Skip to main content
Log in

Taxing telecommunications in developing countries

  • Policy Watch
  • Published:
International Tax and Public Finance Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Developing countries apply numerous sector-specific taxes to telecommunications. This paper explores whether there is an economic rationale for sector-specific taxes on telecommunications and, if so, what form they should take to balance the competing goals of promoting connectivity and mobilizing revenues. A survey of the literature finds that limited competition likely creates rents that could efficiently be taxed. We look at how sector-specific taxes could best be levied in addition to standard income and value-added taxes, based on capturing rents and minimizing distortions. Taxes that target possible economic rents or profits are preferable, but their administrative challenges may necessitate reliance on service excises at the cost of higher consumer prices and lower connectivity. Taxes on capital inputs and consumer access, which distort production and restrict network access, should be avoided, as should tax incentives, which are generally not needed to attract foreign capital.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Institutional subscriptions

Fig. 1

Source: World Development Indicators, GSMA

Fig. 2

Source: International Telecommunications Union

Fig. 3

Source: International Telecommunications Union

Fig. 4

Source: GSMAintelligence.com

Fig. 5

Source: Agence de Régulation des Postes et Télécommunications

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Spectrum fees are charges that telecom operators pay, usually to the local telecom regulatory authority, to rent segments of the electromagnetic spectrum over which to transmit signals.

  2. Subscriber identity module (SIM) cards are the integrated circuits, or smart chips, used in Global System for Mobile Communications (GSM) phones and other devices to store the owner’s identity and contact number.

  3. 2G is distinguished from third generation (3G) and later generations (4G and 5G, now prevalent in developed countries) by the speed of transmission. 2G networks generally support voice communication and texting only; 3G and later generations allow higher-volume data transmissions, thus supporting smart phones and full Internet access.

  4. Data are from the International Telecommunications Unions and GSMA databases. For detailed data on penetration rates by country, see https://www.itu.int/en/ITU-D/Statistics/Pages/default.aspx.

  5. For a review of the literature on mobile telecommunications, see Donner (2008), Aker and Mbiti (2010), Lam and Shiu (2010), Andrianaivo and Kpodar (2012), Pradhan et al. (2014) and Kumar et al. (2015). Asongu (2015) offers a preliminary study on the relationship between cell phone use and income inequality.

  6. Following the pioneering work of Hardy (1980) on the impact of fixed lines on growth, Cronin et al. (1991) find that growth is driven by investments in telecom, as well as the reverse. Röller and Waverman (2001) use a simultaneous equation model to address this problem in a fixed-line network. Waverman et al. (2005) apply a similar model, as well as an endogenous growth model, to cell phone data, ushering in a wave of studies on cell phones and growth. See also Datta and Agarwal (2004) and Lee et al. (2012).

  7. These findings are comparable to Waverman et al. (2005), taking into account the two studies’ different measures of growth in mobile penetration rates.

  8. See Röller and Waverman (2001) for telecommunications and Lee et al. (2012) for cell phones.

  9. See, for example, Economides (1996), Rouvinen (2006), Doganoglu and Grzybowski (2007), Wu and Chu (2009), and Grajek (2003).

  10. For a thorough discussion of two-sided markets, see Evans (2003) and Rochet and Tirole (2003).

  11. See https://www.vodafone.com/what-we-do/services/m-pesa.

  12. Defined as 1 gigabyte of data, 250 min of telephony, and 100 text messages.

  13. A more detailed discussion of telecom elasticities can be found in Matheson and Petit (2017).

  14. VoIP requires a broadband (3G) connection and is therefore less widespread in lower-income countries, where affordability often limits access to 2G technology. VoIP services such as Skype, Facetime, and WhatsApp are generally referred to as “over-the-top” providers.

  15. The spectrum has numerous wavelengths, each with its own technical characteristics best suited to different types of transmission. Generally, higher frequencies have clearer reception but carry over a shorter range than lower frequencies. Given current technology, wavelengths in the 800–900 megahertz range are best suited for cell phone communications, although frequencies as high as 2+ gigahertz are sometimes used. Other wavelengths are suitable for commercial radio transmission, remote control devices (for television, garage doors, etc.), satellite communications, global positioning systems, emergency vehicles communications (police, coast guards, etc.), and other communications instruments.

  16. Some countries (e.g., India) have allowed a large number of operators to use very narrow “slices” of the cell phone compatible spectrum. Although this policy increases competition, a major drawback is that each operator has very limited space to expand services.

  17. The dominant firm is often the incumbent telecom operator, which may still be partially or fully owned by the government. See GSMAIntelligence.com for data and more details.

  18. A substantial literature reviewed in Vogelsang (2003) addresses the issue of whether price regulation is necessary to ensure reasonable network access charges. Although models suggest that market forces should usually provide for reasonable charges, access charge regulation is still not uncommon in developing countries. See GSMA (2012b).

  19. Broad-based taxation implies subjecting a clearly defined base, such as labor income, capital income, or final consumption, to uniform tax rates with few exemptions for specific activities. It does not mean that the tax base should be widened to include gross transaction values, as is the case for turnover taxes and transaction taxes, since these types of taxes cascade and cause distortions.

  20. For a detailed discussion of this issue, see https://www.oecd.org/tax/beps/.

  21. Data are for 2018 and are from the International Monetary Fund revenue database.

  22. Some countries, however, set prices administratively based on various pricing algorithms (Bauer 2003).

  23. Telecom MNEs may be better able to manage risk than some developing country governments. However, risk management may include reduced investment, resulting in higher prices and/or lower service quality.

  24. Profit and gross revenue sharing are fully analogous to CIT and service excises dealt with in the following sections.

  25. For an in-depth discussion of spectrum license valuations, see Hazlett (2008), Bazelon and McHenry (2013), and Prasad (2015).

  26. For a deeper discussion of rent taxes, see Boadway and Keen (2010) and Land (2010).

  27. Mintz (2017) notes that where both a rent tax and the standard CIT are applied, their interaction can interfere with the neutrality of the rent tax with respect to investment decisions.

  28. There are several methods for doing this (Schatan, 2012), including the payment of excessive royalties for firm-specific technology, the payment of excessive management or service fees, the over-invoicing for inputs through offshore cost centers (notably capital goods), and excessive leverage (thin capitalization).

  29. In the case of Vodafone, Indian cell phone license holder Hutchison avoided US$ 2.6 billion in capital gains tax by selling its offshore subsidiary to Vodafone, rather than directly selling the license. See IMF et al. (2017).

  30. This was the rationale for the US telephone excise introduced in 1898, which persists to this day despite now universal coverage. Cremer et al. (2001) discuss how commodity taxes can enhance progressivity under certain conditions.

  31. For a given level of service prices, both types of excise take a certain percentage of gross revenues; as prices change, however, an ad valorem excise will continue to take the same percentage, while the percentage taken by the specific excise will move inversely with prices.

  32. See, for example, Hamilton (1999) and Anderson et al. (2001).

  33. See, for example, Delipalla and Keen (1992) and Carbonnier (2014).

  34. The traffic subject to these charges is generally monitored by private engineering consulting firms which promote the tax as a business strategy and are usually paid a percentage of the revenue they collect—up to 50 percent in some cases.

  35. Although assessing the size of the illegal market is challenging, GSMA (2014) estimates that in Ghana, 10 percent of international calls were re-routed through SIM boxes. Authorities have consequently deployed sophisticated means to track SIM boxes and their owners.

  36. Handsets may also be subject to elevated customs charges.

  37. Ideally, this would be accomplished by avoiding BTTs altogether, since exempting mobile money would simply lead to base shifting, but in any event the BTT rate should be kept as low as possible to minimize financial exclusion and cascading.

  38. See Council Implementing Regulation (EU) No. 1042/2013 of October 7, 2013, amending Implementing Regulation (EU) No. 282/2011, as regards the place of supply of services, as well as OECD (2017).

  39. Some countries have applied the VAT to net international revenue (i.e., access fees charged to, minus access fees paid to foreign carriers), which amounts to applying the VAT to net exports. Given the net incoming traffic to most low-income countries, removing such practices has met with fierce resistance.

  40. The application of VAT to international calls is part of a broader debate on the taxation of e-commerce (whether goods are tangible or intangible). While the basic destination principle remains, its application is subject to significant coordination issues compounded by compliance and enforcement challenges that can only be tackled through the uniform implementation of common norms. Relying on the nationality of the SIM card in the case of telecoms, simplifying registration for non-resident traders, and reverse-charging VAT are all parts of a rapidly developing arsenal of policy and administrative tools to prevent the erosion of the tax base that accompanied the development of the digital economy. For an overview of this debate, see Hellerstein (2016) and Agrawal and Fox (2016).

  41. Most World Trade Organization members have been required to phase out export processing zones.

References

  • African Development Bank. (2013). Financial inclusion and integration through mobile payments and transfer. Nairobi: African Development Bank.

    Google Scholar 

  • Agrawal, D. R., & Fox, W. (2016). Taxes in an E-commerce generation. CESifo Working Paper Series No. 6050.

  • Aker, J. (2010). Information from markets near and far: Mobile phones and agricultural markets in Niger. American Economic Journal: Applied Economics, 2, 46–59.

    Google Scholar 

  • Aker, J. C., & Fafchamps, M. (2015). Mobile phone coverage and producer markets: Evidence from West Africa. World Bank Economic Review, 29(2), 262–292.

    Google Scholar 

  • Aker, J. C., & Mbiti, I. (2010). Mobile phones and economic development in Africa. Journal of Economic Perspective, 24(3), 207–232.

    Google Scholar 

  • Anderson, S., de Palma, A., & Kreider, B. (2001). The efficiency of indirect taxes under imperfect competition. Journal of Public Economics, 81(2), 231–251.

    Google Scholar 

  • Andini, C., & Cabral, R. (2013). How do mobile voice operators compete? IVQR estimates. Applied Economic Letters, 20(1), 18–22.

    Google Scholar 

  • Andrianaivo, M., & Kpodar, K. (2012). Mobile phones, financial inclusion and growth. Review of Economics and Institutions, 3(2), 1–30.

    Google Scholar 

  • Asongu, S. A. (2015). The impact of mobile phone penetration on African inequality. International Journal of Social Economics, 42(8), 706–716.

    Google Scholar 

  • Averch, H., & Johnson, L. (1962). The behavior of the firm under regulatory constraint. American Economic Review, 52, 1052–1069.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bauer, J. (2003). Impact of license fees on the prices of mobile voice service. Telecommunications Policy, 27, 417–434.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bazelon, C., & McHenry, G. (2013). Spectrum value. Telecommunications Policy, 32, 737–747.

    Google Scholar 

  • Boadway, R., & Keen, M. (2010). Principles of resource taxation for low-income countries. In P. Daniel, M. Keen, & C. McPherson (Eds.), The taxation of petroleum and minerals: Principles, problems and practices (pp. 13–74). London: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Boniecki, D., Marcati, C., Abou-Zahr, W., Alatovic, T., & El Hamamsy, O. (2016). Telecommunications industry at Cliff’s edge: Time for bold decisions. McKinsey and Company.

  • Carbonnier, C. (2014). The incidence of non-linear price-dependent consumption taxes. Journal of Public Economics, 118, 111–119.

    Google Scholar 

  • Commerce Commission. (2003). Review of price elasticities of demand for fixed line and mobile telecommunications services. Government of New Zealand.

  • Cramton, P. (2002). Spectrum auctions. In M. Cave, et al. (Eds.), Handbook of telecommunications economics (pp. 605–639). Amsterdam: Elsevier Science.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cremer, H., Pestiau, P., & Rochet, J. C. (2001). Direct versus indirect taxation: The design of tax structure revisited. International Economic Review, 42(30), 781–799.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cronin, F. J., Parker, E. B., Colleran, E. K., & Gold, M. A. (1991). Telecommunications infrastructure and economic growth: An analysis of causality. Telecommunications Policy, 15(6), 529535.

    Google Scholar 

  • Datta, A., & Agarwal, S. (2004). Telecommunications and economic growth: A panel data approach. Applied Economics, 36, 1649–1654.

    Google Scholar 

  • Davidson, C., & Martin, L. (1985). General equilibrium tax incidence under imperfect competition: A quantity-setting supergame analysis. Journal of Political Economy, 93(6), 1212–1223.

    Google Scholar 

  • Delipalla, S., & Keen, M. (1992). The comparison between ad valorem and specific taxation under imperfect competition. Journal of Public Economics, 49, 351–367.

    Google Scholar 

  • Diamond, P. A., & Mirrlees, J. A. (1971). Optimal taxation and public production I: Production efficiency. American Economic Review, 61(1), 8–27.

    Google Scholar 

  • Doganoglu, T., & Grzybowski, L. (2007). Estimating network effects in mobile telephony in Germany. Information Economics and Policy, 19(1), 65–79.

    Google Scholar 

  • Donner, J. (2008). Research approaches to mobile use in the developing world: A review of the literature. The Information Society: An International Journal, 24(3), 140–159.

    Google Scholar 

  • Duncombe, R. (2016). Mobile phones for agricultural and rural development: A literature review and suggestions for future research. European Journal of Development Research, 28(2), 213–235.

    Google Scholar 

  • Economides, N. (1996). The economics of networks. International Journal of Industrial Organization, 14(6), 673–699.

    Google Scholar 

  • Evans, D. (2003). The antitrust economic of multi-sided platform markets. Yale Journal on Regulation, 20, 325–381.

    Google Scholar 

  • Garbacz, C., & Thompson, H. G. (2007). Demand for telecommunication services in developing countries. Telecommunications Policy, 31, 276–289.

    Google Scholar 

  • Grajek, M. (2003). Estimating network effects and compatibility: Evidence from the polish mobile market. Information Economics and Policy, 22, 130–143.

    Google Scholar 

  • GSMA. (2008). Comparison of fixed and mobile cost structures. Retrieved July 31, 2020 from https://www.gsma.com/publicpolicy/wp-content/uploads/2012/09/Tax-Comparison-of-fixedand-mobile-cost-structures.pdf.

  • GSMA. (2012a). The impact of taxation on the development of the mobile broadband sector. Retrieved July 31, 2020 from https://www.gsma.com/latinamerica/wp-content/uploads/2012/06/tasreport.pdf.

  • GSMA. (2012b). Competition and the mobile sector – in developed and developing countries. Retrieved July 31, 2020 from https://pdfs.semanticscholar.org/959e/14ec86389dd9f581704d444fac32bf835e98.pdf.

  • GSMA. (2014). Surtaxes on international incoming traffic in Africa. Retrieved July 31, 2020 from https://www.gsma.com/publicpolicy/wpcontent/uploads/2012/03/Surtaxes_on_International_Incoming_Traffic_in_Africa_FULLREPORT_WEB.pdf.

  • GSMA. (2016). Digital inclusion and mobile sector taxation. Retrieved July 31, 2020 from https://www.gsma.com/mobilefordevelopment/wp-content/uploads/2016/07/Digital-Inclusion-and-Mobile-Sector-Taxation-2016.pdf.

  • GSMA. (2019). Rethinking mobile taxation to improve connectivity. Retrieved July 31, 2020 from https://www.gsma.com/publicpolicy/wp-content/uploads/2019/02/Rethinking-mobiletaxation-to-improve-connectivity_Feb19.pdf.

  • Haan, M. A., & Toolsema, L. A. (2011). License auctions when winning bids are financed through debt. Journal of Industrial Economics, 59(2), 254–281.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hamilton, S. (1999). Tax incidence under oligopoly: A comparison of policy approaches. Journal of Public Economics, 71, 233–245.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hardy, A. P. (1980). The role of telephone in economic development. Telecommunications Policy, 4(4), 278–286.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hazlett, T. (2008). Property rights and wireless license values. Journal of Law and Economics, 51(3), 563–598.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hazlett, T., Munoz, R., & Avanzini, D. (2011). What really matters in spectrum allocation design. George Mason University Law and Economics Research Paper Series 11–48.

  • Heckemeyer, J. H., & Overesch, M. (2013). Multinationals’ profit response to tax differentials: Effect size and shifting channels. ZEW Discussion Papers, No. 13-045.

  • Hellerstein, W. (2016). Taxing remote sales in the digital age: A global perspective. American University Law Review, 65(5), 1195–1239.

    Google Scholar 

  • IMF, OECD, UN & World Bank. (2015). Options for low income countries’ effective and efficient use of tax incentives for investment: A report to the G-20 Development Working Group, October 2015. Retrieved July 31, 2020 from https://www.imf.org/external/np/g20/pdf/101515.pdf.

  • IMF, OECD, UN, & World Bank Group. (2017). The taxation of offshore indirect transfers—A toolkit. Retrieved July 31, 2020 from https://www.taxplatform.org/sites/pct/files/publications/PCT_Toolkit_The_Taxation_of_Offshore_Indirect_Transfers_June_2020.pdf.

  • Janssen, M. C. W., & Karamychev, V. A. (2009). Auctions, aftermarket competition, and risk attitudes. International Journal of Industrial Organization, 27(2), 274–285.

    Google Scholar 

  • Jensen, R. T. (2007). The digital provide: Information, technology, market performance, and welfare in the South Indian fisheries sector. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 122(3), 879924.

    Google Scholar 

  • Katz, M., & Rosen, H. S. (1985). Tax analysis in an oligopoly model. Public Finance Quarterly, 13(1), 3–19.

    Google Scholar 

  • Katz, M., & Shapiro, C. (1985). Network externalities, competition and compatibility. American Economic Review, 75(3), 414–440.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kirilenko, A., & Summers, V. (2003). Bank debt taxes: Yield vs. disintermediation. In P. Honohan (Ed.), Taxation of financial intermediation: Theory and practice for emerging economies. Oxford: World Bank and Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kumar, R. R., Kumar, R. D., & Patel, A. (2015). Accounting for telecommunications contribution to economic growth: A study of small pacific island states. Telecommunications Policy, 39, 284–295.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kuroda, T., & del Pilar Baquero Forero, M. (2017). The effects of spectrum allocation mechanisms on market outcomes: Auctions vs. beauty contests. Telecommunications Policy, 41(5–6), 341–354.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kwerel, E. (2000). Spectrum auctions do not raise the price of wireless services: Theory and evidence. Washington, DC: Federal Communications Commission, Office of Plans and Policy.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kwon, Y., Lee, J., & Oh, Y. (2010). Economic and policy implications of spectrum license fee payment methods. Telecommunications Policy, 34(3), 175–184.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lam, P.-L., & Shiu, A. (2010). Economic growth, telecommunications development and productivity growth of the telecommunications sector: Evidence around the world. Telecommunications Policy, 34(4), 185–199.

    Google Scholar 

  • Land, B. C. (2010). Resource rent taxes: A re-appraisal. In P. Daniel, M. Keen, & C. McPherson (Eds.), The taxation of petroleum and minerals: Principles, problems and practices (pp. 241–262). London: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lee, S. H., Levendis, J., & Gutiérrez, L. (2012). Telecommunications and economic growth: An empirical analysis of Sub-Saharan Africa. Applied Economics, 44(4), 461–469.

    Google Scholar 

  • Li, Y., & Lyons, B. (2012). Market structure, regulation and the speed of mobile network penetration. International Journal of Industrial Organization, 30(6), 697–707.

    Google Scholar 

  • Liu, L., & Altshuler, R. (2013). Measuring the burden of the corporate income tax under imperfect competition. National Tax Journal, 66(1), 215–237.

    Google Scholar 

  • Matheson, T., & Petit, P. (2017). Taxing telecommunications in developing countries. IMF Working Paper 17/247, International Monetary Fund, Washington DC.

  • McMillan, J. (1995). Why auction the spectrum? Telecommunications Policy, 19(3), 191–199.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mintz, J. (2017). Taxes, royalties and cross-border resource investments. In P. Daniel, M. Keen, A. Swistak, & V. Thuronyi (Eds.), International taxation and the extractive industries (pp. 306–331). London: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Morris, A. C. (2005). Spectrum auctions: Distortionary input tax or efficient revenue instrument? Telecommunications Policy, 29(9–10), 687–709.

    Google Scholar 

  • Muto, M. T., & Yamano, (2009). The impact of mobile phone coverage expansion on market participation: Panel data evidence from Uganda. World Development, 37(12), 1887–1896.

    Google Scholar 

  • OECD. (2014). International traffic termination. OECD Digital Economy Papers No. 238.

  • OECD. (2017). International VAT/GST guidelines. Paris: OECD Publishing.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pradhan, R., Arvin, M. B., Norman, N. R., & Bele, S. K. (2014). Economic growth and the development of telecommunications infrastructure in the G-20 countries: A panel-VAR approach. Telecommunications Policy, 38(7), 634–649.

    Google Scholar 

  • Prasad, R. (2015). The production function methodology for estimating the value of spectrum. Telecommunications Policy, 39(1), 77–88.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rochet, J. C., & Tirole, J. (2003). Platform competition in two-sided markets. Journal of the European Economic Association, 1(4), 990–1029.

    Google Scholar 

  • Röller, L.-H., & Waverman, L. (2001). Telecommunications infrastructure and economic development: A simultaneous approach. American Economic Review, 91(4), 909–923.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rouvinen, P. (2006). Diffusion of digital mobile telephone: Are developing countries different? Telecommunications Policy, 30(1), 46–63.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schatan, R. (2012). Tax minimizing strategies and the arm’s-length principle. Tax Notes International, 9, 121–126.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sridhar, K., & Sridhar, V. (2007). Telecommunications infrastructure and economic growth: Evidence from developing countries. Applied Econometrics and International Development, 7(20), 37–56.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sung, N. (2014). Market concentration and competition in OECD mobile telecommunications markets. Applied Economics, 46(25), 3037–3048.

    Google Scholar 

  • Symeou, P. (2011). Economy size and performance: An efficiency analysis in the telecommunications sector. Telecommunications Policy, 35(5), 426–440.

    Google Scholar 

  • Vogelsang, I. (2003). Price Regulation of Access to Telecommunications Networks. Journal of Economic Literature, 41, 830–862.

    Google Scholar 

  • Waverman, L., Meschi, M., & Fuss, M. (2005). The impact of telecoms on economic growth in developing countries. Moving the debate forward. The Vodafone Policy Paper Series, 2, 10–23.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wu, F.-S., & Chu, W.-L. (2009). Diffusion models of mobile telephony. Information Economics and Policy, 22, 130–143.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

The authors are grateful to many colleagues and external collaborators who commented on various versions of this paper, including anonymous reviewers, Ruud de Mooij, Michael Keen, Alex Klemm, Victoria Perry, Christophe Waerzeggers, World Bank colleagues, and others. Remaining errors and omissions are the sole responsibility of the authors.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Thornton Matheson.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Matheson, T., Petit, P. Taxing telecommunications in developing countries. Int Tax Public Finance 28, 248–280 (2021). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10797-020-09621-6

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10797-020-09621-6

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation