Abstract
This paper investigates how current and future generations are affected by commitment-based Nash equilibrium environmental strategies when the environmental absorption efficiency is susceptible to switch from a pollution sink to a source. We formulate a two-player differential game model of transboundary pollution that includes the environmental absorption efficiency as a state variable that can be enhanced thanks to restoration efforts. Based on a logarithmic specification for the instantaneous revenue function, we characterize the cooperative solution and the commitment-based Nash equilibrium strategy, and examine their differences in terms of steady state and transient behavior. We notably show that a commitment-based Nash equilibrium strategy makes it possible to prevent a definitive switching of the environmental absorption efficiency from a pollution sink to a source but imposes greater economic sacrifices on current generations than on future generations. In comparison, the cooperative solution imposes greater sacrifices on current generations in terms of revenues but it imposes lower environmental costs on both current and future generations than commitment-based Nash equilibrium strategy.
This is a preview of subscription content, access via your institution.
References
Canadell JG, Le Quéré C, Raupach MR, Field CB, Buitenhuis ET, Ciais P, Conway TJ, Gillett NP, Houghton RA, Marland G (2007) Contributions to accelerating atmospheric \(\text{ CO }_{2}\) growth from economic activity, carbon intensity, and efficiency of natural sinks. Proc Nat Acad Sci 104(47):18866–18870
Cox PM, Betts RA, Jones C, Spall SA, Totterdell I (2000) Acceleration of global warming due to carbon-cycle feedbacks in a coupled climate model. Nature 408:184–187
Dockner E, Jørgensen S, Long NV, Sorger G (2000) Differential games in economics and management science. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge
Dockner EJ, Long NV (1993) International pollution control: cooperative versus non-cooperative strategies. J Environ Econ Manag 25(1):13–29
Dockner EJ, Wagener F (2014) Markov perfect Nash equilibria in models with a single capital stock. Econ Theory 56(3):585–625
El Ouardighi F, Benchekroun H, Grass D (2014) Controlling pollution and environmental absorption capacity. Ann Oper Res 220(1):111–133
El Ouardighi F, Benchekroun H, Grass D (2016) Self-regenerating environmental absorption efficiency and the Soylent Green scenario. Ann Oper Res 238(1):179–198
Grass D, Caulkins JP, Feichtinger G, Tragler G, Behrens DA (2008) Optimal control of nonlinear processes with applications in drugs, corruption, and terror. Springer, Heidelberg
Joos F, Prentice IC, Sitch S, Meyer R, Hooss G, Plattner G-K, Gerber S, Hasselmann K (2001) Global warming feedbacks on terrestrial carbon uptake under the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change (IPCC) emission scenarios. Glob Biogeochem Cycles 15(4):891–907
Kossioris G, Plexousakis M, Xepapadeas A, de Zeeuw AJ, Mäler K-G (2008) Feedback Nash equilibria for non-linear differential games in pollution control. J Econ Dyn Control 32(4):1312–1331
Lenton TM, Williamson MS, Edwards NR, Marsh R, Price AR, Ridgwell AJ, Shepherd JG, Cox SJ, The GENIE Team (2006) Millennial timescale carbon cycle and climate change in an efficient Earth system model. Clim Dyn 26(7/8):687–711
Le Quéré C, Rödenbeck’ C, Buitenhuis ET, Conway TJ, Langenfelds R, Gomez A, Labuschagne C, Ramonet M, Nakazawa T, Metzl N, Gillett N, Heimann M (2007) Saturation of the Southern Ocean \(\text{ CO }_{2}\) sink due to recent climate change. Science 316(5832):1735–1738
Mäler K-G, Xepapadeas A, de Zeeuw AJ (2003) The economics of shallow lakes. Environ Resour Econ 26(4):603–624
Piao SL, Ciais P, Friedlingstein P, Peylin P, Reichstein M, Luyssaert S, Margolis H, Fang JY, Barr A, Chen AP, Grelle A, Hollinger DY, Laurila T, Lindroth A, Richardson AD, Vesala T (2008) Net carbon dioxide losses of northern ecosystems in response to autumn warming. Nature 451:49–52
Rubio S, Casino B (2002) A note on cooperative versus noncooperative strategies in international pollution control. Resour Energy Econ 24(3):251–261
Van der Ploeg F, de Zeeuw AJ (1992) International aspects of pollution control. Environ Resour Econ 2(2):117–139
Acknowledgements
This research was financially supported by ESSEC Business School Research Centre (France). Giorgio Gnecco and Marcello Sanguineti are members of GNAMPA-INdAM (Gruppo Nazionale per l’Analisi Matematica, la Probabilità e le loro Applicazioni - Instituto Nazionale di Alta Matematica). The authors acknowledge helpful comments by an Associate Editor and two anonymous reviewers. The usual disclaimer applies.
Author information
Authors and Affiliations
Corresponding author
Appendix
Appendix
1.1 Sketch of the proofs of the results presented in Sect. 3
For the optimal control problem related to the CS case, the current-value Hamiltonian is:
in which \(\eta _j \equiv \eta _j (t)\) are (current-value) costate variables, \(j=1,2\).
Assuming an interior solution, the application of Pontryagin’s principle gives the following necessary conditions:
\(i=1,2,\) while the costate variables evolution is described by
Equations (A2) and (A3) show that the players’ CS policies are indeed symmetric, as expected. Using (A2)–(A3), formulas (1)–(2) can be rewritten as:
To get further insights into the optimal control problem at hand, let us assume a steady state to study how an optimal control is at such a state. Setting \(\dot{P} =\dot{A}=0\) provides:\(\sum _i {e_i } =AP\) and \(\sum _i {w_i } =\gamma P\). Differentiating the two latter equations with respect to time and recalling \(\dot{P} =\dot{A}=0\) provides steady efforts: \(\dot{e}_i =\dot{w}_i =0,\quad i = 1, 2\). Moreover, differentiating (A2)–(A3) over any time interval and using \(\dot{e}_i =\dot{w}_i =0\), \(i=1,\;2\), the costate variables are also time-invariant. Hence, if the absorption efficiency and the pollution stock are both steady, then the associated costate variables are also steady, and each player’s efforts are time-invariant.
Given this framework, the theoretical results presented in Sect. 3 are obtained by the resolution of the equations (A1–A7). It is noteworthy that the limiting transversality conditions are satisfied by the CS steady state in (5).
1.2 Sketch of the proofs of the results presented in Sect. 4
For the differential game problem related to the OLNE case, the current-value Hamiltonian of player ican be expressed as:
in which \(\lambda _{ij} \equiv \lambda _{ij} (t)\) denote player i’s (current-value) costate variables, \(i=1,2\), \(j=1,2\).
Assuming an interior solution, player i’s necessary conditions for the OLNE are:
\(i=1,2,\) in which the superscript “on” is used to denote the OLNE.
The costate variables evolve according to:
In the present case, the costate variables of both players are identical; that is, \(\lambda _{i1} \equiv \lambda _1 \) and \(\lambda _{i2} \equiv \lambda _2 \), \(i=1,2\). Hence, (A9) and (A10) show that the players’ equilibrium strategies are symmetric, as expected. As a consequence, only two costate equations have to be considered in the analysis.
Exploiting (A9)–(A10), (1)–(2) can be rewritten as
Hence, if the absorption efficiency and the pollution stock are both steady, then each player’s control efforts are time-invariant.
Given this framework, the theoretical results presented in Sect. 4 are obtained by the resolution of the equations (A8)–(A13). It is also noteworthy that the limiting transversality conditions are satisfied by the OLNE steady state (11).
Rights and permissions
About this article
Cite this article
El Ouardighi, F., Kogan, K., Gnecco, G. et al. Commitment-Based Equilibrium Environmental Strategies Under Time-Dependent Absorption Efficiency. Group Decis Negot 27, 235–249 (2018). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10726-017-9545-7
Published:
Issue Date:
DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10726-017-9545-7
Keywords
- Transboundary pollution
- Environmental absorption efficiency
- Cooperative solution
- Commitment-based strategies