Abstract
As the demand for publicly funded health care continues to rise in the U.S., there is increasing pressure on state governments to ensure patient access through adjustments in provider compensation policies. This paper longitudinally examines the fees that states paid physicians for services covered by the Medicaid program over the period 1998–2004. Controlling for an extensive set of economic and health care industry characteristics, the elasticity of states’ Medicaid fees, with respect to Medicare fees, is estimated to be in the range of 0.2–0.7 depending on the type of physician service examined. The findings indicate a significant degree of price competition between the Medicaid and Medicare programs for physician services that is more pronounced for cardiology and critical care, but not hospital care. The results also suggest several policy levers that work to either increase patient access or reduce total program costs through changes in fees.
This is a preview of subscription content,
to check access.Notes
Fee-for-service compensation policies are a common approach for paying health care providers within Medicaid. Even among states that have adopted managed care methods, physician service fees continue to play an influential role in determining capitation rates and reimbursements through primary care case management programs (Zuckerman et al. 2009; Schneider et al. 2002; Norton and Zuckerman 2000).
Outpatient physician services are covered under Medicare Part B, and inpatient physician services are covered under Medicare Part A. Additional plan options were created with the Balanced Budget Act of 1997, and Private Fee-for-Service plans can now have higher fees than the traditional program; see Blum et al (2007) for details.
Medicaid is a means-tested welfare program that is jointly administered by both federal and state governments, while Medicare is an entitlement program that is administered by the federal government.
See Tables 3 and 9 at http://www.cms.hhs.gov/NationalHealthExpendData/downloads/tables.pdf
Expenditures were adjusted by the author using the CPI in 2011 dollars. For original figures see Table 8.E1 at http://www.ssa.gov/policy/docs/statcomps/supplement/2011/8e.html
See section 1902(a)(30)(A) of the Social Security Act, 42 U.S.C. 1396a(a)(30)(A). The geographic area guideline was introduced with the enactment of the Omnibus Budget Reconciliation Act of 1989 (Flint 2006).
Outpatient physician services are covered under Medicare Part B, and inpatient physician services are covered under Medicare Part A.
A further distinction in Practice Expense RVUs is also made for whether the service was provided in a facility or non-facility setting. A non-facility setting is typically a physician’s office, while a facility setting is typically an inpatient or outpatient hospital where practice expenses are lower. In this study, we focus on the role of non-facility Medicare physician fees where applicable.
In certain instances, Medicare has set a fee for a physician service that it does not actually provide to recipients.
Since 1997, GPCIs are currently designated for 89 unique geographic localities in the U.S., and certain states have more than one locality. In practice, states do not account for a non-uniform distribution of health care production costs across localities when setting Medicaid physician fees. For instance, New York has five localities designated by Medicare, and each locality has a different GPCI assigned for each of the three RVU measures in Eq. (1) that is applied to every covered physician service; however, only one set of Medicaid physician fees is determined by the state and it is applied equally to all five of the localities. See https://www.cms.gov/PhysicianFeeSched/15_AlternativeGPCIReview.asp#TopOfPage
The FMAP is the percentage of state Medicaid spending matched by the federal government. It is calculated as 1 minus 0.45 times the square of the ratio of state per capita income to national per capita income averaged over three years; and is bounded between 50 % for the highest income states and 83 % for the lowest income states.
A limited set of physician services were analyzed: a follow-up hospital visit, a follow-up office visit, an inguinal hernia repair, a diagnostic dilation and curettage, a complete blood count, and an electrocardiogram.
The income and resource tests each have an associated standard and methodology. A standard is a particular level, below which an individual is deemed eligible. A methodology is the way in which an individual’s income and resources are counted for the purposes of applying the standard.
Independent Medicaid eligibility rules are set by the following states: Connecticut, Hawaii, Illinois, Indiana, Minnesota, Missouri, New Hampshire, North Dakota, Ohio, Oklahoma, Virginia.
The null hypothesis that \(\upbeta _{1}\) is equal to one is rejected (\(P<0.0001\)), which implies that transforming the outcome as the ratio of Medicaid-to-Medicare fees is not statistically supported by the data in this context.
The states with a constant FMAP of 50 % for 1998-2004 were CT, IL, MD, MA, NH, NJ, and NY. See Table 9 in the appendix for details.
References
Baicker, K. (2005). Extensive or intensive generosity? The price and income effects of federal grants. Review of Economics and Statistics, 87(2), 371–384.
Baker, L. C., & Royalty, A. B. (2000). Medicaid policy, physician behavior, and health care for the low-income population. Journal of Human Resources, 35(3), 480–502.
Blum, J., Brown, R., & Frieder, M. (2007). An examination of Medicare private fee-for-service plans. In Medicare Issue brief. Washington, DC: Kaiser Family Foundation.
Buntin, M. J. B., Escarcé, J. J., Goldman, D., Kan, H., Laugesen, M. J., & Shekelle, P. (2004). Increased Medicare expenditures for physicians’ services: What are the causes? Inquiry, 41(1), 83–94.
Cohen, J. W., & Cunningham, P. J. (1995). Medicaid physician fee levels and children’s access to care. Health Affairs, 14(1), 255–262.
Cubanski, J., Huang, J., Damico, A., Jacobson, G., & Neuman, T. (2010). Medicare chartbook (4th ed.). Washington, DC: The Henry J. Kaiser Family Foundation.
Currie, J., Gruber, J., & Fischer, M. (1995). Physician payments and infant mortality: Evidence from Medicaid fee policy. American Economic Review, 85(2), 106–111.
Decker, S. L. (2007). Medicaid physician fees and the quality of medical care of Medicaid patients in the USA. Review of Economics of the Household, 5(1), 95–112.
Decker, S. L. (2009). Changes in Medicaid physician fees and patterns of ambulatory care. Inquiry, 46(3), 291–304.
Flint, S. S. (2006). Ensuring equal access for Medicaid children. Health & Social Work, 31(1), 65.
Garthwaite, C. L. (2011). The doctor might see you now: The supply side effects of public health insurance expansions. Working Paper No. 17070: National Bureau of Economic Research.
Gaynor, M., & Haas-Wilson, D. (1999). Change, consolidation, and competition in health care markets. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 13(1), 141–164.
Gaynor, M., Ho, K., & Town, R. (2014). The industrial organization of health care markets. Working Paper No. 19800: National Bureau of Economic Research.
Ginsburg, P. B., LeRoy, L. B., & Hammons, G. T. (1990). Medicare physician payment reform. Health Affairs, 9(1), 178–188.
Glied, S. (2003). Health care costs: On the rise again. The Journal of Economic Perspectives, 17(2), 125–148.
Gray, B. (2001). Do Medicaid physician fees for prenatal services affect birth outcomes? Journal of Health Economics, 20(4), 571–590.
Grimaldi, P. L. (2002). Medicare fees for physician services are resource-based. Journal of Health Care Finance, 28(3), 88.
Gruber, J., Kim, J., & Mayzlin, D. (1999). Physician fees and procedure intensity: The case of cesarean delivery. Journal of Health Economics, 18(4), 473–490.
Hadley, J., & Reschovsky, J. (2006). Medicare fees and physicians’ medicare service volume: Beneficiaries treated and services per beneficiary. International Journal of Health Care Finance and Economics, 6(2), 131–150.
Hadley, J., Reschovsky, J., Corey, C., & Zuckerman, S. (2009). Medicare fees and the volume of physicians services. Inquiry, 46(4), 372–390.
Johnson, S., & Newton, W. (2002). Resource-based relative value units: A primer for academic family physicians. Family Medicine, 34(3), 172.
Kleiner, S., Lyons, S., & White, W. D. (2012). Provider concentration in markets for physician services for patients with traditional Medicare. Health Management, Policy and Innovation, 1(1), 3–18.
McGuire, T. G., & Pauly, M. V. (1991). Physician response to fee changes with multiple payers. Journal of Health Economics, 10(4), 385–410.
Mitchell, J., Hadley, J., & Gaskin, D. (2002). Spillover effects of Medicare fee reductions: Evidence from ophthalmology. International Journal of Health Care Finance and Economics, 2(3), 171–188.
Norton, S., & Zuckerman, S. (2000). Trends in Medicaid physician fees, 1993–1998. Health Affairs, 19(4), 222–232.
Schneider, A., Elias, R., Garfield, R., Rousseau, D., & Wachino, V. (2002). The Medicaid Resource Book. Washington, DC: The Kaiser Commission on Medicaid and the Uninsured.
Sloan, F. A. (1984). State discretion in federal categorical assistance programs: The case of Medicaid. Public Finance Quarterly, 12(3), 321–346.
Sloan, F. A., Cromwell, J., & Mitchell, J. B. (1978a). Private physicians and public programs. Lexington, MA: Lexington Books.
Sloan, F. A., Mitchell, J., & Cromwell, J. (1978b). Physician participation in state Medicaid programs. Journal of Human Resources, 13(4), 211–245.
Staiger, D. O., Auerbach, D. I., & Buerhaus, P. I. (2010). Trends in the work hours of physicians in the United States. JAMA: The Journal of the American Medical Association, 303(8), 747–753.
Turcotte, L., Robst, J., & Polachek, S. (2005). Medicaid coverage and medical interventions during pregnancy. International Journal of Health Care Finance and Economics, 5(3), 255–271.
U.S. Congress. (2010). Public Law 111–148. 124 STAT, 119-1024.
U.S. Government Accountability Office (2009). Medicare Physician Services: Utilization Trends Indicate Sustained Beneficiary Access with High and Growing Levels of Service in Some Areas of the Nation. GAO-09-559.
Yelowitz, A. S. (1998). Why did the SSI-disabled program grow so much? Disentangling the effect of Medicaid. Journal of Health Economics, 17(3), 321–349.
Zelman, W. N., McCue, M. J., & Glick, N. D. (2009). Financial management of health care organizations: An introduction to fundamental tools, concepts, and applications. San Francisco, CA: Jossey-Bass.
Zuckerman, S., McFeeters, J., Cunningham, P., & Nichols, L. (2004). Changes in Medicaid physician fees 1998–2003: Implications for physician participation. Health Affairs, 23(4), 292–292.
Zuckerman, S., Williams, A. F., & Stockley, K. E. (2009). Trends in Medicaid physician fees, 2003–2008. Health Affairs, 28(3), w510–w519.
Acknowledgments
The author thanks Chava Sheffield at CMS for help with acquiring the earlier Medicare data and a reviewer for helpful comments on an earlier draft.
Author information
Authors and Affiliations
Corresponding author
Rights and permissions
About this article
Cite this article
Howard, L.L. Do the Medicaid and Medicare programs compete for access to health care services? A longitudinal analysis of physician fees, 1998–2004. Int J Health Care Finance Econ 14, 229–250 (2014). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10754-014-9146-9
Received:
Accepted:
Published:
Issue Date:
DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10754-014-9146-9