Skip to main content
Log in

Play locally, learn globally: group selection and structural basis of cooperation

  • Published:
Journal of Bioeconomics Aims and scope

Abstract

In group-structured populations, altruistic cooperation among unrelated group members may be sustainable even when the evolution of behavioral traits is governed by a payoff-based replicator dynamic. This paper explores the importance in this dynamic of two aspects of group structure: global or local interaction in a public goods game and global or local cultural transmission (learning) of behavioral traits. To clarify the underlying dynamic, I derive an extension of the Price equation for the decomposition of changes in the population frequency of a binary trait. I use this to analyze the effect of different structures of interaction and learning on within- and between-group variances of the frequency of cooperative behaviors and thereby on the evolution of cooperation. Of the four population structures given by global/local learning and global/local interaction, local interaction with global learning provides the most favorable environment for the evolution of cooperation. This combination of learning and interaction structures supports a high level of between-group variance in the frequency of cooperative types, so that most cooperators benefit from being in groups composed mostly of cooperators. However, while global learning is essential to the evolution of cooperation, cooperation is more robust when learning is not entirely global because local learning process, ironically, limits the extent to which defectors can free ride on cooperative group members.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

References

  • Axelrod R. (1986) An evolutionary approach to norms. The American Political Science Review 80(4): 1095–1111

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bergstrom T.C. (2002) Evolution of social behavior: Individual and group selection. Journal of Economic Perspectives 16(2): 67–88

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bergstrom T.C. (2003) The algebra of assortativity and the evolution of cooperation. International Game Theory Review 5: 211–228

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Binford L.R. (2001) Constructing frames of reference. University of California Press, Berkeley, California

    Google Scholar 

  • Boehm C. (1997) Impact of the human egalitarian syndrome on Darwinian selection mechanics. American Naturalist 150: S100–S121

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bowles S., Choi J.-K., Hopfensitz A. (2003) The coevolution of individual behaviors and social institutions. Journal of Theoretical Biology 233(2): 135–147

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Boyd R., Richerson P.J. (1985) Culture and the evolutionary process. University of Chicago Press, Chicago

    Google Scholar 

  • Boyd R., Richerson P.J. (1988) The evolution of reciprocity in sizable groups. Journal of Theoretical Biology 132: 337–356

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Boyd R., Richerson P.J. (1992) Punishment allows the evolution of cooperation (or anything else) in sizable groups. Ethology and Sociobiology 13(3): 171–195

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Boyd R., Richerson P.J. (2002) Group beneficial norms can spread rapidly in a structured population. Journal of Theoretical Biology 215: 287–296

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Boyd R., Gintis H., Bowles S., Richerson P.J. (2003) The evolution of altruistic punishment. Proceedings of the National Academy of Science 100(6): 3531–3535

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cohen D., Eshel I. (1976) On the founder effect and the evolution of altruistic traits. Theoretical Population Biology 10: 276–302

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dawes R.M., Thaler R.H. (1988) Anomalies: Cooperation. Journal of Economic Perspectives 2(3): 187–197

    Google Scholar 

  • Fehr E., Gachter S. (2000) Fairness and retaliation: The economics of reciprocity. Journal of Economic Perspectives 14(3): 159–181

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grafen A. (1979) The hawk-dove game played between relatives. Animal Behaviour 27: 905–907

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hamilton W.D. (1964) The genetical theory of social behaviour. Journal of Theoretical Biology 7: 1–52

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kaplan H., Gurven M., Hill K. (2005) The natural history of human food sharing and cooperation: A review and a new multi-individual approach to the negotiation of norms. In: Gintis H., Bowles S., Boyd R., Fehr E. (eds) Moral sentiments and material interests: On the foundations of cooperation in economic life. MIT Press, Cambridge, MA

    Google Scholar 

  • Knudsen T. (2002) The evolution of cooperation in structured population. Constitutional Political Economy 13(2): 129–148

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Landa J.T. (1981) A theory of the ethnically homogeneous middleman group: An institutional alternative to contract law. Journal of Legal Studies 10(2): 349–362

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Landa J.T. (1999) The law and bioeconomics of ethnic cooperation and conflict in plural societies of Southeast Asia: A theory of Chinese merchant success. Journal of Bioeconomics 1(3): 269–284

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Maynard Smith J. (1964) Group selection and kin selection. Nature 201(4924): 1145–1147

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mitteldorf J., Wilson D.S. (2000) Population viscosity and the evolution of altruism. Journal of Theoretical Biology 204: 481–496

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Myerson R.B., Pollock G.B., Swinkels J.M. (1991) Viscous population equilibria. Games and Economic Behavior 3: 101–109

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Price G.R. (1972) Extension of covariance selection mathematics. Annals of Human Genetics 35: 485–490

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Skyrms B. (2004) The stag hunt and the evolution of social structure. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, MA

    Google Scholar 

  • Wade M.J. (1978) A critical review of the models of group selection. Quarterly Review of Biology 53(2): 101–114

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wilson D.S. (1975) A theory of group selection. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences of the United States of America 72(1): 143–146

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wilson D.S. (1977) Structured demes and the evolution of group-advantageous traits. American Naturalist 111(977): 157–185

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wilson D.S. (1979) Structured demes and trait-group variation. American Naturalist 113(4): 606–610

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wilson D.S., Pollock G.B., Dugatkin L.A. (1992) Can altruism evolve in purely viscous populations? Evolutionary Ecology 6: 331–341

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wilson D.S., Sober E. (1994) Reintroducing group selection to the human behavioral sciences. Behavioral and Brain Sciences 17(4): 585–654

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wright S. (1945) Tempo and mode in evolution: A critical review. Ecology 26(4): 415–419

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Jung-Kyoo Choi.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Choi, JK. Play locally, learn globally: group selection and structural basis of cooperation. J Bioecon 10, 239–257 (2008). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10818-008-9039-4

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10818-008-9039-4

Keywords

JEL classifications

Navigation