Skip to main content
Log in

Public debt, bailouts, and common bonds

  • Published:
International Tax and Public Finance Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

We look at a model where countries of different sizes provide local public goods with positive spillovers. Matching grants can give rise to optimal expenditure levels, but countries can induce bailouts. We study the characteristics of these bailouts in a subgame-perfect Nash equilibrium and how these characteristics are affected by the introduction of common bonds. Partial substitution of common for sovereign bonds has two implications. First, it lowers the average and marginal borrowing costs of countries which may be eligible for bailouts. This effect leads to higher borrowing in these countries irrespective of their bailout expectations. Second, the lower borrowing costs mitigate the incentives of countries to induce a bailout and, therefore, constrain the parameter set for which a soft budget constraint equilibrium exists. As a result, the introduction of common bonds can also be in the interest of those countries that provide the bailouts.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Institutional subscriptions

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. The possible advantages, disadvantages, and institutional aspects of euro bonds are further discussed outside the context of a formal model by Issing (2009), De Grauwe and Moesen (2009), Favero and Missale (2010), Bishop et al. (2011), Eijffinger (2011), Hellwig and Philippon (2011), Boonstra and Bruinshoofd (2013), Claessens et al. (2012), and Gilbert et al. (2013).

  2. The positive relationship between public debt and interest rates is supported by early empirical research by Edwards (1984) and more recently by Chung and Turnovsky (2010).

  3. The cost of financing usually depends on the debt-to-GDP ratio. However, due to the exogenous per capita income y, \(b_i\) can be interpreted as a proxy for debt to GDP of country i, which is given by \(n_ib_i/n_iy=b_i/y \propto b_i\).

  4. A similar modeling of spillovers is done by Besley and Coate (2003). In contrast to their model, there is no heterogeneity among individuals within a country in our model, but heterogeneity across countries (i.e., differences in country size). Feidler and Staal (2012) demonstrate that these differences can be seen as a proxy for heterogeneity among individuals within a country.

  5. Note that this differs from the first-best outcome that would be determined when the values of all \(\delta _j\) are known. The derivation of this first-best outcome, however, does not only differ from the derivation in this subsection by taking the spillover effect into account, as it would also differ with respect to the information asymmetries in decentralized decision making studied in the next subsection. Since the system of matching grants and the bailouts are motivated by the spillover effect, we follow Wildasin (1997) and Crivelli and Staal (2013) and take as a benchmark the outcome that would be achieved if the spillover effect is taken into account. We thank two anonymous referees for pointing this out to us.

  6. The second derivative with respect to \(\underline{m_i}\) is always negative, and thus, the second-order condition is always satisfied.

  7. Since countries \(j\ne i\) are identical, \(b_j\) measures the per capita debt of all countries \(j\ne i\) and, therefore, determines the common interest rate.

  8. Under this condition, country i issues the maximum allowed amount of common bonds. In order to see this, note that for any substitution of national by common debt, without increasing the overall level of \(b_i\), less taxes are necessary to finance a given level of \(g_{i2}\) and private consumption \(c_{i2}\) goes up.

  9. Note that homogeneity of degree between 0 and 1 would violate the assumption that \(r^{\prime \prime }\) is positive. Furthermore, for \(\delta _i<\delta _j\), this condition is always satisfied, while for \(\delta _i>\delta _j\) recall from Sect. 3 that \(\delta _j=p^H\delta _\mathrm{high}+(1-p^H)\delta _\mathrm{low}\) with \(p^H\) close to 1, which implies that in the latter case, this lower bound for \(\bar{b}\) is close to 0.

  10. Equation (31) holds both in a soft and hard budget constraint cases, as the bailout decision remains given by (21), while \(\partial \underline{m_i}/\partial b_i\) becomes \(\partial \underline{m_i}/\partial b_i = \left( 1+r_i\left( b_i^*\right) \left( 1+\varepsilon _i^*(1 -\bar{b}/b_i^*)\right) \right) (1 +2\underline{m_i})/(1+2\underline{m_i}+2g_{i2})>0\).

  11. Use (16), (36a), (36b), (36c), and (36d).

  12. See, e.g., Claessens et al. (2012) for a survey of proposals.

References

  • Akai, N., & Silva, E. C. D. (2009). Interregional redistribution as a cure to the soft budget syndrome in federations. International Tax and Public Finance, 16(1), 43–58.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Beber, A., Brandt, M., & Kavajecz, K. (2009). Flight-to-quality or flight-to-liquidity? Evidence from the Euro-area bond market. Review of Financial Studies, 22(3), 925–957.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Beetsma, R., & Mavromatis, K. (2014). An analysis of eurobonds. Journal of International Money and Finance, 45, 91–111.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bernoth, K., von Hagen, J., & Schuknecht, L. (2012). Sovereign risk premiums in the European government bond market. Journal of International Money and Finance, 31, 975–995.

  • Besley, T., & Coate, S. (2003). Central versus local provision of public goods: A political economy analysis. Journal of Public Economics, 87(12), 2611–2637.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bishop, G., Boonstra, W., Bos, M., Gilbert, N., Kamalodin, S., Karsenti, R., et al. (2011). An EMU bond fund proposal. European League for Economic Cooperation.

  • Boonstra, W. W., & Bruinshoofd, W. A. (2013). Conditional euro t-bills as a transitional regime. In M. Balling, P. Egger, & E. Gnan (Eds.), States, banks and the financing of the economy: Fiscal policy and sovereign risk perspectives. Vienna: SUERF.

    Google Scholar 

  • Botta, A. (2011). Fiscal policy, eurobonds and economic recovery: Some heterodox policy recipes against financial instability and sovereign debt crisis. MPRA Paper 33860, University Library of Munich, Germany.

  • Chung, K., & Turnovsky, S. J. (2010). Foreign debt supply in an imperfect international capital market: Theory and evidence. Journal of International Money and Finance, 29(2), 201–223.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Claessens, S., Mody, A., & Vallée, S. (2012). Paths to eurobonds. IMF Working Paper 12/172.

  • Crivelli, E., & Staal, K. (2013). Size, spillovers and soft budget constraints. International Tax and Public Finance, 20(2), 338–356.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • De Grauwe, P., & Moesen, W. (2009). Gains for all: A proposal for a common euro bond. Leuven: University of Leuven.

    Google Scholar 

  • Delpla, J., & von Weizsäcker, J. (2010). The blue bond proposal. Bruegel Policy Briefs 420. Brussels: Bruegel.

  • Edwards, S. (1984). LDC foreign borrowing and default risk: An empirical investigation, 1976–80. American Economic Review, 74(4), 726–734.

    Google Scholar 

  • Eijffinger, S. (2011). Eurobonds—Concepts and implications. Briefing Note, European Parliament, Policy Department A: Economic and Scientific Policies.

  • European Commission. (2011). Green paper on the feasibility of introducing stability bonds. COM(2011) 818 final.

  • Favero, C., & Missale, A. (2010). EU public debt management and eurobonds. In European Parliament’s Committee on economic and monetary affairs, Brussels, European Parliament.

  • Favero, C., Pagano, M., & von Thadden, E. (2010). How does liquidity affect government bond yields? Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 45(1), 107–134.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Feidler, J., & Staal, K. (2012). Centralized and decentralized provision of public goods. Economics of Governance, 13(1), 73–93.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gilbert, N., Hessel, J., & Verkaart, S. (2013). Towards a stable monetary union: What role for eurobonds? Working Paper, No. 379. De Nederlandsche Bank.

  • Gomez-Puig, M. (2006). Size matters for liquidity: Evidence from EMU sovereign yield spreads. Economics Letters, 90, 156–162.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Goodspeed, T. (2002). Bailouts in a federation. International Tax and Public Finance, 9(4), 409–421.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hellwig, C., & Philippon, T. (2011). Eurobills, not eurobonds. Mimeo.

  • Herz, B., & Hohberger, S. (2013). Fiscal policy, monetary regimes and current account dynamics. Review of International Economics, 21(1), 118–136.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Inman, R. (2001). Transfers and bailouts: Institutions for enforcing local fiscal discipline. Constitutional Political Economy, 12, 141–160.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Issing, O. (2009). Why a common eurobond isn’t such a good idea. White Paper No. III. Center for Financial Studies, University of Frankfurt.

  • Köthenbürger, M. (2007). Ex-post redistribution in a federation: Implications for corrective policy. Journal of Public Economics, 91(3–4), 481–496.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rodden, J. (2003). Soft budget constraints and German federalism. In J. Rodden (Ed.), Fiscal decentralization and the challenge of hard budget constraints. Cambridge: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Seitz, H. (1999). Subnational government bailouts in Germany. ZEI Working Paper B20.

  • Stein, E. (1999). Fiscal decentralization and government size in Latin America. Journal of Applied Economics, 2(2), 357–391.

    Google Scholar 

  • Von Hagen, J., Bordignon, M., Dahlberg, M., Grewal, B., Petterson, P., & Seitz, H. (2000). Subnational government bailouts in OECD countries: Four case studies. Research Network Working Paper R-399. Inter-American Development Bank.

  • Wildasin, D. E. (1997). Externalities and bailouts: Hard and soft budget constraints in intergovernmental fiscal relations. Nashville: Vanderbilt University.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

We are grateful to two anonymous referees for comments and suggestions that have improved the paper substantially. We would also like to thank Ernesto Crivelli, Anya Kalayda, Emilson Silva, Jacob Veenstra, and participants of the IIPF Conference (Dublin), the EPCS Meeting (Groningen) and a seminar at the University of Bonn.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Klaas Staal.

Appendix

Appendix

Proof of Lemma 2

The proof consists of two parts. First, we show that the utility difference can be both positive and negative. Since \(g_{j\tau }^*=\hat{g}_{j\tau }\), no difference in utility can come through the externalities of foreign public good provision. Second, (25) and (26) show that \(g_{i1}^*=\hat{g}_{i1}\) and \(g_{i2}^*<\hat{g}_{i2}\). Therefore, utility from public good provision is lower in a soft budget constraint equilibrium than in the optimal outcome. Third, \(g_{i1}^*=\hat{g}_{i1}\) and \(b_i^*>\hat{b}_i\) from (27) imply \(t_{i1}^*<\hat{t}_{i1}\) and \(c_{i1}^*>\hat{c}_{i1}\). Thus, higher borrowing increases utility from private consumption in period 1. As a result, \(U_i^*>\hat{U}_i\) if \(t_{i2}^*\) is sufficiently smaller or not too much larger than \(\hat{t}_{i2}\), which would augment second-period consumption \(c_{i2}^*\) relative to \(\hat{c}_{i2}\). However, \(t_{i2}^*\gtreqless \hat{t}_{i2}\) depends on the reaction of public debt to the bailout. If public debt increases only marginally relative to its optimal level, then \(t_{i2}^*<\hat{t}_{i2}\) and the possibility exists that country i chooses to induce a bailout. The stronger \(b_i\) reacts to the bailout, the larger \(t_{i2}^*\) is, and the lower the utility difference \(U_i^*-\hat{U}_i\). In the extreme, a large difference \(b_i^*-\hat{b}_i\) leads to a sufficiently large difference \(t_{i2}^*-\hat{t}_{i2}>0\) and \(U_i^*<\hat{U}_i\). However, whether \(t_{i2}^*-\hat{t}_{i2}>0\) actually leads to \(U_i^*<\hat{U}_i\) depends also on the time preference parameter. We show this explicitly by plugging the first-order conditions (13), (14), (25), (26), and (27) in (23.1) and showing that \(U_i^*<\hat{U}_i\) holds if and only if the following condition is satisfied:

$$\begin{aligned} \begin{aligned} \delta _i > \frac{b_i^*-\hat{b}_i}{(1+r_i(b_i^*))b_i^*-(1+r_i(\hat{b}_i))\hat{b}_i+g_{i2}^*-\underline{m_i}-\hat{g}_{i2}- \ln ( {g_{i2}^*})+({\hat{g}_{i2}})}. \end{aligned} \end{aligned}$$
(33)

Therefore, the government in country i may decide not to induce a bailout when it is has a high time preference parameter \(\delta _i\).

Subsequently, we differentiate the utility difference with respect to \(n_i\). Using the Envelope Theorem, any effect of \(n_i\) on the equilibrium \(\hat{t}_{i\tau }, \hat{b}_i, t_{i\tau }^*, b_i^*\) has zero effect on \(\hat{U}_i\) and \(U_i^*\), respectively. Moreover, the effects through \(\hat{t}_{j\tau }, \hat{b}_j,t_{j\tau }^*\), and \(b_j^*\) cancel out, which leaves

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\mathrm{d}}{\mathrm{d}n_i}\left[ U_i^*-\hat{U}_i\right] =\frac{\delta _i}{g_{i2}^*}\frac{\mathrm{d} \underline{m_i}}{d n_i}<0. \end{aligned}$$
(34)

Therefore, there are three cases. Either (23) is always negative, which means \(\overline{n_L}=0\), or it is always positive and thus \(\overline{n_L}=N/2\), or it changes sign as \(n_i\) increases. The last case means that by the intermediate value theorem, there exists \(\overline{n_L}\in [0,N/2]\), such that (23) holds if and only if \(n_i<\overline{n_L}\). \(\square \)

Proof of Proposition 1

To show that \(\mathcal{{S}}\) can constitute a subgame-perfect Nash equilibrium, we have to show that no actor has an incentive to change its strategy. We use backward induction.

First, consider (\(\mathcal{{S}}4\)). Note that when the governments of countries j are asked to provide a bailout, these governments conclude that \(\delta _i=\delta _\mathrm{low}\), as otherwise the government of country i would not make this request. This thus automatically takes away the information asymmetry that existed in period 1. Due to the subgame perfectness, the governments of countries j cannot stick to a non-bailout policy, even though from a welfare perspective, they may prefer to do so. Given this restriction, (21) describes their bailout decision.

Then, consider (\(\mathcal{{S}}3\)). When countries j give a bailout as (21) describes, then the previous section shows that (13) and (14) describe the utility maximizing choices, these choices are also maximizing the utility of the citizens in countries j if country i does not induce a bailout.

Considering (\(\mathcal{{S}}2\)), note that when \(\delta _\mathrm{high}\) is large enough, i.e., close to one, it follows from (14) that the government of country i does not borrow money and that it has no incentive to consume more in period 1 at the cost of lower public good provision in country i in period 2. It will thus not induce a bailout in period 2. On the other hand, when \(\delta _i=\delta _\mathrm{low}\) is small enough, i.e., close to zero, it gets more attractive for individuals in country i to consume more in period 1 at the expense of consumption and public good provision in period 2, and choose a \(b_i\) big enough to change all period 2 income into period 1 consumption. In addition, for a lower \(\delta \), the period 2 costs associated with a bailout for the individuals in country i matter less when they take their decision in period 1 on a debt level that implies inducing a bailout in period 2.

Finally, consider (\(\mathcal{{S}}1\)). Changing the system of matching grants in a way to avoid bailouts leads to public good levels that are too high when country i does not induce a bailout, that is, when \(\delta _i=\delta _\mathrm{high}\). Since \(\delta _i\) is not known when the system of matching grants is designed, the only way to give the government of country i an incentive to increase its public good provision is by increasing the size of the matching grant. Let \(g_i^a\) denote the amount of public goods in country i when the system of matching grants is adjusted in such a way that the government of country i will never induce a bailout, and let \(T^a\) denote the additional tax that has to be raised to finance the adjustment in the system of matching grants. The benefits of doing so are the additional spillovers that can be expected when a bailout is avoided minus the loss due to suboptimal decision making when, even without adjustments, no bailout would have been induced: \(p^L\left[ \ln (g_i^a)-\ln (g_i^*) -T^a\right] +(1-p^L)\left[ \ln (g_i^a)-\ln (\hat{g}_i)-T^a\right] \). While the first term might be positive, the second term is surely negative, so for \(p^L\) small enough, there is no incentive to change the system of matching grants. \(\square \)

Proof of Proposition 2

The first result exists both in the case of hard and soft budget constraints. Totally differentiating equation (31) with respect to \(b_i\) and \(\bar{b}\), we get

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\mathrm{d}b_i}{\mathrm{d}\bar{b}} = \frac{r_{i}^{\prime }(b_i)}{2r_{i}^{\prime }(b_i)+b_ir_{i}^{\prime \prime }(b_i)-\overline{b}r_{i}^{\prime \prime }(b_i)}. \end{aligned}$$
(35)

Moreover, taking into consideration that \(r^{\prime }(b_i)\) is homogenous of degree \(h-1\) and, therefore, \(r^{\prime \prime }(b_i)b_i=(h-1)r^{\prime }(b_i)\), we get

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\mathrm{d} b_i^*}{\mathrm{d}\bar{b}}= & {} \frac{1}{2+(h-1)\left( 1-\bar{b}/b_i^*\right) }>0,\\ \frac{\mathrm{d} \hat{b}_i}{\mathrm{d}\bar{b}}= & {} \frac{1}{2+(h-1)\left( 1-\bar{b}/\hat{b}_i\right) }>0. \end{aligned}$$

The second result follows directly from Eq. (28), which determines the size of the bailout and is independent of \(\bar{b}\).

The third result is related to the previous one. Since both the bailout and \(g_{i2}^*\) are determined only by \(\kappa , n_i\) and N, common bonds and the borrowing of country i do not influence the incentive of the remaining countries to increase the bailout above zero.

The fourth result states that the critical value \(\overline{n_L}\) goes down. It is the case if the introduction of common bonds lowers the value of \(U_i^*-\hat{U}_i\) for any \(n_i\). In this case, either \(\overline{n_L}\) declines (if an interior value for it exists), or it remains at 0 or N / 2. Therefore, showing that

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\mathrm{d}}{\mathrm{d}\bar{b}}(U_i^*-\hat{U}_i)<0 \end{aligned}$$

suffices to prove this result. We can show that it always holds. First, due to the independence of \(g_{i\tau }^*,\hat{g}_{i\tau }, g_{j\tau }^*\), and \(\hat{g}_{j\tau }\) of common bonds, the utility difference is not affected by \(\bar{b}\) through public good consumption. Nevertheless, since common bonds lead to an increase in borrowing in each equilibrium, taxes decline in period 1 and may rise in period 2. Using Eqs. (13), (14), (16), (25), (26), and (35), we can show that

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\mathrm{d} t_{i1}^*}{\mathrm{d}\bar{b}}&=-\frac{(1-\kappa )n_i}{n_i+\kappa (N-n_i)}\frac{\mathrm{d}b_i^*}{\mathrm{d}\bar{b}}<0, \end{aligned}$$
(36a)
$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\mathrm{d} \hat{t}_{i1}}{\mathrm{d}\bar{b}}&=-\frac{(1-\kappa )n_i}{n_i+\kappa (N-n_i)}\frac{\mathrm{d}\hat{b}_i}{\mathrm{d}\bar{b}}<0, \end{aligned}$$
(36b)
$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\mathrm{d}t_{i2}^*}{\mathrm{d}\bar{b}}&=\frac{(1-\kappa )n_i}{n_i+\kappa (N-n_i)}\left[ r_j(b_j^*)-r_i(b_i^*)\right. \nonumber \\&\quad \left. + \left( 1+r_i(b_i^*)\left( 1+\varepsilon _i^*\left( 1-\frac{\bar{b}}{b_i^*}\right) \right) \right) \frac{\mathrm{d}b_i^*}{\mathrm{d}\bar{b}}\right] \gtreqless 0, \end{aligned}$$
(36c)
$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\mathrm{d} \hat{t}_{i2}}{\mathrm{d}\bar{b}}&=\frac{(1-\kappa )n_i}{n_i+\kappa (N-n_i)}\left[ r_j(\hat{b}_j)-r_i(\hat{b}_i) \right. \nonumber \\&\quad \left. + \left( 1+r_i(\hat{b}_i)\left( 1+\hat{\varepsilon }_i\left( 1-\frac{\bar{b}}{\hat{b}_i}\right) \right) \right) \frac{\mathrm{d}\hat{b}_i}{\mathrm{d}\bar{b}}\right] \gtreqless 0. \end{aligned}$$
(36d)

Using the above equations, we can derive

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\mathrm{d}}{\mathrm{d}\bar{b}}(U_i^*-\hat{U}_i)= & {} -\frac{1}{1-\kappa }\left[ \frac{\mathrm{d} t_{i1}^*}{\mathrm{d}\bar{b}}-\frac{\mathrm{d} \hat{t}_{i1}}{\mathrm{d}\bar{b}}+\delta _i\left( \frac{\mathrm{d} t_{i2}^*}{\mathrm{d}\bar{b}}-\frac{\mathrm{d} \hat{t}_{i2}}{\mathrm{d}\bar{b}}\right) \right] \\= & {} \frac{-\delta _i n_i}{n_i+\kappa (N-n_i)}\left[ \rho +r(\hat{b}_i)-r(b_i^*)\right] \end{aligned}$$

Taking into consideration the first-order conditions of governments, given by Eqs. (14) and (31), we can present the above utility difference change as

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\mathrm{d}}{\mathrm{d}\bar{b}}(U_i^*-\hat{U}_i)=\frac{-\delta _i n_i h}{n_i+\kappa (N-n_i)}\left[ (r(b_i^*)-r(\hat{b}_i))+\left( \frac{r(\hat{b}_i)\bar{b}}{\hat{b}_i}-\frac{r(b_i^*)\bar{b}}{b_i^*}\right) \right] \le 0. \end{aligned}$$
(37)

The first term in the square brackets is positive \((r(b_i^*)-r(\hat{b}_i))>0\), while the last term is negative and increasing in the amount of common bonds. The whole term in the square brackets is multiplied by a negative number, and we can conclude that the change in the utility difference attains its largest value when \(\bar{b}\) approaches its upper limit \(b_i\). In this case, full substitution of sovereign for common debt is achieved, and both \(b_i^*\) and \(\hat{b}_i\) equal \(\bar{b}\). In this case, we can show that

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\mathrm{d}}{\mathrm{d}\bar{b}}(U_i^*-\hat{U}_i)\Bigg |_{{\text {full substitution}}} =0. \end{aligned}$$
(38)

Therefore, the marginal effect of common bonds on the incentives to induce a bailout is always negative, except for full substitution of national for common bonds. Thus, the impact of a discrete introduction of common bonds from \(\bar{b}=0\) to \(\bar{b}>0\) is also negative. Note that common bonds have a larger positive effect on second-period taxes in an equilibrium with a bailout than in one without. Therefore, the possible negative tax differential \(t_{i2}^*-\hat{t}_{i2}\), which is responsible for the inducement of a bailout, declines in absolute value. Lastly, \(\mathrm{d}(U_i^*-\hat{U}_i)/\mathrm{d}\bar{b}\) is most negative when \(\bar{b}=0\), because the positive effect vanishes. Therefore, the marginal effect on \(\overline{n_L}\) is strongest at the lowest possible common bond ceiling. It vanishes at full substitution of national for common bonds. \(\square \)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Kalamov, Z., Staal, K. Public debt, bailouts, and common bonds. Int Tax Public Finance 23, 670–692 (2016). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10797-016-9395-2

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10797-016-9395-2

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation