Abstract
The literature of cultural economics generally finds that an artistic education has no significant impact on artists’ income and careers in the arts. In artists’ labor markets, indefinable features such as talent and artistic creativity apparently contribute more to success or higher rates of payment than education and training. In this article, we will readdress this question by looking at the artists’ survival in the arts occupations. We find it reasonable to expect than an artistic education can have a significant impact on artists’ careers because of the importance of technical skills, networks and signaling effects. We analyze the question by using a unique longitudinal dataset for five different groups of artists in Denmark, using the Cox model to apply survival functions and semi-parametric analysis. The results show, among other things, that an artistic education has a significant impact on artists’ careers in the arts, and we find important industry differences.
This is a preview of subscription content, access via your institution.






Notes
For further information on the specific variables see http://www.dst.dk/TilSalg/Forskningsservice.aspx.
For comparison, currently there are 5.6 mill. inhabitants in Denmark.
It is worth noting that decorators and commercial designers have their own job category (ISCO code 3471) in Statistics Denmark, and they have not been included in the analysis.
We can get an impression of the bias by looking at our full sample of about 45.000 individuals (before regression). We can calculate the number of individuals with an interrupted artistic career in the same year. As an example, 1300 individuals have an artistic career that start before 2002 and continue from 2003, but is interrupted in 2002, where they do not work as artists (they might have a job in another occupation). We can make the same calculation for all the years in our sample, and it turns out, that the maximum number for one year is about 4300, and the minimum number is about 1300. Based on these calculations, we can assume the number of individuals with interrupted career in 1996, who returned in 1997, is between 1300 and 4300. Therefore, we expect the bias to be small.
Statistics Denmark changed the definition of the group of visual artists during the studied period, with a small impact on the number of artists in the group and therefore also on the survival function, which can be seen in the decrease in visual artists between years 4 and 5.
Age is not included in quadratic form, since it does not have a quadric distribution. The career length across age is randomly distributed—with a small tendency toward shorter career length for the youngest individuals.
References
Abbing, H. (2002). Why are artists poor. The exceptional economy of the arts. Amsterdam: Amsterdam University Press.
Allison, P. D. (1995). Survival analysis using the SAS System: A practical guide. USA: SAS Institute.
Alper, N., & Wassall, G. H. (2006). Artists’ careers and their labor markets. In V. A. Ginsburgh & D. Throsby (Eds.), Handbook of the economics of the arts and culture (pp. 813–864). Amsterdam: Elsevier Science, North Holland.
Bille, T. and G. Schulze (2006): Culture in urban and regional development. In: D. Throsby and V. Ginsburgh (ed.): Handbook on the economics of arts and culture, Handbook of Economics Series, general editors K. Arrow and M.D. Intriligator, Elsevier Science, North-Holland, pp 1052–1099.
Bille, T., Frey, B. S., Steiner, L., & Fjællegaard, C. B. (2013). Happiness in the arts—international evidence on artists’ job satisfaction. Economic Letters, 121(1), 15–18.
Caves, R. (2000). Creative industries: Contracts between Arts and Commerce. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.
Coulangeon, P., Ravet, H., & Roharik, I. (2005). Gender differentiated effect of time in performing arts professions: Musicians, actors and dancers in contemporary France. Poetics, 33, 369–387.
Eikhof, D. R., Haunschild, A., & Schöβler, F. (2012). Behind the scenes of boundarylessness: Careers in German theatre. In C. Mathieu (Ed.), Careers in Creative Industries (pp. 69–87). New York: Routledge.
Filer, R. (1986). The “starving artist”—myth or reality? Earnings of artists in the United States. Journal of Political Economy, 49, 56–75.
Filer, R. (1989). The economic condition of artists in America. In D. V. Shaw, W. Hendon, & V. L. Owen (Eds.), Cultural Economics 88: An American perspective. Akron: Association for Cultural Economics.
Filer, R. (1990). The arts and academe: The effect of education on earning of artists. Journal of Cultural Economics, 14(1), 15–38.
Heian, M. T., Løyland, K., & Mangset, P. (2012). Stability and change: Work and income conditions for Norwegian artists. Nordic Journal of Cultural Policy, 15(1), 46–76.
Hosmer, D. W., & Lemeshow, Stanley. (1999). Applied survival analysis—Regression modeling of time to event data. USA: John Wiley & Sons.
Mathieu, C. (Ed.). (2012). Careers in creative industries. New York: Routledge.
Menger, P. M. (1999). Artistic Labor Markets and Careers. Annual Reviews, 25, 541–574.
Menger, P. M. (2006). Artistic labor markets: Contingent work, excess supply and occupational risk management. In V. A. Ginsburgh & D. Throsby (Eds.), Handbook of the economics of art and culture (pp. 765–811). North Holland, Amsterdam: Elsevier Science.
Murphy, E. C. (2014). Workers’ movement out of declining occupations in Great Britain, Germany and Switzerland. European Sociological Review, 30(6), 685–701.
Rengers, M. (2002). Economic lives of artists: Studies into careers and the labour market in the cultural sector. Utrecht: Utrecht University, Interuniversity Center for Social Science Theory and Methodology.
Rosen, S. (1972). Learning and experience of the founder of self-employment duration: A comparative advantage approach. Small Business Economics, 39(1), 1–17.
Rosen, S. (1981). The economics of superstars. American Economic Review, 71(5), 845–858.
Steiner, L., & Schneider, L. (2013). The happy artist? An empirical application of the work-preference model. Journal of Cultural Economics, 37(2), 225–246.
Throsby, D. (1992): Artists as workers. Reprinted in: R. Towse (eds) (1997): Cultural economics. The arts, the heritage and the media industries, Edward Elgar, Cheltenham.
Throsby, D. (1994). A work-preference model of artist behavior. In A. Peacock & I. Rizzo (Eds.), Cultural economics and cultural policies (pp. 69–80). Dordrecht: Kluwer Academic Publishers.
Throsby, D. (2001). Economics and culture. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Throsby, D. (2006). Disaggregated earnings functions for artists. In V. Ginsburgh & P.-M. Menger (Eds.), Economics of the arts: Selected essays (pp. 331–346). Dordrecht: Kluwer Academic Publishers.
Throsby, D., & Hollister, V. (2003). Don’t give up your day job yet; An economic study of professional artists in Australia. Sydney: Australia Council.
Towse, R. (2006). Human capital and artists’ labour markets. In V. A. Ginsburgh & D. Throsby (Eds.), Handbook of the economics of the arts and culture (pp. 865–894). North-Holland, Amsterdam: Elsevier Science.
Withers, G. (1985). Artists’ subsidy of the arts. Australian Economics Papers, 24, 290–295.
Woodbridge, J. (2002). Econometric analyses of cross section and panel data. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.
Wooldridge, Jeffrey M. (2010). Econometric analysis of cross section and panel data. USA: MIT Press.
Author information
Authors and Affiliations
Corresponding author
Electronic supplementary material
Below is the link to the electronic supplementary material.
Rights and permissions
About this article
Cite this article
Bille, T., Jensen, S. Artistic education matters: survival in the arts occupations. J Cult Econ 42, 23–43 (2018). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10824-016-9278-5
Received:
Accepted:
Published:
Issue Date:
DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10824-016-9278-5