Advertisement

Journal of Cultural Economics

, Volume 32, Issue 4, pp 243–259 | Cite as

Why has cultural economics ignored copyright?

  • Ruth Towse
Original Article

Abstract

My stance is that copyright policy should be viewed as part of cultural policy; cultural economists have had a great deal to say about subsidy and cultural policy but very little about copyright, though cultural economics is well placed to analyse copyright as an incentive to creativity in the creative industries because of its understanding of cultural policy and of artists’ labour markets. The article contrasts subsidy and copyright as policy tools and briefly discusses two current policy problems in relation to copyright—regulating copyright collection societies and the so-called ‘copyright levy’—arguing that these are the sort of issues cultural economists could (and should) be dealing with.

Keywords

Cultural economics Copyright Cultural policy 

JEL classification

Z11 K11 O34 O38 

References

  1. Acheson, K., & Maule, C. (1999). Much ado about culture North American trade disputes. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan.Google Scholar
  2. Benhamou, F., & Farchy, J. (2007). Droit d’auteur et copyright. Paris: La Découverte (Repères).Google Scholar
  3. Benhamou, F. & Sagot-Duvauroux, D. (2006–2007). Économies des droits d’auteur. Place et rôle de la propriété littéraire et artistique dans le fonctionnement économique des filières d’industries culturelles. Culture Etudes, May.Google Scholar
  4. Besen, S. & Kirby, S. (1989). Compensating creators of intellectual property: Collectives that collect. RAND Report Nº R S. -3751-MF.Google Scholar
  5. Bettig, R. (1996). Copyrighting culture: The political economy of intellectual property. Boulder, CO: Westview Press.Google Scholar
  6. Boldrin, M., & Levine, D. (2002). The case against intellectual property. American Economic Review, Papers and Proceedings, 9(2), 209–212.Google Scholar
  7. Burke, A. (1996). How effective are the international copyright conventions in the music industry? Journal of Cultural Economics, 20(1), 51–66.Google Scholar
  8. Cameron, S., & Collins, A. (1997). Transaction costs and partnerships: The case of rock bands. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organisation, 32(2), 171–183.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  9. Caves, R. (2000). Creative industries: Contracts between art and commerce. Cambridge, MA and London: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
  10. Drexl, J. (2007). Competition in the filed of collecting management: Preferring ‘creative competition’ to allocative efficiency in European copyright law. In P. Torremans (Ed.), Copyright law: A handbook of contemporary research (pp. 255–282). Cheltenham, UK and Northampton, MA, USA: Edward Elgar.Google Scholar
  11. Farchy, J., & Rochelandet, F. (2000). Protection of authors and dissemination of works in the digital universe. The case of the French film industry. Communications & Strategies, 39, 37–58.Google Scholar
  12. Ficsor, M. (2003). Collective management of copyright and related rights. Geneva: World Intellectual Property Organisation.Google Scholar
  13. Ginsburgh, V. (2008). The economic consequences of the droit de suite in the European Union. In R. Towse (Ed.), Recent developments in cultural economics (pp. 384–393). Cheltenham, UK and Northampton, MA, USA: Edward Elgar.Google Scholar
  14. Gowers, A. (2006). Review of intellectual property. London: HMSO, UK Treasury.Google Scholar
  15. Hadfield, G. (1992). The economics of copyright: An historical perspective. Copyright Law Symposium, 38, 1–46.Google Scholar
  16. Handke, C., & Towse, R. (2007). Economics of copyright collecting societies. International Review of Intellectual Property and Competition Law, 38(8), 937–957.Google Scholar
  17. Hansen, A., Ponni V., & Picard, R. (2003). Economics of composition in a small nation: The situation of composers, lyric writers and arrangers in Finland. Working paper, Business Research and Development Centre, Turku School of Economics and Business Administration.Google Scholar
  18. Hansmann, H., & Santilli, M. (2001). Royalties for artists versus royalties for authors and composers. Journal of Cultural Economics, 25(4), 259–281.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  19. Hurt, R., & Schuchman, R. (1966). The economic rationale of copyright. American Economic Review, 56, 421–432.Google Scholar
  20. Kretschmer, M. & Hardwick, P. (2007). Authors’ earnings from copyright and non-copyright sources: A Survey of 25,000 British and German writers. Bournemouth University, Poole: CIPPM and ALCS. www.cippm.org.uk/publications/index.html.
  21. Küng, L., Picard, R. & Towse, R. (eds) (2008). The internet and the mass media. London: Sage.Google Scholar
  22. Landes, W., & Posner, R. (1989). An economic analysis of copyright law. Journal of Legal Studies, XVIII, 325–363.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  23. Landes, W., & Posner, R. (2003). The economic structure of intellectual property law. Cambridge, MA: Belknap Press.Google Scholar
  24. Liebowitz, S., & Watt, R. (2006). How to best ensure remuneration for creators in the market for music? Copyright and its alternatives. Journal of Economic Surveys, 20(4), 513–545.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  25. Matsumoto, S. (2002). Performers in the digital era: Empirical evidence from Japan. In R. Towse (Ed.), Copyright in the cultural industries (pp. 196–209). Cheltenham, UK, and Northampton, MA, USA: Edward Elgar.Google Scholar
  26. O’Hare, M. (1985). Copyright: When is monopoly efficient? Journal of Policy Analysis and Management, 4, 407–418.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  27. Peacock, A. (1993). Paying the piper: Culture, music, money. Edinburgh: Edinburgh University Press.Google Scholar
  28. Peacock, A., & Weir, R. (1975). The composer in the market place. London: Faber Music.Google Scholar
  29. Plant, Arnold. (1934). The economic aspects of copyright in books. Economica, 1(2), 167–195.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  30. Rochelandet, F. (2003). Are copyright collecting societies efficient organisations? An evaluation of collective administration of copyright in Europe. In W. Gordon & R. Watt (Eds.), The economics of copyright: Developments in research and analysis (pp. 176–197). Cheltenham UK and Northampton MA, USA: Edward Elgar.Google Scholar
  31. Rose, M. (1993). Authors and owners: The invention of copyright. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
  32. Rushton, M. (1998). The moral rights of artists: Droit moral or droite pecunaire? Journal of Cultural Economics, 22(1), 1–13.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  33. Rushton, M. (2001). The law and economics of artists’ inalienable rights. Journal of Cultural Economics, 25(4), 243–257.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  34. Samuelson, P. (1999). Implications of the agreement on trade related aspects of intellectual property rights for cultural dimensions of national copyright laws. Journal of Cultural Economics, 23(1–2), 95–107.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  35. Shavell, S., & van Ypersele, T. (2001). Rewards versus intellectual property rights. Journal of Law and Economics, 44, 525–548.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  36. Snow, A., & Watt, R. (2005). Risk sharing and the distribution of copyright collective income. In L. Takeyama, W. Gordon & R. Towse (Eds.), Developments in the economics of copyright: Research and analysis (pp. 23–36). Cheltenham, UK and Northampton, MA: Edward Elgar.Google Scholar
  37. Throsby, D. (1994). A work-preference model of artist labour supply. In A. Peacock & I. Rizzo (Eds.), Cultural economics and cultural policies. Boston MA and Dordrecht: Kluwer.Google Scholar
  38. Throsby, D. (2001). Economics and culture. Cambridge, UK and New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
  39. Throsby, D. & Hollister, V. (2003). Don’t give up your day job yet. Sydney: Australia Council for the Arts. http://www.australiacouncil.gov.au/__data/assets/pdf_file/0017/2906/00_contents.pdf.
  40. Towse, R. (1997). Communication: The monopolies and Mergers Commission’s investigation of the UK music market. Journal of Cultural Economics, 21(2), 147–151.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  41. Towse, R. (2001). Partly for the money: Rewards and incentives to artists. KYKLOS, 54(2/3), 473–490.Google Scholar
  42. Towse, R. (2006). Copyright and artists: A view from cultural economics. Journal of Economic Surveys, 20(4), 567–585.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  43. Towse, R. (2007a). The singer or the song? Developments in performers’ rights from the perspective of a cultural economist’. Review of Law & Economics, 3(3), Article 6. http://www.bepress.com/rle/vol3/iss3/art6.
  44. Towse, R. (2007b). Regulating copyright collecting societies. Keynote talk. Poole, Dorset: Centre for Intellectual Property Policy and Management, Bournemouth University. http://www.cippm.org.uk/symposia/Bournemouth%20Keynote%20talk%203%20December.pdf.
  45. Towse, R., Handke, C., & Stepan, P. (2008). The economics of copyright law: A stocktake of the literature. Review of Economic Research in Copyright Issues, 5(1), 1–22.Google Scholar
  46. Varian, H. (2005). Copying and copyright. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 19(2), 121–138.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  47. Watt, R. (2007). An empirical analysis of the economics of copyright: How valid are the results of studies in developed countries for developing countries? In World Intellectual Property Organisation (WIPO) (Ed.), The economics of intellectual property—Suggestions for further research in developing countries and countries with economies in transition. Geneva: WIPO.Google Scholar

Copyright information

© Springer Science+Business Media, LLC. 2008

Authors and Affiliations

  1. 1.Economics of Creative Industries, Erasmus University RotterdamRotterdamThe Netherlands
  2. 2.CIPPM, The Business SchoolBournemouth UniversityPooleUK

Personalised recommendations