Advertisement

International Tax and Public Finance

, Volume 22, Issue 1, pp 102–119 | Cite as

Optimal tax on capital inflows discriminated by debt-risk profile

  • Julian A. Parra-Polania
  • Carmiña O. VargasEmail author
Article

Abstract

In this study, the optimal value of a tax on capital inflows is estimated so that private agents internalize the social costs of their borrowing decisions in an economy with financial constraints. A key feature of our model is that we provide a theoretical foundation to tax level differentiation by asset volatility. Using Colombian data for the 1996–2011 period (which includes the crisis of 1998–1999), we find the tax would be around 1.2 %.

Keywords

Optimal tax Capital flows Externalities Financial constraint 

JEL Classification

H23 D62 F34 

Notes

Acknowledgments

The authors wish to thank the editor, Eckhard Janeba, and two anonymous referees for helpful comments. We also thank J. Bejarano, J. E. Gomez, J. Ojeda, H. Rincon, H. Vargas and A. Velasco for their valuable suggestions; A. Korinek for clarifications on the empirical analysis of his document (Korinek 2010). The opinions expressed herein are solely the responsibility of the authors and do not necessarily reflect those of the Central Bank of Colombia or its Board of Directors.

References

  1. Aghion, P., Bacchetta, P., & Banerjee, A. (2004). Financial development and the instability of open economies. Journal of Monetary Economics, 51, 1077–1106.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  2. Bernanke, B., & Gertler, M. (1989). Agency costs, net worth and business fluctuations. American Economic Review, 79, 14–31.Google Scholar
  3. Bianchi, J. (2011). Overborrowing and systemic externalities in the business cycle. American Economic Review, 101(7), 3400–3426.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  4. Bianchi, J., & Mendoza, E. (2011). Overborrowing, financial crises and ‘macro-prudential’ policy. Working Paper No. 11–24, International Monetary Fund.Google Scholar
  5. Caballero, R. J., & Krishnamurthy, A. (2001). International and domestic collateral constraints in a model of emerging market crises. Journal of Monetary Economics, 48(3), 513–548.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  6. Caballero, R. J., & Krishnamurthy, A. (2003). Excessive dollar debt: Financial development and underinsurance. Journal of Finance, 58(2), 867–894.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  7. Caballero, R. J., & Krishnamurthy, A. (2004). Smoothing sudden stops. Journal of Economic Theory, 119(1), 104–127.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  8. Chetty, R. (2009). Sufficient statistics for welfare analysis: A bridge between structural and reduced-form methods. Annual Review of Economics, 1(1), 451–487.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  9. Geanakoplos, J., & Polemarchakis, H. (1986). Existence, regularity, and constrained suboptimality of competitive allocations when markets are incomplete. In W. P. Heller, R. M. Ross, & D. A. Starrett (Eds.), Uncertainty, information and communication: Essays in honor of Kenneth Arrow. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
  10. Gómez J., & Kiefer, N. (2006). Bank failure: Evidence from the Colombian financial crisis. Working Paper No. 06–12, Cornell University.Google Scholar
  11. Greenwald, B. C., & Stiglitz, J. E. (1986). Externalities in economies with imperfect information and incomplete markets. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 101(2), 229–264.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  12. Jeanne, O., & Korinek, A. (2010a). Excessive volatility in capital flows: A Pigouvian taxation approach. American Economic Review: Papers and Proceedings, 100(2), 403–407.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  13. Jeanne, O., & Korinek, A. (2010b). Managing credit booms and busts: A Pigouvian taxation approach. NBER Working Paper No. 16377.Google Scholar
  14. Kiyotaki, N., & Moore, J. (1997). Credit cycles. Journal of Political Economy, 105, 211–248.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  15. Korinek, A. (2010). Regulating capital flows to emerging markets: An externality view. Mimeo, University of Maryland.Google Scholar
  16. Korinek, A. (2011a). The new economics of prudential capital controls: A research agenda. IMF Economic Review, 59(3), 523–561.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  17. Korinek, A. (2011b). Hot money and serial financial crises. IMF Economic Review, 59(59), 306–339.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  18. Krugman, P. (1979). A model of balance-of-payment crises. Journal of Money Credit and Banking, 11(3), 311–325.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  19. Mendoza, E. (2002). Credit, prices, and crashes: Business cycles with a sudden stop. In S. Edwards & J. A. Frankel (Eds.), Preventing currency crises in emerging markets. Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press and National Bureau of Economic Research.Google Scholar
  20. Mendoza, E. (2005). Real exchange rate volatility and the price of nontradable goods in economies prone to sudden stops. Economia, 6(1), 103–105.Google Scholar
  21. Mendoza, E. (2010). Sudden stops, financial crises, and leverage. American Economic Review, 100, 1941–1966.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  22. Obstfeld, M. (1994). The logic of currency crises. Cahiers Economiques et Monetaries, 43, 189–213.Google Scholar
  23. Prada, J., & Rojas, L. (2010). La Elasticidad de Frisch y la Transmisión de la Política Monetaria en Colombia. In M. Jalil & L. Mahadeva (Eds.), Mecanismos de transmisión de la Política Monetaria en Colombia, chapter 13. Bogotá: Banco de la República and Universidad Externado de Colombia.Google Scholar
  24. Reinhart, C., Rogoff, K., & Savastano, M. (2003). Debt intolerance. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, Economic Studies Program, 34(1), 1–74.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  25. Stein, J. (2012). Monetary policy as financial stability regulation. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 127, 57–95.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  26. Villar, L., Salamanca, D., & Murcia, A. (2005). Crédito, represión financiera y flujos de capitales en Colombia 1974–2003. Desarrollo y Sociedad, 55, 167–209.Google Scholar

Copyright information

© Springer Science+Business Media New York 2014

Authors and Affiliations

  1. 1.Banco de la República (Colombian Central Bank)BogotáColombia

Personalised recommendations