Skip to main content
Log in

Endogenous Timing of R&D Decisions and Privatization Policy with Research Spillovers

  • Published:
Journal of Industry, Competition and Trade Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This study investigates an endogenous R&D timing game between duopoly firms which undertake cost-reducing R&D investments simultaneously or sequentially, and then play Cournot output competition. We examine and compare equilibrium outcomes in private and mixed markets, respectively, and find that spillovers rate critically affects contrasting results. We show that a simultaneous-move (sequential-move) appears in a private duopoly if the spillovers rate is low (high) while a sequential-move appears in a mixed duopoly irrespective of spillovers. We also show that public leadership is the only equilibrium if the spillovers rate is intermediate and its resulting welfare is the highest. This suggests that the implementation of privatization policy transforms a public leader to a private competitor, which can decrease the social welfare.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. In an endogenous timing game in mixed market, Bárcena-Ruiz (2007), Lu (2006), Lu and Poddar (2009), and Heywood and Ye (2009) examined different contexts. For recent analysis, see Bárcena-Ruiz and Garzón (2010), Tomaru and Kiyono (2010), Balogh and Tasnádi (2012), Amir and De Feo (2014), Matsumura and Ogawa (2010, 2014, 2017), Naya (2015), Din and Sun (2016), Lee and Xu (2018), Garcia et al. (2019), and Cho et al. (2019) among others.

  2. For more details, see Miyagiwa and Ohno (2002) and Marinucci (2012). Ishibashi and Matsumura (2006) also provided some Japanese cases where the public and private organizations compete in R&D sectors sequentially or simultaneously, which include health, space, bio-technology, and agriculture.

  3. Knowledge and benefits obtained by a firm from its R&D activities might leak out to other firms. Thus, the firm cannot appropriate all the fruit of its R&D activities. Since d’Aspremont and Jacquemin (1988) and Suzumura (1992), the economics of R&D spillovers has been one of the most active issues in industrial economics over the last two decades. For example, Katsoulacos and Ulph (1998), Poyago-Theotoky (1995, 1999), Amir et al. (2000), and Baranes and Tropeano (2003) constructed a theoretical model of endogenous R&D spillovers.

  4. As related works, Suetens (2005) experimented how the rate of spillovers affects firms’ incentives to cooperate and non-cooperate in R&D while Lee and Muminov (2021) provided an incentive compatible R&D subsidy scheme for cooperative R&D competition in a mixed duopoly.

  5. The model with linear demand and quadratic cost functions is a standard formulation, which makes it possible to obtain a closed-form solution for each of the game and allows for a comparison of the equilibrium outcomes. It is also popularly used in the literature of mixed oligopolies since it can rule out an uninteresting corner solution case of a public monopoly. See, for example, Gil-Molto et al. (Gil-Molto et al. 2011; Gil-Molto et al. 2020), Kesavayuth and Zikos (2013), Lee et al. (2017), and Leal et al. (Leal et al. 2018, Leal et al. 2021).

  6. Note also that the difference of marginal cost between the two firms is 2(qi − qj) − (1 − β)(xi − xj). It implies that the distribution of production costs across the firms is efficient only under the symmetric equilibrium where qi = qj and xi = xj. For more economic rationale behind this formulation, see Matsumura and Okamura (2015) and Kim et al. (2019).

  7. Due to the linear-quadratic structure of the model, it is easy to show that all the second-order conditions of the equilibrium outcomes in this study are satisfied.

  8. The proofs of lemmas and propositions are provided in Appendix.

  9. It is often observed that cooperation between the firms occurs under the research joint venture. See, for example, Poyago-Theotoky (1995, 1999), Lee (1998), Amir (2000), and Lee and Muminov (2021).

  10. If we consider the first-best outcome where the welfare is directly maximized by R&D (xFB) and output production (qFB), we have \( {x}_0^{CM}\frac{>}{<}{x}^{FB} \) if \( \beta \frac{<}{>}0.213 \) while \( {x}^{FB}>{x}_1^{CM} \) for any β ∈ [0, 1]. Thus, if the spillovers rate is low, the public firm chooses over-investment while the private firm always chooses under-investment.

  11. Note that \( {q}_0^{CM}\frac{>}{<}{q}^{FB} \) if \( \beta \frac{<}{>}0.576 \) while \( {q}^{FB}>{q}_1^{CM} \) for any β ∈ [0, 1]. Thus, if the spillovers rate is not so high, the public firm chooses over-production while the private firm always chooses under-production.

  12. Note that \( {x}_0^{LM}\frac{>}{<}{x}^{FB} \) if \( \beta \frac{<}{>}0.181 \) while \( {x}^{FB}>{x}_1^{LM} \). Thus, if the spillovers rate is low, the public leader chooses over-investment while the private follower always chooses under-investment.

  13. Note that \( {q}_0^{LM}\frac{>}{<}{q}^{FB} \) if \( \beta \frac{<}{>}0.59 \) while \( {q}^{FB}>{q}_1^{LM} \). Thus, if the spillovers rate is not so high, the public leader chooses over-production while the private follower always chooses under-production.

  14. Note that \( {x}_0^{FM}\frac{>}{<}{x}^{FB} \) if \( \beta \frac{<}{>}0.213 \) while \( {x}^{FB}>{x}_1^{LM} \). Thus, if the spillovers rate is low, the public follower chooses over-investment while the private leader always chooses under-investment.

  15. Note that \( {q}_0^{FM}\frac{>}{<}{q}^{FB} \) if \( \beta \frac{<}{>}0.583 \) while \( {q}^{FB}>{q}_1^{FM} \). Thus, if the spillovers rate is not so high, the public follower chooses over-production while the private leader always chooses under-production.

  16. From the strategic relation of R&D decisions, it is noted that the private firm might reduce its R&D when the public firm chooses over-investment while the public firm might reduce its R&D when the private firm chooses under-investment, especially when the spillovers rate is intermediate, 0.165 < β < 0.333. Thus, when the public firm is able to control the R&D decisions under the public leadership, it can reduce its over-investment, compared to the simultaneous-move game.

References

  • Amir R (2000) Modelling imperfectly appropriable R&D via spillovers. Int J Ind Organ 18:1013–1032

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Amir R, De Feo G (2014) Endogenous timing in a mixed duopoly. Int J Game Theory 43:629–658

    Google Scholar 

  • Amir M, Amir R, Jin J (2000) Sequencing R&D decisions in a two-period duopoly with spillovers. Int J Ind Organ 18:1013–1032

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Balogh TL, Tasnádi A (2012) Does timing of decisions in a mixed duopoly matter? J Econ 106(3):233–249

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baranes E, Tropeano J-P (2003) Why are technological spillovers spatially bounded? A market orientated approach. Reg Sci Urban Econ 33(4):445–466

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bárcena-Ruiz J (2007) Endogenous timing in a mixed duopoly: price competition. J Econ 91:263–272

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bárcena-Ruiz J, Garzón M (2010) Endogenous timing in a mixed oligopoly with semipublic firms. Port Econ J 9:97–113

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cho S, Lee S-H, Hoang X (2019) Corporate social responsibility and strategic trade policy: an endogenous timing game and its policy implications. Aust Econ Pap 58(4):480–497

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • d’Aspremont C, Jacquemin A (1988) Cooperative and non-cooperative R&D in duopoly with spillovers. Am Econ Rev 78:1133–1137

    Google Scholar 

  • Delbono F, Denicolo V (1993) Regulating Innovative activity: the role of a public firm. Int J Ind Organ 11(1):35–48

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Din H, Sun C (2016) Combining the endogenous choice of timing and competition version in a mixed duopoly. J Econ 118:141–166

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fjell K, Heywood J (2004) Mixed oligopoly, subsidization and the order of firm’s moves: the relevance of privatization. Econ Lett 83(3):411–416

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Garcia A, Leal M, Lee SH (2019) Endogenous timing with a socially responsible firm. Korean Econ Rev 35(2):345–370

    Google Scholar 

  • Gil-Molto M, Poyago-Theotoky J, Zikos V (2011) R&D subsidies, spillovers and privatization in mixed markets. South Econ J 78:233–255

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gil-Molto M, Poyago-Theotoky J, Rodrigues-Neto J, Zikos V (2020) Mixed oligopoly, cost-reducing research and development, and privatization. Eur J Oper Res 283(3):1094–1106

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hamilton J, Slutsky S (1990) Endogenous timing in duopoly games: Stackelberg or Cournot equilibria. Games Econ Behav 2(1):29–46

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Haruna S, Goel RK (2017) Output subsidies in mixed oligopoly with research spillovers. J Econ Financ 41:235–256

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Haruna S, Goel RK (2018) Optimal pollution control in a mixed oligopoly with research spillovers. Aust Econ Pap 58(1):21–40

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Heywood JS, Ye G (2009) Partial privatization in a mixed duopoly with an R&D rivalry. Bull Econ Res 61:165–178

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ishibashi I, Matsumura T (2006) R&D competition between public and private sectors. Eur Econ Rev 50:1347–1366

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Katsoulacos Y, Ulph D (1998) Endogenous spillovers and the performance of research joint ventures. J Ind Econ 46(3):333–357

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kesavayuth D, Zikos V (2013) R&D versus output subsidies in mixed markets. Econ Lett 118:293–296

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kim S-L, Lee SH, Matsumura T (2019) Corporate social responsibility and privatization policy in a mixed oligopoly. J Econ 128(1):67–89

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Leal M, Garcia A, Lee SH (2018) The timing of environmental tax policy with a consumer-friendly firm. Hitotsubashi J Econ 59(1):25–43

    Google Scholar 

  • Leal M, Garcia A, Lee SH (2021) Sequencing R&D decisions with a consumer-friendly firm and spillovers. Jpn Econ Rev 72(2):243–260

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lee SH (1998) R&D spillovers, technology cartel and monopoly regulation. Int Econ J 12:77–88

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lee SH, Muminov T (2021) R&D information sharing in a mixed duopoly and incentive subsidy for research joint venture competition. Bull Econ Res 73(2):154–170

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lee SH, Tomaru Y (2017) Output and R&D subsidies in mixed oligopoly. Oper Res Lett 45:238–241

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lee SH, Xu L (2018) Endogenous timing in private and mixed duopolies with emission taxes. J Econ 124:175–201

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lee SH, Muminov T, Tomaru Y (2017) Partial privatization and subsidization in a mixed duopoly: R&D versus output subsidies. Hitotsubashi J Econ 58(2):163–177

    Google Scholar 

  • Lu Y (2006) Endogenous timing in a mixed oligopoly with foreign competitors: the linear demand case. J Econ 88:49–68

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lu Y, Poddar S (2009) Endogenous timing in a mixed duopoly and private duopoly – ‘capacity-then-quantity’ game: the linear demand case. Aust Econ Pap 48(2):138–150

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Marinucci, M. (2012) A primer on R&D cooperation among firms. Occasional Papers No. 130, Bank of Italy

  • Matsumura T, Ogawa A (2010) On the robustness of private leadership in mixed duopoly. Aust Econ Pap 49(2):149–160

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Matsumura T, Ogawa A (2014) Corporate social responsibility or payoff asymmetry? A study of an endogenous timing game. South Econ J 81(2):457–473

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Matsumura T, Ogawa A (2017) Endogenous timing in mixed duopolies with externality. Aust Econ Pap 56(4):304–327

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Matsumura T, Okamura M (2015) Competition and privatization policies revisited: the payoff interdependence approach. J Econ 116(2):137–150

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Miyagiwa K, Ohno Y (2002) Uncertainty, spillovers and cooperative R&D. Int J Ind Organ 20:855–876

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Naya J (2015) Endogenous timing in a mixed duopoly model. J Econ 116:165–174

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nett L (1994) Why private firms are more innovative than public firms. Eur J Polit Econ 10(4):639–653

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pal D (1998) Endogenous timing in a mixed oligopoly. Econ Lett 61(2):181–185

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Poyago-Theotoky J (1995) Equilibrium and optimal size of a research joint venture in an oligopoly with spillovers. J Ind Econ 43:209–226

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Poyago-Theotoky J (1999) A note on endogenous spillovers in a non-tournament R&D duopoly. Rev Ind Organ 15:253–262

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Suetens S (2005) Cooperative and non-cooperative R&D in experimental duopoly markets. Int J Ind Organ 23:63–82

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Suzumura K (1992) Cooperative and non-cooperative R&D in an oligopoly with spillovers. Am Econ Rev 82:1307–1320

    Google Scholar 

  • Tomaru Y, Kiyono K (2010) Endogenous timing in mixed duopoly with increasing marginal costs. J Inst Theor Econ 166(4):591–613

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Sang-Ho Lee.

Ethics declarations

Conflict of Interest

The authors declare that they have no conflict of interest.

Funding

We have not received any financial support from any person or organizations that could inappropriately influence our work.

Ethical Approval

Our paper is original and has not been published previously in the journal. Further, it has neither been under consideration nor submitted to other journals.

Informed consent

We consent that all the information can be released under author’s agreement.

Additional information

Publisher’s Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

APPENDIX

APPENDIX

Proof of Lemma 1:

Comparing total R&D and total outputs in (8), (11) and (9), (12), respectively, we obtain XCP − XLP ≤ 0 and QCP − QLP ≤ 0 where the equality satisfies if β = 0.25

Proof of Lemma 2:

Comparing the profits of firms in (10) and (13), we can obtain (i) \( {\pi}_0^{LP}-{\pi}_i^{CP}\ge 0 \) where the equality satisfies if β = 0.25, (ii) \( {\pi}_1^{LP}-{\pi}_i^{CP}\ \frac{>}{<}0\ \mathrm{if}\ \beta \frac{>}{<}0.25 \), and (iii) \( {\pi}_0^{LP}-{\pi}_1^{LP}\ \frac{>}{<}0\ \mathrm{if}\ \beta \frac{<}{>}0.25. \)

Proof of Lemma 3:

Comparing welfares in (10) and (14), we obtain WCP − WLP ≤ 0 where the equality satisfies if β = 0.25.

Proof of Lemma 4:

First, comparing total R&D derived in (20), (23), and (26), we obtain (i) \( {X}^{LM}-{X}^{CM}\frac{>}{<}0\kern0.5em \mathrm{if}\kern0.5em \beta \frac{>}{<}0.333; \) (ii) XFM − XCM < 0 if  0.165 < β < 0.333, but the reverse holds otherwise; (iii) XLM − XFM > 0 if  0.333 < β < 0.558, but the reverse holds otherwise.

Second, comparing total outputs in (21), (24), and (27), we obtain (i) \( {Q}^{LM}-{Q}^{CM}\frac{>}{<}0\kern0.5em \mathrm{if}\kern0.5em \beta \frac{>}{<}0.333; \) (ii) QFM − QCM < 0  if  0.165 < β < 0.333, but the reverse holds otherwise; (iii) QLM − QFM > 0  if  0.333 < β < 0.611, but the reverse holds otherwise.

Proof of Lemma 5:

Comparing the profits of firms in (22), (25), and (28), we obtain (i) \( {\pi}_1^{LM}-{\pi}_1^{CM}\ge 0, \) (ii) \( {\pi}_1^{FM}-{\pi}_1^{CM}\ge 0, \) and (iii) \( {\pi}_1^{LM}-{\pi}_1^{FM}\ge 0 \)where the equality satisfies if β = 0.333.

Proof of Lemma 6:

Comparing welfares in (22), (25), and (28), we obtain (i) WLM − WCM ≥ 0 where the equality satisfies if β = 0.333; (ii) WFM − WCM < 0 if  0.165 < β < 0.333, but the reverse holds otherwise; (iii) WFM − WLM < 0 if 0.163 < β < 0.333, but the reverse holds otherwise.

Proof of Proposition 5:

Comparing social welfares between private and mixed duopoly markets, we obtain WFM − WLP > 0 and WLM − WLP > 0 for any β ∈ [0, 1]. Then, from Lemmas 3 and 6, we have WCM > WCP and min{WFM, WLM} > WLP ≥ WCP where the equality satisfies if β = 0.25. Therefore, we have the following: (i) WCP < WLM < WFM if 0 < β < 0.163; (ii) WCP < WFM < WLM if 0.163 < β < 0.25, (iii) WLP < WLM if 0.25 < β < 0.333; (iv) WLP < WLM < WFM if 0.333 < β < 1.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Lee, SH., Muminov, T.K. Endogenous Timing of R&D Decisions and Privatization Policy with Research Spillovers. J Ind Compet Trade 21, 505–525 (2021). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10842-021-00365-5

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Revised:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10842-021-00365-5

Keywords

JEL Classifications

Navigation