International Tax and Public Finance

, Volume 24, Issue 5, pp 903–926 | Cite as

Taxes in an e-commerce generation

Policy Watch

Abstract

Rapid growth in e-commerce has altered the ability of jurisdictions to enforce commodity taxes on a destination basis. This results in different effective tax rates depending on the way in which goods and services are purchased and the characteristics of both the products and the sellers. We discuss the arguments for the destination principle as the appropriate place-of-taxation rule for consumption taxation of cross-border trade. We analyze various recent reforms to the value-added tax in the European Union in response to e-commerce. We then examine various policy options in the USA—maintaining the status quo, changing nexus rules, states adopting information reporting, and national reforms that require firms to remit taxes regardless of physical presence—and relate them to the recent European reforms. We conclude based on our analysis and the recent European Union experience that reforms at the national level appear to be the important next step to enforcing commodity taxes at destination in the USA.

Keywords

Destination taxation Origin taxation Commodity taxes Online shopping E-commerce Tax competition Digital products 

JEL Classification

H2 H7 L81 R5 

References

  1. Agrawal, D. R. (2014). LOST in America: Evidence on local sales taxes from national panel data. Regional Science and Urban Economics, 49, 147–163.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  2. Agrawal, D. R. (2015a). The tax gradient: Spatial aspects of fiscal competition. American Economic Journal: Economic Policy, 7(2), 1–29.Google Scholar
  3. Agrawal, D. R. (2015b). The Internet as a tax haven? The effect of the Internet on tax competition. SSRN working paper.Google Scholar
  4. Alm, J., & Melnik, M. I. (2010). Do eBay sellers comply with state sales taxes? National Tax Journal, 63(2), 215–236.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  5. Alm, J., & Melnik, M. I. (2012). Cross-border shopping and state use tax liabilities: Evidence from eBay transactions. Public Budgeting & Finance, 32(1): 5–35.Google Scholar
  6. Anderson, J. E. (2015). Paying the state use tax: Is a ‘nudge’ enough? Public Finance Review. doi:10.1177/1091142115614390.
  7. Ballard, C. L., & Lee, J. (2007). Internet purchases, cross-border shopping and sales taxes. National Tax Journal, 60(4), 711–725.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  8. Baugh, B., Ben-David, I., & Park, H. (2014). The Amazon tax: Empirical evidence from Amazon and main street retailers. NBER working paper.Google Scholar
  9. Behrens, K., Hamilton, J., Ottaviano, G. I. P., & Thisse, J.-F. (2009). Commodity tax competition and industry location under the destination and origin principle. Regional Science and Urban Economics, 39, 422–433.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  10. Bird, R. M. (2012). The GST/HST: Creating an integrated sales tax in federal country. SPP Research Papers, 5(12), 1–38.Google Scholar
  11. Bird, R. M., & Gendron, P. P. (1998). Dual VATs and cross-border trade: Two problems, one solution? International Tax and Public Finance, 5(3), 429–442.Google Scholar
  12. Bruce, D., & Fox, W. F. (2013). An analysis of Internet sales taxation and the small seller exemption. Office of Advocacy, Small Business Administration, November.Google Scholar
  13. Bruce, D., Fox, W., & Luna, L. A. (2009). State and local sales tax revenue losses from electronic commerce. State Tax Notes, May 18, 2009.Google Scholar
  14. Bruce, D., Fox, W., & Luna, L. A. (2015). E-tailer sales tax nexus and state tax policies. National Tax Journal, 68(3S), 735–766.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  15. Bruce, D., Fox, W., & Murray, M. (2003). To tax or not to tax? The case of electronic commerce. Contemporary Economic Policy, 21, 25–40.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  16. Diamond, P. A., & Mirrlees, J. A. (1971). Optimal taxation and public production I: Production efficiency. American Economic Review, 61(1), 8–27.Google Scholar
  17. Einav, L., Knoepfle, D., Levin, J., & Sundaresan, N. (2014). Sales taxes and Internet commerce. American Economic Review, 104(1), 1–26.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  18. Ellison, G., & Ellison, S. F. (2009). Tax sensitivity and home state preferences in Internet purchasing. American Economic Journal: Economic Policy, 1(2), 53–71.Google Scholar
  19. Fox, W. F. (2012). Sales and excise taxes. In R. Ebel & J. E. Petersen (Eds.), Oxford handbook on state and local finance. New York: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
  20. Fox, W. F., Luna, L. A., & Schaur, G. (2014). Destination taxation and evasion: Evidence from U.S. inter-state commodity flows. Journal of Accounting and Economics, 57, 43–57.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  21. Fox, W. F., & Yang, Z. (2016). Destination taxation: Road to economic success? National Tax Journal, 69(2), 285–314.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  22. Goolsbee, A. (2000). In a world without borders: The impact of taxes on Internet commerce. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 115(2), 561–576.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  23. Goolsbee, A., Lovenheim, M. F., & Slemrod, J. (2010). Playing with fire: Cigarettes, taxes and competition from the Internet. American Economic Journal: Economic Policy, 2(1), 131–154.Google Scholar
  24. Hatta, T. (1986). Welfare effects of changing commodity tax rates toward uniformity. Journal of Public Economics, 29, 99–112.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  25. Hellerstein, W. (2016). A Hitchhiker’s guide to the OECD’s international VAT/GST guidelines. Florida Tax Review, 18(10), 589–637.Google Scholar
  26. Hellerstein, W., & Gillis, T. H. (2010). The VAT in the European Union. Tax Notes, 127, 461–471.Google Scholar
  27. Johannesen, N. (2010). Imperfect tax competition for profits, asymmetric equilibrium, and beneficial tax havens. Journal of International Economics, 81(2), 253–264.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  28. Keen, M., & Hellerstein, W. (2010). Interjurisdictional issues in the design of a VAT. Tax Law Review, 63(2), 359–408.Google Scholar
  29. Keen, M., & Lahiri, S. (1998). The comparison between destination and origin principles under imperfect competition. Journal of International Economics, 45, 323–350.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  30. Keen, M., Lahiri, S., & Raimondos-Møller, P. (2002). Tax principles and tax harmonization under imperfect competition: A cautionary example. European Economic Review, 46, 1559–1568.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  31. Keen, M., & Smith, S. (1996). The future of value added tax in the European Union. Economic Policy, 11(23), 373–420.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  32. Keen, M., & Smith, S. (2000). Viva VIVAT! International Tax and Public Finance, 7(6), 741–751.Google Scholar
  33. Keen, M. & Smith, S. (2007). VAT fraud and evasion: What do we know, and what can be done? IMF working paper 07/31.Google Scholar
  34. Keen, M., & Wildasin, D. (2004). Pareto-efficient international taxation. American Economic Review, 94(1), 259–275.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  35. Lockwood, B. (1993). Commodity tax competition under destination and origin principles. Journal of Public Economics, 52(2), 141–162.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  36. Manzi, N. (2012). Use tax collection on income tax returns in other states. Policy Brief, Minnesota Department of Representative, Research Department, April.Google Scholar
  37. Mazerov, M. (2013). States should extend sales taxes to digital goods and services. State Tax Notes, 67, 35–52.Google Scholar
  38. McLure, C. E. (2000). Implementing subnational value added taxes on internal trade: The compensating VAT (CVAT). International Tax and Public Finance, 7(6), 723–740.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  39. McLure, C. E. (2003). The value added tax on electronic commerce in the European Union. International Tax and Public Finance, 10, 753–762.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  40. Mintz, J. M. (1995). The business transfer tax as a consumption tax. Tax Notes International, 10(1), 75–86.Google Scholar
  41. Naritomi, J. (2014). Consumers as tax auditors. Working paper.Google Scholar
  42. OECD. (2014). Addressing the tax challenges of the digital economy. OECD/G20 Base Erosion and Profit Shifting Project, OECD Publishing.Google Scholar
  43. OECD. (2015). International VAT/GST guidelines. Paris: OECD Publishing.Google Scholar
  44. PriceWaterhouseCoopers. (2007). Retail sales tax compliance costs: A national estimate. Joint Cost of Collection Study, June 1.Google Scholar
  45. Slemrod, J. (1990). Optimal taxation and optimal tax systems. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 4, 157–178.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  46. Slemrod, J., & Wilson, J. D. (2009). Tax competition with parasitic tax havens. Journal of Public Economics, 93(11–12), 1261–1270.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  47. State of Washington. (2010). Department of revenue compliance study. Research report no. 2010–4, August 20.Google Scholar
  48. Tosun, M. S., & Skidmore, M. L. (2007). Cross-border shopping and the sales tax: An examination of food purchases in West Virginia. The B.E. Journal of Economic Analysis & Policy, 7(1), 1–18.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  49. Wildasin, D. E. (2001). Sales taxation in Kentucky: Problems and prospects. In: D. E. Wildasin, M. T. Childress, M. Hackbart, L. K. Lynch, & C. W. Martie (Eds.), Financing state and local government: Future challenges and opportunities (pp. 27–38). Kentucky Long Term Policy Research Center.Google Scholar
  50. Zodrow, G. R. (2006). Optimal commodity taxation of traditional and electronic commerce. National Tax Journal, 59, 7–31.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

Copyright information

© Springer Science+Business Media New York 2016

Authors and Affiliations

  1. 1.Department of Economics, Martin School of Public PolicyUniversity of KentuckyLexingtonUSA
  2. 2.CESifoMunichGermany
  3. 3.Boyd Center for Business and Economic ResearchUniversity of TennesseeKnoxvilleUSA

Personalised recommendations