Abstract
Advances in the study of social behavior require a revision in the economic concept of the invisible hand, which states that self-interested behavior leads to well-functioning societies without individuals having the welfare of the society in mind. Evolutionary theory shows that self-interest does not robustly benefit the common good because behaviors that are “for the good of the group” seldom maximize relative fitness within the group. The evolution of group-level functional organization requires a process of group-level selection. Species that have become highly adaptive at the group level are called ultrasocial. The idea that an invisible hand leads to social harmony is valid primarily for ultrasocial species, where selection at the group level results in individual-level behaviors that produce group-beneficial outcomes. Individuals do not necessarily have the welfare of the group in mind, but neither do their behaviors or underlying proximate mechanisms resemble the economic concept of self-interest. Evolutionary science therefore provides a valid concept of the invisible hand, but one that is different from the received version, with far-reaching implications for economics, politics, and public policy.
Similar content being viewed by others
References
Acemoglu, D., & Robinson, J. (2012). Why nations fail: The Origins of power, prosperity, and poverty. New York: Crown.
Bearder, S. K. (1999). Physical and social diversity among nocturnal primates: A new view based on long term research. Primates, 40, 267–282.
Beinhocker, E. D. (2006). Origin of wealth: Evolution, complexity, and the radical remaking of economics. Cambridge, MA: Harvard Business School Press.
Boehm, C. (1999). Hierarchy in the forest: Egalitarianism and the evolution of human altruism. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.
Boehm, C. (2011). Moral ons: The evolution of virtue, altruism, and shame. New York: Basic Books.
Bowles, S., & Gintis, H. (2002). Social capital and community governance. The Economic Journal, 112, F419–F436. doi:10.1111/1468-0297.00077.
Bowles, S. (2009). Did warfare among ancestral hunter-gatherers affect the evolution of human social behavior? Science, 324, 1293–1298.
Boyd, R., Richerson, P. J., & Henrich, J. (2011). The cultural niche: Why social learning is essential for human adaptation. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences, 108, 10918–10925.
Couzin, I. (2007). Collective minds. Nature, 445(7129), 715. doi:10.1038/445715a.
Couzin, I. D., Ioannou, C. C., Demirel, G., Gross, T., Torney, C., Hartnett, A., Conradt, L., Levin, S. A., & Leonard, N. E. (2011). Democratic consensus in animal groups. Science, 334, 1578–1580.
de Tocqueville, A. (1835). Democracy in America (J. P. Mayer Ed.). Garden City, NY: Anchor Books.
Deacon, T. W. (1998). The symbolic species. New York: Norton.
Dunbar, R. I. M. (1996). Grooming, gossip and the evolution of language. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.
Feldman, A. M. (1987). Welfare economics. In J. Eatwell, M. Milgate, & P. Newman (Eds.), The new palgrave dictionary of economics (pp. 889–895). New York: Palgrave Macmillan.
Frank, R. (2011). The Darwin economy: Liberty, competition, and the common good. Princeton: Princeton University Press.
Friedman, M. (1953). Essays in positive economics. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Georgescu-Roegen, N. (1971). The entropy law and the economic process. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.
Gintis, H., Bowles, S., Boyd, R., & Fehr, E. (2005). Moral sentiments and material interests. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.
Gould, S. J., & Lewontin, R. C. (1979). The spandrels of San Marco and the panglossian paradigm: A critique of the adaptationist program. Proceedings of the Royal Society of London, B205, 581–598.
Gowdy, J., & van den Bergh, J. C. J. M. (2003). The microfoundations of macroeconomics: An evolutionary perspective. Cambridge Journal of Economics, 27, 65–84.
Gowdy, J., & Seidl, I. (2004). Economic man and selfish genes: The relevance of group selection to economic policy. Journal of Socioeconomics, 33, 343–358.
Gowdy, J., & Krall, L. (2013). Ultrasociality and the origin of the Anthropocene. Ecological Economics, 95, 137–147.
Gowdy, J., & Krall, L. (2014). Agriculture and the evolution of human ultrasociality. Journal of Bioeconomics, 16(2), 179–202.
Gregory, S. W. J., & Webster, S. (1996). A nonverbal signal in voices of interview partners effectively predicts communication accommodation and social status perceptions. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 70, 1231–1240.
Hayek, F. (1988). The fatal conceit. London: Routledge.
Henderson, J., & Quandt, R. (1980). Microeconomic theory: A mathematical approach. New York: McGraw-Hill.
Henrich, J., & Gil-White, F. J. (2001). The evolution of prestige: Freely conferred deference as a mechanism for enhancing the benefits of cultural transmission. Evolution and Human Behavior, 22(3), 165–196. doi:10.1016/S1090-5138(00)00071-4.
Henrich, J. (2003). Cultural group selection, coevolutionary processes and large-scale cooperation. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 53, 3–35.
Henrich, J., Boyd, R., Bowles, S., Camerer, C., Fehr, E., & Gintis, H. (2004). Foundations of human sociality: economic experiments and ethnographic evidence from fifteen small-scale societies. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Henrich, J., Boyd, R., & Richerson, P. J. (2012). The puzzle of monogamous marriage. Philosophical transactions of the Royal Society of London. Series B, Biological sciences, 367(1589), 657–669. doi:10.1098/rstb.2011.0290.
Hodgson, G. M., & Thorbjorn, K. (2010). Darwin’s conjecture: The search of general principles of social and economic evolution. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Hrdy, S. (2011). Mothers and others: The evolutionary origins of human understanding. Cambridge, MA: Belknap.
Jablonka, E., & Lamb, M. J. (2006). Evolution in four dimension: Genetic, epigenetic, behavioral, and symbolic variation in the history of life. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.
Kaplan, H., & Hill, K. (1985). Food sharing among Ache foragers: Tests of explanatory hypotheses. Current Anthropology, 26, 223–245.
Liu, E., & Hanauer, N. (2011). The Gardens of democracy: A new American story of citizenship, the economy, and the role of government. Seattle: Sasquatch.
Margulis, L. (1970). Origin of eukaryotic cells. New Haven: Yale University Press.
Mas-Colell, A., Whinston, M., & Green, J. (1995). Microeconomic Theory. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Maynard Smith, J., & Szathmary, E. (1995). The major transitions of life. New York: W.H. Freeman.
Maynard Smith, J., & Szathmary, E. (1999). The origins of life: From the birth of life to the origin of language. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Mayr, E. (1961). Cause and effect in biology. Science, 134(3489), 1501–1506.
McGinnis, M. D. (1999). Polycentric governance and development: Readings from the workshop in political theory and policy analysis. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.
Mirowski, P. (1989). More heat than light: Economics as social physics, physics as nature’s economics. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Okasha, S. (2006). Evolution and the levels of selection. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Ostrom, E. (1990). Governing the commons: The Evolution of institutions for collective Action. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Ostrom, E. (2010). Beyond markets and states: Polycentric governance of complex economic systems. American Economic Review, 100, 1–33.
Pagel, M., & Mace, R. (2004). The cultural wealth of nations. Nature, 428, 275–278.
Pickett, K., & Wilkinson, J. B. (2009). The spirit level: Why greater equality makes societies stronger. London: Bloomsbury Press.
Pinker, S. (2012). The false allure of group selection. Retrieved July 20, 2012, from http://edge.org/conversation/the-false-allure-of-group-selection.
Pruitt, J. N., & Goodnight, C. J. (2014). Site-specific group selection drives locally adapted group compositions. Nature, 514(7522), 359–362. doi:10.1038/nature13811.
Richerson, P. J., & Boyd, R. (2005). Not by genes alone: How culture transformed human evolution. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Seeley, T. D. (2010). Honeybee democracy. Princeton: Princeton University Press.
Seeley, T. D., Visscher, P. K., Schlegel, T., Hogan, P. M., Franks, N. R., & Marshall, J. R. (2012). Stop signals provide cross inhibition in collective decision-making by honeybee swarms. Science, 335(6064), 108–111. doi:10.1126/science.1210361.
Smith, A. (1759). The theory of moral sentiments. New York: Empire.
Smith, A. (1776). An inquiry into the nature and causes of the wealth of nations. New York: Simon and Brown.
Sober, E., & Wilson, D. S. (1998). Unto others: The evolution and psychology of unselfish behavior. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.
Sontag, C., Wilson, D. S., & Wilcox, R. S. (2006). Social foraging in Bufo americanus tadpoles. Animal Behaviour, 72(6), 1451–1456. doi:10.1016/j.anbehav.2006.05.006.
Strier, K. B. (2011). Primate behavioral ecology (4th ed.). Boston: Pearson.
Thaler, R. H., & Sunstein, C. R. (2008). Nudge: Improving decisions about health, wealth, and happiness. New Haven: Yale University Press.
Tomasello, M. (2009). Why we cooperate. Boston: MIT Press.
Turchin, P. (2003). Historical dynamics: Why states rise and fall. Princeton: Princeton University Press.
Turchin, P. (2005). War and peace and war. Upper Saddle River, NJ: Pi Press.
Turchin, P. (2010). Warfare and the evolution of social complexity: A multilevel selection approach. Structure and Dynamics, 4(3), 1–37.
Veblen, T. (1908). Professor Clark’s economics. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 22, 147–195.
Walras, L. (1874). Elements of pure economics: Or the theory of social wealth. London: Routledge.
Wexler, B. E. (2006). Brain and culture. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.
Williams, G. C. (1966). Adaptation and natural selection: A critique of some current evolutionary thought. Princeton: Princeton University Press.
Wilson, D. S. (2012a). Clash of Paradigms: Why proponents of multilevel selection theory and inclusive fitness theory sometimes (but not always) misunderstand each other. Social Evolution Forum.
Wilson, D. S. (2002). Darwin’s cathedral: Evolution, religion and the nature of society. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Wilson, D. S. (2004). The new fable of the bees: Multilevel selection, adaptive societies, and the concept of self interest. Advances in Austrian Economics, 7(04), 201–220. doi:10.1016/S1529-2134(04)07009-7.
Wilson, D. S., & Wilson, E. O. (2007). Rethinking the theoretical foundation of sociobiology. Quarterly Review of Biology, 82, 327–348.
Wilson, D. S. (2012). A tale of two classics. New Scientist, 30, 30–31.
Wilson, E. O. (2012). The Social conquest of earth. New York: Norton.
Wilson, D. S., Hayes, S. C., Biglan, A., & Embry, D. D. (2014). Evolving the future: Toward a science of intentional change. Behavioral and Brain Sciences, 37, 395–416.
Wilson, D. S. (2015). Does altruism exist? Culture, Genes, and the welfare of others. New Haven: Yale University Press.
Author information
Authors and Affiliations
Corresponding author
Rights and permissions
About this article
Cite this article
Wilson, D.S., Gowdy, J.M. Human ultrasociality and the invisible hand: foundational developments in evolutionary science alter a foundational concept in economics. J Bioecon 17, 37–52 (2015). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10818-014-9192-x
Received:
Accepted:
Published:
Issue Date:
DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10818-014-9192-x