Wellbeing and Happiness

This is a preview of subscription content, log in to check access.

Notes

  1. 1.

    Amartya Sen (1999), as noted at the outset, expresses suspicion over the use of the “happiness” measure: if there is no improvement in wellbeing, but people are happier, the happiness measure is misleading. Or put differently, if improvements in the material conditions of the poor in developing countries do not lead to the advancement of their happiness, we then should not use happiness as a measure. However, Sen misunderstands the Wellbeing-Happiness Paradox and its policy implications (see van der Rijt 2013). The finding about the disconnect between wellbeing and happiness is only with respect to the time-series data of individuals in developed countries.

  2. 2.

    While people choose their group, and such a group is a stratum of the wider society, this does not deny that people, at least occasionally, compare their stratum to other strata in the wider society. In this regard, the proposed analytic does not change. If we think of the different strata in the wider society as individuals, and hence, then the comparison would simply be broadened. The same dynamics of aspiration applies, irrespective of the boundary of the comparison group.

  3. 3.

    Other explanations of the paradox are abounding. Di Tella and MacCulloch (2008) propose that the paradox is the outcome of omitted variables. It is true that happiness is stationary as income rises, but this is the case because of omitted variables. While happiness rises with income, it is declining as a result of rising environmental degradation, rising hours of work, and increasing decline of the quality of life. Another explanation is the power of habit: As people become richer, they become used to their new level of being. So, people use the recent past income as the benchmark for assessing the their happiness (see Frederick and Loewenstein 1999).

  4. 4.

    Promoters of set point theory suppose that the set point is mainly given by two factors: i) genetic inheritance; and ii) traits that have developed in early life. Thus individuals cannot choose their own happiness set point (Gullone and Cummins 2002; Cummins et al. 2008; Frey and Stutzer 2002a; Layard 2006; Gilbert 2006; Nettle 2005).

  5. 5.

    The psychological literature usually treats amiability or friendship as an output rather than as an input, equating amiability with wellbeing (Powdthavee 2011; Argyle 2001; Baumeister and Leary 1995; Berscheid and Reis 1998; Demir 2010). But other literatures do not equate amiability or friendship with wellbeing—and in fact find no correlation between the two (Lucas et al. 2008), though this is disputed (e.g., Saphire-Bernstein and Taylor in David et al. 2014; Demir in David et al. 2014). The issue of friendship and amiability is actually complicated and it is outside the focus of this paper.

  6. 6.

    For instance, Bruni and Porta (2005; 2007; 2016) define the economics of happiness as generally about the quality of life in terms of virtues, pro-social preferences, and preferences in advanced economies. Similarly, Frey (2008; Frey and Stutzer 2002a; 2013) enumerates a multitude of ordinary inputs, from a quality environment to close relationships, that shape one’s happiness (see also Powdthavee 2011; Baumeister and Leary 1995; Anand 2016). Likewise, the contributors to Alan Krueger et al. (2009) and McDaid and Cooper (2014) stress the importance of family life and quality of life. Even some psychologists subscribe to the economist’s identification of happiness with expansionist and comprehensive utility that amasses net experiences of “pleasantness” (e.g., Parducci 1995).

  7. 7.

    Note, in an earlier work, I conflated “transcendental utility” with ego-based utility, which I called “symbolic utility” (Khalil 2004).

  8. 8.

    The proposed link or dependency of context and content has an immediate and simultaneous implication for two major ethical theories. First, one cannot reduce the context to an element of the corporal inputs category à la utilitarian argument. Second, one cannot elevate the context to an abstract rule that stands independently of the content à la Kantian categorical imperative (e.g. Korsgaard 2009; Sen 1987; cf. Khalil 1999).

  9. 9.

    While the term “projected” corresponds to the term “expected” in the economics literature, I prefer using the term “projected” as the term “expected” has a different connotation in other literature. For instance, Helliwell et al. (2016) report that Denmark ranks as the happiest country in the world—even happier than the equally prosperous Nordic countries. (This finding is questionable (see Tov and Au in David et al. 2014), however the point holds even if the example does not.) Christensen et al. (2006) and Booth (2014) maintain that the Danes are happier because they set their “expectations” low, and so are pleased with their realized wellbeing. Here, the term “expectations” is equivalent to the proposed “imagined wellbeing”—i.e., it does not correspond to how the economics literature uses the term.

  10. 10.

    Cantril (1965), a social psychologist who pioneered public opinion research, designed surveys that can be considered the early catalyst behind the scientific study of happiness. The surveys collect self-reports on wellbeing (Alexandrova 2008). Such reports, as Kahneman and Krueger (2006) show, have become reliable because they are highly correlated with reports of friends, health-records, sleep quality, and so on. They are also highly correlated with objective measures such as smiling (Duchenne smile), laughing, heart rate, electrical activity of the brain, and other biological indicators (Diener 2009).

  11. 11.

    To add to the confusion, some researchers treat positive effect (PA) and negative effect (NA) as conceptually symmetrical to the cognitive component. Hence, they advocate a “tripartite theory” consisting of PA, NA, and the cognitive component (e.g., Arthaud-Day et al. 2005). Further adding confusion, Diener and Biswas-Diener (2002) and Miao et al. (in David et al. 2014) advocate a “four-component” theory which breaks the cognitive component into global satisfaction about life as opposed to domain satisfaction about marriage, work, and so on. While these classifications are not theoretically grounded, their value resides in providing practical measurement benefits such as finding the correlation between happiness, on one hand, and differences in gender, age, personality traits, racial minorities, religiosity, marital status, culture, and so on, on the other.

  12. 12.

    As a result of weakness of will (Khalil 2015, 2017a), a person may not actually command the optimized definite wellbeing course of action, but this issue falls outside the scope of this paper.

  13. 13.

    Many corporal products, e.g., health, laughter, or music enjoyment, cannot be commanded. Elster (1998, p. 320) therefore argues that such pleasures pose a “by-product problem.” Elster (2009) also regards the emotions in general as posing a by-product problem. Even if he is correct, this does not mean that happiness is similar to by-product emotions  in the way Elster uses the term “by-product.”

References

  1. Aaker, J., M. Rudd, and C. Mogilner. 2011. If money doesn’t make you happy, consider time. Journal of Consumer Psychology 21: 126–133.

    Google Scholar 

  2. Anand, P. 2016. Happiness explained. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  3. Argyle, M. 2001. The psychology of happiness, 2nd ed. New York: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  4. Alexandrova, A. 2005. Subjective well-being and Kahneman’s ‘objective happiness’. Journal of Happiness Studies 6: 301–324.

    Google Scholar 

  5. Alexandrova, A. 2008. First-person reports and the measurement of happiness. Philosophical Psychology 21: 571–583.

    Google Scholar 

  6. Alexandrova, A. 2017. A philosophy for the science of well-being. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  7. Andrews, F.M., and S.B. Withey. 1976. Social indicators of well-being: America’s perception of life quality. New York: Plenum Press.

    Google Scholar 

  8. Arthaud-Day, M.L., J.C. Rode, C.H. Mooney, and J.P. Near. 2005. The subjective well-being construct: A test of its convergent, discriminant, and factorial validity. Social Indicators Research 74: 445–476.

    Google Scholar 

  9. Baumeister, R.F., and M.R. Leary. 1995. The need to belong: Desire for interpersonal attachments as a fundamental human motivation. Psychological Bulletin 117: 497–529.

    Google Scholar 

  10. Becker, G.S. 1993. Nobel lecture: The economic way of looking at behavior. Journal of Political Economy 101: 385–409.

    Google Scholar 

  11. Belk, R.W. 1988. Possessions and the Extended Self. Journal of Consumer Research 15: 139–168.

    Google Scholar 

  12. Berscheid, E., and H.T. Reis. 1998. Attraction and close relationships. In The handbook of social psychology, 4th, ed. D.T. Gilbert, S.T. Fiske, and G. Lindzey, 13–281. New York: McGraw-Hill.

    Google Scholar 

  13. Blanchflower, D.G., and A.J. Oswald. 2004. Well-being over time in Britain and the USA. Journal of Public Economics 88: 1359–1386.

    Google Scholar 

  14. Booth, M. 2014. The almost nearly perfect people: Behind the myth of the Scandinavian utopia. London: Vintage Books.

    Google Scholar 

  15. Bradburn, N.M. 1969. The structure of psychological well-being. Chicago: Aldine.

    Google Scholar 

  16. Brickman, P., D. Coates, and R. Janoff-Bulman. 1978. Lottery winners and accident victims: Is happiness relative? Journal of Personality and Social Psychology 36: 917–927.

    Google Scholar 

  17. Brickman, P., and D.T. Campbell. 1971. Hedonic relativism and planning the good society. In Adaptation-level theory: A symposium, ed. M.H. Appley, 287–302. Academic Press.

  18. Bruni, L., and P.L. Porta (eds.). 2005. Economics and happiness: Framing the analysis. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  19. Bruni, L., and P.L. Porta (eds.). 2007. Handbook on the economics of happiness. Cheltenhamc: Edward Elgar.

    Google Scholar 

  20. Bruni, L., and P.L. Porta (eds.). 2016. Handbook of research methods and applications in happiness and quality of life. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.

    Google Scholar 

  21. Campbell, A., P.E. Converse, and W.L. Rodgers. 1976. The quality of American life. New York: Russell Sage Foundation.

    Google Scholar 

  22. Cantril, H. 1965. The pattern of human concerns. New Brunswick: Rutgers University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  23. Carter, T.J., and T. Gilovich. 2014. Getting the Most for the Money: The Hedonic Return on Experiential and Material Purchases. In Consumption and Well-Being in the Material World, ed. M. Tatzel, 49–62. Netherlands: Springer.

    Google Scholar 

  24. Chekola, M. 2007. Happiness, rationality, autonomy and the good life. Journal of Happiness Studies 8: 51–78.

    Google Scholar 

  25. Chodoff, P. 2002. The medicalization of the human condition. Psychiatric Services 53: 627–628.

    Google Scholar 

  26. Clark, A.E., P. Frijters, and M.A. Shields. 2008. Relative income, happiness, and utility: An explanation for the Easterlin paradox and other puzzles. Journal of Economic Literature 49: 95–144.

    Google Scholar 

  27. Clark, A.E., Y. Georgellis, and P. Sanfey. 2001. Scarring: The psychological impact of past unemployment. Economica 68: 221–421.

    Google Scholar 

  28. Christensen, K., A.M. Herskind, and J.W. Vaupel. 2006. Why Danes are smug: Comparative study of life satisfaction in the European Union. British Medical Journal 333 (7582): 1289–1291.

    Google Scholar 

  29. Costa Jr., P.T., and R.R. McCrae. 1980. Influence of extraversion and neuroticism on subjective well-being: Happy and unhappy people. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology 38: 668–678.

    Google Scholar 

  30. Cummins, R.A., D. Mellor, M.A. Stokes, and A.A.L.D. Lau. 2008. Quality of life down-under: The Australian unity wellbeing index. New York: Springer.

    Google Scholar 

  31. Damiano, E., H. Li, and W. Suen. 2010. First in village or second in Rome?”. International Economic Review 51: 263–288.

    Google Scholar 

  32. David, S.A., I. Boniwell, and A. Conley Ayers (eds.). 2014. The Oxford handbook of happiness. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  33. Deaton, A. 2008. Income, health, and well-being around the world: Evidence from the Gallup world poll. Journal of Economic Perspectives 22: 53–72.

    Google Scholar 

  34. Deaton, A. 2016. Measuring and understanding behavior, welfare, and poverty. (Nobel Lecture). American Economic Review 106: 1221–1243.

    Google Scholar 

  35. Demir, M. 2010. Close relationships and happiness among emerging adults. Journal of Happiness Studies 11: 293–313.

    Google Scholar 

  36. Diener, E. 1984. Subjective well-being. Psychological Bulletin 95: 542–575.

    Google Scholar 

  37. Diener, E., and F. Fujita. 1997. Social comparison and subjective well-being. In Health, Coping and Well-being: Perspectives from Social Comparison Theory, ed. B.P. Buunk and R. Gibbons, 329–357. Mahwah: Lawrence Erlbaum Associates.

    Google Scholar 

  38. Diener, E. (2009) Assessing well-being: The collected works of Ed Diener. New York: Springer.

  39. Diener, E., and R. Biswas-Diener. 2002. Will money increase subjective well-being? A literature review and guide to needed research. Social Indicators Research 57: 119–169.

    Google Scholar 

  40. Diener, E., and R.A. Emmons. 1984. The independence of positive and negative affect. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology 47: 1105–1117.

    Google Scholar 

  41. Diener, E., J. Horwitz, and R.A. Emmons. 1985. Happiness of the very wealthy. Social Indicators Research 16: 263–274.

    Google Scholar 

  42. Diener, E., W. Ng, J. Harter, and R. Arora. 2010. Wealth and happiness across the world: Material prosperity predicts life evaluation, while psychosocial prosperity predicts positive feeling. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology 97: 143–156.

    Google Scholar 

  43. Diener, E., and S. Oishi. 2000. Money and happiness: Income and subjective well-being across nations. In Culture and subjective well-being, ed. E. Diener and E.M. Suh, 185–218. Cambridge: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  44. Diener, E., E. Sandvik, L. Seidlitz, and M. Diener. 1993. The relationship between income and subjective well-being: Relative or absolute? Social Indicators Research 28: 195–223.

    Google Scholar 

  45. Diener, E., E. Suh, R. Lucas, and H. Smith. 1999. Subjective well-being: Three decades of progress. Psychological Bulletin 125: 276–302.

    Google Scholar 

  46. Di Tella, R., and R. MacCulloch. 2008. Gross national happiness as an answer to the Easterlin Paradox? Journal of Development Economics 86: 22–42.

    Google Scholar 

  47. Di Tella, R., J. Haisken-De New, and R. MacCulloch. 2010. Happiness adaptation to income and to status in an individual panel. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization 76: 834–852.

    Google Scholar 

  48. Dolan, P., T. Peasgood, and M. White. 2008. Do we really know what makes us happy? A review of the economic literature on the factors associated with subjective well-being. Journal of Economic Psychology 29: 94–122.

    Google Scholar 

  49. Dworkin, R.W. 2007. Artificial Happiness: The dark side of the new happy class. New York: Basic Books.

    Google Scholar 

  50. Easterlin, R.A. 1974. Does economic growth improve the human lot? In Nations and households in economic growth: Essays in honour of Moses Abramovitz, ed. P.A. David and M.W. Reder. New York: Academic Press.

    Google Scholar 

  51. Easterlin, R.A. 1995. Will raising the incomes of all increase the happiness of all? Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization 27: 35–47.

    Google Scholar 

  52. Easterlin, R.A. 2001. Income and happiness: Towards a unified theory. Economic Journal 111: 465–484.

    Google Scholar 

  53. Easterlin, R.A. 2003. Explaining happiness. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences (USA) 100: 11176–11183.

    Google Scholar 

  54. Easterlin, R.A. 2010. In Happiness, growth, and the life cycle, ed. H. Hinte and K.F. Zimmermann. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  55. Easterlin, R.A. 2013. Happiness, growth, and public policy. Economic Inquiry 51: 1–15.

    Google Scholar 

  56. Easterlin, R.A., L.A. McVey, M. Switek, O. Sawangfa, and J.S. Zweig. 2010. The happiness–income paradox revisited. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences (USA) 107: 22463–22468.

    Google Scholar 

  57. Elster, J. 1998. Alchemies of the mind: Rationality and the emotions. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  58. Elster, J. 2009. Emotional choice and rational choice. In The Oxford handbook of philosophy of emotion, ed. Peter Goldie, 263–281. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  59. Falk, A., and M. Knell. 2004. Choosing the Joneses: Endogenous goals and reference standards. Scandinavian Journal of Economics 106: 417–435.

    Google Scholar 

  60. Flower, R. 2004. Lifestyle drugs: Pharmacology and the social agenda. Trends in Pharmacological Sciences 25: 182–185.

    Google Scholar 

  61. Frank, R.H. 1985. Choosing the right pond: Human behavior and the quest for status. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  62. Frank, R.H. 2004. How not to buy happiness. Daedalus 133: 69–79.

    Google Scholar 

  63. Frederick, S., and G. Loewenstein. 1999. Hedonic adaptation. In Well-being: The foundations of hedonic psychology, ed. D. Kahneman, E. Diener, and N. Schwarz. New York: Russell Sage Foundation.

    Google Scholar 

  64. Frey, B.S. 2008. Happiness: A revolution in economics. Cambridge: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  65. Frey, B.S., and A. Stutzer. 2002a. What can economists learn from happiness research? Journal of Economic Literature 40: 402–435.

    Google Scholar 

  66. Frey, B.S., and A. Stutzer. 2002b. Happiness and economics: How the economy and institutions affect human well-being. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  67. Frey, B.S., and A. Stutzer. 2013. Introduction. In Recent developments in the economics of happiness, ed. B.S. Frey and A. Stutzer. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.

    Google Scholar 

  68. Fujiwara, D. (2013) The social impact of housing providers. HACT report (http://www.hact.org.uk/sites/default/files/uploads/Archives/2013/02/The%20Social%20Impact%20of%20Housing%20FINALpdf.pdf)

  69. Gilbert, D.T. 2006. Stumbling on happiness. Alfred A Knopf.

  70. Gilovich, T. & Kumar, A. (2015) We’ll always have Paris: The hedonic payoff from experiential and material investments. In: Advances in experimental social psychology, vol. 51, ed. M. Zanna & J. Olson, ch. 4, pp. 147–187. New York: Academic Press (Elsevier).

  71. Gabaix, X., and A. Landier. 2008. Why has CEO pay increased so much? Quarterly Journal of Economics 123: 49–100.

    Google Scholar 

  72. Graham, C. 2009. Happiness around the world: The paradox of happy peasants and miserable millionaires. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  73. Graham, C., and S. Pettinato. 2002. Happiness and hardship: Opportunity and insecurity in new market economies. Washington, DC: Brookings Institution.

    Google Scholar 

  74. Griffin, J. 2007. What do happiness studies study? Journal of Happiness Studies 8: 139–148.

    Google Scholar 

  75. Gullone, E., and R.A. Cummins (eds.). 2002. The universality of subjective wellbeing indicators: A multi-disciplinary and multi-national perspective. London: Kluwer.

    Google Scholar 

  76. Hagerty, M., and R. Veenhoven. 2003. Wealth and happiness revisited—growing national income does go with greater happiness. Social Indicators Research 64: 1–27.

    Google Scholar 

  77. Harsanyi, J.C. 1997. Utilities, preferences, and corporal goods. Social Choice and Welfare 14: 129–145.

    Google Scholar 

  78. Haybron, D. (2011) Happiness. The Stanford Encyclopedia of Philosophy, ed. E. N. Zalta (http://plato.stanford.edu/archives/fall2011/entries/happiness–checked on 8 May 2016).

  79. Headey, B. 2008. The Set-point theory of well-being: Negative results and consequent revisions. Social Indicators Research 86: 389–403.

    Google Scholar 

  80. Headey, B., and A. Wearing. 1992. Understanding happiness: A theory of subjective well-being. Melbourne: Longman Cheshire.

    Google Scholar 

  81. Heller, D., D. Watson, and R. Ilies. 2004. The role of person versus situation in life satisfaction: A critical examination. Psychological Bulletin 130: 574–600.

    Google Scholar 

  82. Helliwell, J., R. Layard, and J. Sachs (eds.). 2016. World Happiness Report 2016 Update,, vol. 1. New York: Sustainable Development Solutions Network.

    Google Scholar 

  83. Helson, H. 1947. Adaptation-level as frame of reference for prediction of psychological data. American Journal of Psychology 60: 1–29.

    Google Scholar 

  84. Inglehart, R., and H. Klingemann. 2000. Genes, culture, democracy and happiness. In Culture and subjective well-being, ed. E. Diener and E.M. Suh, 165–183. Cambridge: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  85. Kahneman, D., and A. Tversky. 1979. Prospect theory: An analysis of decision under risk. Econometrica 47: 263–291.

    Google Scholar 

  86. Kahneman, D., P.P. Wakker, and R. Sarin. 1997. Back to Bentham? Explorations of experienced utility. Quarterly Journal of Economics 112: 375–406.

    Google Scholar 

  87. Kahneman, D., E. Diener, and N. Schwarz (eds.). 1999. Well-being: The foundations of hedonic psychology. New York: Russell Sage Foundation.

    Google Scholar 

  88. Kahneman, D., and A.B. Krueger. 2006. Developments in the measurement of subjective well-being. Journal of Economic Perspectives 20: 3–24.

    Google Scholar 

  89. Kahneman, D., and A. Deaton. 2010. High income improves evaluation of life but not emotional well-being. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences (USA) 107: 16489–16493.

    Google Scholar 

  90. Kammann, R. 1983. Objective circumstances, life satisfactions and sense of well-being: Consistencies across time and place. New Zealand Psychologist 12: 14–22.

    Google Scholar 

  91. Khalil, E.L. 1989. Adam Smith and Albert Einstein: The aesthetic principle of truth. History of Economics Society Bulletin 11: 222–237.

    Google Scholar 

  92. Khalil, E.L. 1995. On the scope of economics: What is the question? Finnish Economic Papers 8: 40–55.

    Google Scholar 

  93. Khalil, E.L. 1996. What is economic action? From Marshall and Robbins to Polanyi and Becker. Journal of the History of Economic Thought 18: 13–36.

    Google Scholar 

  94. Khalil, E.L. 1997a. Buridan’s ass, uncertainty, risk, and self-competition: A theory of entrepreneurship. Kyklos 50: 147–163.

    Google Scholar 

  95. Khalil, E.L. 1997b. Chaos theory versus Heisenberg’s uncertainty: Risk, uncertainty and economic theory. American Economist 41: 27–40.

    Google Scholar 

  96. Khalil, E.L. 1997c. Economics, biology, and naturalism: Three problems concerning the question ofindividuality. Biology & Philosophy 12: 185–206.

    Google Scholar 

  97. Khalil, E.L. 1999. Sentimental fools: A critique of Amartya Sen’s notion of commitment. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization 40 (4): 373–386.

    Google Scholar 

  98. Khalil, E.L. 2000. Symbolic products: Prestige, pride and identity goods. Theory and Decision 49: 53–77.

    Google Scholar 

  99. Khalil, E.L. 2004. The gift paradox: Complex selves and symbolic goods. Review of Social Economy 62: 379–392.

    Google Scholar 

  100. Khalil, E.L. 2005. An anatomy of authority: Adam Smith as political theorist. Cambridge Journal of Economics 29: 57–71.

    Google Scholar 

  101. Khalil, E.L. 2010. The Bayesian fallacy: Distinguishing internal motivations and religious beliefs from other beliefs. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization 75: 268–280.

    Google Scholar 

  102. Khalil, E.L. 2013. Disentangling the order effect from the context effect: Analogies, homologies and quantum probability. Behavioral and Brain Sciences. 36: 293–294.

    Google Scholar 

  103. Khalil, E.L. 2015. Temptations as impulsivity: How far are regret and the Allais paradox from shoplifting? Economic. Modelling 51: 551–559.

    Google Scholar 

  104. Khalil, E. L. 2017a. Weakness of will and stiffness of will: How far are shirking, slackening, favoritism, spoiling of children, and pornography from obsessive-compulsive behavior? In Handbook of behavioral economics and smart decision-making: Rational decision-making within the bounds of reason, ed. M. Altman, 492–514. Edward Elgar.

  105. Khalil, E.L. 2017b. Socialized view of man vs. rational choice theory: What does 17b’s sympathy have to say? Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization 143: 223–240.

    Google Scholar 

  106. Khalil, E.L. 2018a. Faust and job: The dual-facet of happiness. A Mimeo.

  107. Khalil, E.L. 2018b. A rational theory of happiness: Solving the wellbeing-happiness paradox. A Mimeo.

  108. Khalil, E.L., J. Aimone, D. Houser, S. Wang, and D. Martinez. 2018. The aspirational income hypothesis: On the limits of the relative income hypothesis. A Mimeo.

  109. Kőszegi, B., and M. Rabin. 2006. A model of reference-dependent preferences. Quarterly Journal of Economics 121: 1133–1165.

    Google Scholar 

  110. Korsgaard, C.M. 2009. Self-Constitution: Agency, identity, and integrity. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  111. Krueger, A.B. (ed.). 2009. Measuring the subjective well-being of nations: National accounts of time use and well-being. Chicago: University of Chicago.

    Google Scholar 

  112. Layard, R. 2006. Happiness: Lessons from a new science. London: Penguin Books.

    Google Scholar 

  113. Layard, R., A. Clark, and C. Senik. 2012. First world happiness report launched at the United Nations. New York: Earth Institute, Columbia University New York.

    Google Scholar 

  114. Layard, R., G. Mayraz, and S. Nickell. 2010. Does relative income matter? Are the critics right? In International Differences in Well-Being, ed. E. Diener, J.F. Helliwell, and D. Kahneman. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  115. LeBoeuf, R.A., and E. Shafir. 2003. Deep thoughts and shallow frames: On the susceptibility to framing effects. Journal of Behavioral Decision Making 16: 77–92.

    Google Scholar 

  116. Lim, R. 1995. A Range-frequency explanation of shifting reference points in risky decision making. Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes 63: 6–20.

    Google Scholar 

  117. Loewenstein, George. 1999. Because it is there: The challenge of mountaineering… for utility theory”. Kyklos 52: 315–343.

    Google Scholar 

  118. Lucas, R.E., A.E. Clark, Y. Georgellis, and E. Diener. 2004. Unemployment alters the set-point for life satisfaction. Psychological Science 15: 8–13.

    Google Scholar 

  119. Lucas, R.E., P.S. Dyrenforth, and E. Diener. 2008. Four myths about subjective well-being. Social and Personality Psychology Compass 2: 2001–2015.

    Google Scholar 

  120. Margraf, J., Meyer, A. H. & Lavallee, K. L. (2013) Well-being from the knife? Psychological effects of aesthetic surgery. Clinical Psychological Science July 1:239-252

  121. Margraf, J., A.H. Meyer, and K.L. Lavallee. 2015. Psychological health and aims of aesthetic surgery seekers. Clinical Psychological Science 3: 877–891.

    Google Scholar 

  122. Mas-Colell, A., M.D. Whinton, and J.R. Green. 1995. Microeconomic theory. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  123. Matuska, K., and C. Christiansen (eds.). 2009. Life balance: Multidisciplinary theories and research. Thorofare: Slack Incorporated.

    Google Scholar 

  124. McDaid, D. & Cooper, C. L., eds. (2014) Wellbeing: A complete reference guide, Vol. V: The economics of wellbeing. New York: Wiley Blackwell.

  125. McMahon, D.M. 2004. From the happiness of virtue to the virtue of happiness: 400 B.C.-A.D. 1780. Daedalus 133: 5–17.

    Google Scholar 

  126. McMahon, D.M. 2006. Happiness: A history. New York: Grove Press.

    Google Scholar 

  127. Mishra, V., I. Nielsen, and R. Smyth. 2016. Evidence of set points for subjective wellbeing in longitudinal data. A Mimeo: Monash University, Clayton.

    Google Scholar 

  128. Moynihan, R., and A. Cassels. 2005. Selling Sickness: How Drug Companies Are Turning Us All Into Patients. London: Allen and Unwin.

    Google Scholar 

  129. Nettle, D. 2005. Happiness: the science behind your smile. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  130. Ng, Y.-K. (1978) Economic growth and social welfare: The need for a complete study of happiness. Kyklos 31:575-87. (Reprinted in: Happiness in economics, ed. R. A. Easterlin, 2002, pp. 66-77. Cheltenhamc: Edward Elgar)

  131. Ng, Y.-K. 1987. Relative-income effects and the appropriate level of public expenditure. Oxford Economic Papers 39: 293–300.

    Google Scholar 

  132. Ng, Y.-K. 2002. The East-Asian happiness gap. Pacific Economic Review 7: 51–63.

    Google Scholar 

  133. Oishi, S., and U. Schimmack. 2010. Culture and well-being: A new inquiry into the psychological wealth of nations. Perspectives on Psychological Science 5: 463–471.

    Google Scholar 

  134. Oswald, A.J. 1997. Happiness and economic performance. Economic Journal 107: 1815–1831.

    Google Scholar 

  135. Parducci, A. 1995. Happiness, pleasure, and judgement: The contextual theory and its applications. Hillsdale: L. Erlbaum Associates.

    Google Scholar 

  136. Pavot, W., and E. Diener. 1993. Review of the satisfaction with life scale. Psychological Assessment 5: 164–172.

    Google Scholar 

  137. Pomfret, Gill. 2006. Mountaineering adventure tourists: A conceptual framework for research. Tourism Management 27: 113–123.

    Google Scholar 

  138. Powdthavee, N. 2011. The happiness equation: The surprising economics of our most valuable asset. London: Icon Books.

    Google Scholar 

  139. Robbins, L.C. 1935. An essay on the nature and significance of economic science. London: Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  140. Robinson, M.D., and R.J. Compton. 2008. The happy mind in action: The cognitive basis of subjective well-being. In The science of subjective well-being, ed. M. Eid, and R.J. Larsen, 220–238. Guilford Press.

  141. Ryff, C.D. 1989. Happiness is everything, or is it? Explorations on the meaning of psychological well-being. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology 57: 1069–1081.

    Google Scholar 

  142. Schooler, J.W., D. Ariely, and G. Loewenstein. 2003. The pursuit and assessment of happiness can be self-defeating. In The psychology of economic decision, ed. I. Brocas and J. Carillo. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  143. Schumacher, E.F. 1973. Small is beautiful. New York: Harper & Row.

    Google Scholar 

  144. Schwartz, B. 2004. The paradox of choice: Why more is less. New York: HarperCollins.

    Google Scholar 

  145. Scitovsky, T. 1992. The joyless economy: The psychology of human satisfaction. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  146. Seligman, M.E.P. 2002. Authentic happiness: Using the new positive psychology to realize your potential for lasting fulfillment. New York: Free Press.

    Google Scholar 

  147. Seligman, M.E.P. 2004. Can happiness be taught? Daedalus 133: 80–87.

    Google Scholar 

  148. Seligman, M.E.P. 2011. Flourish: A visionary new understanding of happiness and well-being. New York: Free Press.

    Google Scholar 

  149. Seligman, M.E.P., and M. Csikszentmihalyi. 2000. Positive psychology: An introduction. American Psychologist 55: 5–14.

    Google Scholar 

  150. Sen, A. 1987. On ethics and economics. New York: Blackwell.

    Google Scholar 

  151. Sen, A. 1999. Development as freedom. New York: Knopf.

    Google Scholar 

  152. Shields, M.A., and S.W. Price. 2005. Exploring the economic and social determinants of psychological well-being and perceived social support in England. Journal of the Royal Statistical Society: Series A (Statistics in Society) 168: 513–537.

    Google Scholar 

  153. Sinnott, J.D. (ed.). 2013. Positive psychology: Advances in understanding adult motivation. New York: Springer.

    Google Scholar 

  154. Smith, Adam. 1976. In The theory of moral sentiments, ed. D.D. Raphael and A.L. Macfie. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  155. Snyder, C.R., and S.J. Lopez (eds.). 2005. Handbook of positive psychology. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  156. Stevenson, B. & Wolfers, J. (2008) Economic growth and subjective well-being: Reassessing the Easterlin paradox. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 39:1-102. (With extensive comments by Gary S. Becker, Luis Rayo, and Alan B. Krueger).

  157. Stiglitz, Joseph, Amartya Sen, and Jan-Paul Fitoussi (2009) Report by the commission on the measurement of economic performance and social progress. (http://ec.europa.eu/eurostat/documents/118025/118123/Fitoussi+Commission+report)

  158. Tay, L., and E. Diener. 2001. Needs and subjective well-being around the world. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology 101: 354–365.

    Google Scholar 

  159. Tversky, A., and D. Kahneman. 1981. The framing of decisions and the psychology of choice. Science 211: 453–458.

    Google Scholar 

  160. van der Rijt, J.-W. 2013. Public policy and the conditional value of happiness. Economics and Philosophy 29: 381–408.

    Google Scholar 

  161. van Praag, B. M. S. & Baarsma, B. E. (2014) Using happiness surveys to value intangibles: The case of airport noise. Discussion Paper No.1096, IZA, Bonn, Germany.

  162. Veenhoven, R. 1984. Conditions of happiness. Boston: D. Reidel.

    Google Scholar 

  163. Veenhoven, R. 1993. Happiness in nations: Subjective appreciation of life in 56 nations, 1946–1992. Rotterdam: Risbo Press.

    Google Scholar 

  164. Veenhoven, R. 1996. Developments in satisfaction research. Social Indicators Research 37: 1–47.

    Google Scholar 

  165. Veenhoven, R. 2005. Happiness in hardship. In Economics and happiness: Framing the analysis, ed. L. Bruni and P.L. Porta. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  166. Watson, D., L.A. Clark, and A. Tellegen. 1988. Development and validation of brief measures of positive and negative affect: The PANAS scales. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology 54: 1063–1070.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgment

Earlier versions benefited from the comments of Steven Gardner, Lucy Mayne, Fiona Newton, Michael Ewing, Yew-Kwang Ng, Birendra Rai, Michael Dunstan, James Ang, Ranjan Ray, Dietrich Fausten, Ratbek Dzhumashev, Haiou Zhou, Jonathan Wight, Carol Graham, Volker P.N. Grzimek, anonymous referees, participants of sessions at the Southern Economic Association conference, the Australia New Zealand Workshop on Experimental Economics, and participants of seminars at George Mason University, James Madison University, University of Richmond, Deakin University, Queensland University of Technology, and Monash University. The usual caveat applies.

Author information

Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Elias L. Khalil.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and Permissions

About this article

Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Khalil, E.L. Wellbeing and Happiness. J Value Inquiry 53, 627–652 (2019). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10790-018-9678-1

Download citation