M., Russell, T., Shennan, S., & Steele, J. (2003). Neolithic transition in Europe: The radiocarbon record revisited. Antiquity, 77(295), 45–62.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Goldin, C. (1995). The U-shaped female labor force function in economic development and economic history. In T. P. Schultz (Ed.), Investment in women’s human capital (pp. 61–90). Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gould, R. A. (1977). Discovering the Australian desert culture. Pacific Discovery, 30, 1–11.

    Google Scholar 

  • Guyer, J. (1991). Female farming in anthropology and African History. In M. diLeonardo (Ed.), Gender at the crossroads of knowledge. Berkely: University of California Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hall, R. E., & Jones, C. I. (1999). Why do some countries produce so much more output per worker than others? Quarterly Journal of Economics, 114(1), 83–116.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hariri, J. (2012). The autocratic legacy of early statehood. American Political Science Review, 106(3), 471–794.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hinsch, B. (2003). The origins of separation of the sexes in China. Journal of the American Oriental Society, 123, 595–616.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hunn, E. (2000). On the relative contribution of mean women to subsistence among the hunter-gatherers of the Colombia Plateau. In P. Minnis (Ed.), Ethnobotany: A reader. Norman: University of Oklahoma Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Iversen, T., & Rosenbluth, F. (2010). The political economy of gender inequality. New Haven: Yale University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kaplan, H., Hill, K., Lancaster, J., & Hurtado, A. M. (2000). A theory of human life history evolution: Diet, intelligence, and longevity. Evolutionary Anthropology Issues News and Reviews, 9, 156–185.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kent, S. (1995). Does sedentarization promote gender inequality? A case study from the Kalahari. The Journal of the Royal Anthropological Institute, 1, 513–536.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Klasen, S. (2002). Low schooling for girls, slower growth for all? Cross-country evidence on the effect of gender inequality in education on economic development. World Bank Economic Review, 16(3), 345–373.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Klein, L. F. (1995). Mother as clanswoman. Rank and gender in Tlingit society. In L. F. Klein & L. A. Ackerman (Eds.), Women and power in native north America. Norman: University of Oklahoma Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Korotayev, A. (2003). Division of labor by gender and postmarital residence in cross-cultural perspective: A reconsideration. Cross Cultural Research, 37, 335–372.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kuhn, S. L., & Stiner, M. C. (2006). What’s a mother to do? The division of labor among neandertals and modern humans in Eurasia. Current Anthropology, 47, 953–981.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lai, R. (2007). Evolution of the plough over 10,000 years and the rationale for no-till farming. Soil and Tillage, 93, 1–12.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lancaster, C. S. (1976). Women, horticulture, and society in sub-Saharan Africa. American Anthropologist, New Series, 78(3), 539–564.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • La Porta, R., Lopez-de-Silanes, F., & Shleifer, A. (2008). The economic consequences of legal origins. Journal of Economic Literature, 46(2), 285–332.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lee, R. B. (1968). What hunters do for a living, or, how to make out on scarce resources. In R. B. Lee & I. Devore (Eds.), Man the hunter. Chicago: Aldine Publishing Company.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lerner, G. (1986). The creation of patriarchy. New York: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Machlachlan, M. D. (1983). Why they did not starve: Biocultural adaption in a south indian village. Philadelphia: Institute for the Study of Human Issues Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Marlowe, F. W. (2005). Hunter-gatherers and human evolution. Evolutionary Anthropology, 14, 54–67.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Milanovic, B., Lindert, P. H., & Williamson, J. (2010). Pre-industrial inequality. Economic Journal, 121, 255–272.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Miller, G. (2008). Women’s suffrage, political responsiveness and child survival in American history. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 124(3), 1287–1327.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nunn, N., & Wantchekon, L. (2011). The slave trade and the origins of mistrust in Africa. American Economic Review, 101, 3221–3252.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Olsson, O., & Hibbs, D. (2005). Biogeography and long-run economic development. European Economic Review, 49, 909–938.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Olsson, O., & Paik, C. (2012). A western reversal since the neolithic? The long-run impact of early agriculture. Mimeo.

  • Patterson, N. (1994). Cattle, lords and clansmen. The social structure of early Ireland. Notre Dame: University of Notre Dame Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Peacock, N. (1991). Rethinking the sexual division of labor: Reproductiion and women’s work among the Efe. In Micaela Di Leonardo (Ed.), Gender at the crossroads of knowledge. Berkely, CA: University of California Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Peterson, J. (2002). Sexual revolutions: Gender and labor at the dawn of agriculture. Walnut Creek: Altamira Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Petersen, M. B., & Skaaning, S. E. (2010). Ultimate causes of state formation: The significance of biogeography, diffusion, and neolithic revolutions. Historical Social Research, 35(3), 200–226.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pinhasi, R., Fort, J., & Ammerman, A. (2005). Tracing the origin and spread of agriculture in Europe. PLoS Biology, 3(12), 2220–2228.

    Article  CAS  Google Scholar 

  • Putterman, L. (2007). State antiquity index (Version 3).http://www.econ.brown.edu/fac/louis_putterman/antiquity%20index.htm.

  • Putterman, L. (2008). Agriculture, diffusion, and development: Ripple effects of the neolithic revolution. Economica, 75(300), 729–748.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Putterman, L., & Trainor, C. A. (2006). Agricultural transition year country data set. Providence: Brown University.

    Google Scholar 

  • Putterman, L., & Weil, D. N. (2010). Post-1500 population flows and the long-run determinants of economic growth and inequality. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 125(4), 1627–1682.

    Article  PubMed Central  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  • Qian, N. (2008). Missing women and the price of tea in China: The effect of sex-specific earnings on sex imbalance. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 123(3), 1251–1285.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Reher, D. S. (2004). The demographic transition revisited as a global process. Population Space and Place, 10(1), 19–41.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ross, M. (2009). Oil, islam, and women. American Political Science Review, 102(2), 1–18.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ruggles, D., Alexander, J. T., Genadek, K., Goeken, R., Schroeder, M. B., & Sobek, M. (2010). Integrated public use microdata series: Version 5.0 [machine-readable database]. Minneapolis: University of Minnesota.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schrire, C., & Steiger, W. L. (1974). A matter of life and death: An investigation into the practice of female infanticide in the arctic. Man, New Series, 9(2), 161–184.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schvaneveldt, P. L., Kerpelman, J. L., & Schvaneveldt, J. (2005). Generational and cultural changes in family life in the United Arab Emirates: A comparison of mothers and daughters. Journal of Comparative Family Studies, 36(1), 77–91.

    Google Scholar 

  • Skoglund, P. H., Malmström, M., Raghaan, J., Storå, P., Hall, E., Willerslev, M. P. T., et al. (2012). Origins and genetic legacy of neolithic farmers and hunter-gatherers in Europe. Science, 366, 466–469.

    Article  ADS  Google Scholar 

  • Spatial Data Repository, The Demographic and Health Surveys Program. ICF International. Available from http://www.spatialdata.dhsprogram.com. Retrieved November 26, 2014.

  • Tabellini, G. (2010). Culture and institutions: Economic development in the regions of Europe. Journal of the European Economic Association, 8(4), 677–716.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Talhelm, T., Zhang, X., Oishi, S., Shimin, C., Duan, D., Lan, X., et al. (2014). Large-scale psychological differences within China explained by rice versus wheat agriculture. Science, 344, 603–607.

    Article  CAS  PubMed  ADS  Google Scholar 

  • Tam, H. (2010). U-shaped female labor participation with economic development: Some panel data evidence. Economics Letters, 110, 140–142.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tanaka, J. (1976). Subsistence ecology of central kalahari San. In R. B. Leem & I. Devore (Eds.), Kalahari hunter-gatherers. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • United Nations. (2011). Accelerating progress towards the millennium development goals: Options for sustained and inclusive growth and issues for advancing the United Nations Development Agenda beyond 2015. Annual report of secretary-general, July, 2011.

  • White, D. R., Burton, M. L., & Dow, M. C. (1981). Sexual division of labor in African agriculture. A Network Autocorrelation Analysis. American Anthropolgist, 83, 824–849.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wood, W., & Eagly, A. C. (2002). A cross-cultural analysis of the behavior of women and men: Implications for the origins of sex differences. Psychological Bulletin, 128, 699–727.

    Article  PubMed  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

We would like to thank the Editor-in-Chief Oded Galor, five anonymous referees, Patricia Draper, Paola Giuliano, Jens Iversen, Lars Lønstrup, Paul Sharp, Battista Servergnini, Rupert Stasch, MEHR seminar participants (University of Copenhagen), and seminar participants at the Danish Public Choice workshop 2013 (Aarhus University) for useful comments and helpful suggestions. We would also like to thank Alberto Alesina, Paola Giuliano, and Nathan Nunn for kindly sharing their data.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Casper Worm Hansen.

Electronic supplementary material

Below is the link to the electronic supplementary material.

Supplementary material 1 (pdf 192 KB)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Hansen, C.W., Jensen, P.S. & Skovsgaard, C.V. Modern gender roles and agricultural history: the Neolithic inheritance. J Econ Growth 20, 365–404 (2015). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10887-015-9119-y

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10887-015-9119-y

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation