Skip to main content
Log in

Transparency in the Mortgage Market

  • Published:
Journal of Financial Services Research Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This paper studies the impact of transparency in the mortgage market on the underlying real estate market. We show that geographic transparency in the secondary mortgage market, which implies geographic risk based pricing in the primary market, can limit risk-sharing and make house prices more volatile. Ex ante, regions prefer opaque markets to enable insurance opportunities. We discuss the implications for risk based pricing and house price volatility more generally. In addition, we investigate the specific conditions under which competitive lenders would optimally choose to provide opaque lending, thus reducing volatility in the real estate market. We show that in general the opaque competitive equilibrium is not stable, and lenders have incentive to switch to transparent lending if one of the geographic regions has experienced a negative income shock. We propose market and regulatory mechanisms that make the opaque competitive equilibrium stable and insurance opportunities possible.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Institutional subscriptions

Fig. 1
Fig. 2

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. In 2008, Fannie Mae briefly implemented a “Declining Markets Policy” by restricting the maximum CTLV for properties located within a declining market to five percentage points less than the maximum permitted for the selected mortgage product. Fannie Mae ended this policy in a few months.

  2. For a discussion of the liquidity of the MBS market and its benefits as measured in the TBA market see Vickery and Wright (2010).

  3. DGH argue that while symmetry of information about payoffs is essential for liquidity, transparency is not and opacity actually contributes to liquidity as symmetric information can be achieved through shared ignorance. Highly nontransparent markets can be very liquid (19th century clearinghouses, currency). When it is possible to obtain information about an asset, people invest in finding information differentially, resulting in lower overall liquidity.

  4. This is in contrast to Akerlof (1970) who shows that transparency is good in markets that suffer a “lemons” problem. Informing all parties who the lemons are will make the market function more smoothly.

  5. The exogenous auto-correlation in income we assume in the model generates an auto-correlation in house prices. For evidence on auto-correlation in house prices see Duca et al. (2010), Case and Shiller (1989), and Poterba et al. (1991).

References

  • Anctil RM, et al. (2010) Does information transparency decrease coordination failure? Games and Economic Behavior 70.2:228–241

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Akerlof GA (1970) The market for Lemons: quality uncertainty and the market mechanism. Q J Econ 84(3):488–500

  • Beltran DO, Cordell L, Thomas CP (2013) Asymmetric information and the death of ABS CDOs. International Finance Discussion Papers

  • Bouvard M, Chaigneau P, Motta ADe (2012) Transparency in the financial system: rollover risk and crises. Available at SSRN 1973673

  • Case KE, Shiller RJ (1989) The efficiency of the market for single-family homes

  • Dang TVi, Gorton G, Holmstrm B (2012) Ignorance, debt and financial crises. Unpublished, Yale SOM

  • Dang TVi, Gorton G, Holmstrm B (2013) The Information Sensitivity of a Security

  • Dang T Vi, Gorton G, Holmstrm B (2012) Haircuts and Repo Chains, working paper

  • Dang T Vi, et al. (2013) Banks as secret keepers. Working paper. Columbia University, Yale University, MIT, University of Pennsylvania and. NBER

  • Downing C, Jaffe DM, Wallace N (2005) Information asymmetries in the mortgage-backed securities market. AFA 2006 Boston Meetings Paper. Available at SSRN: http://ssrn.com/abstract=722423 or doi:10.2139/ssrn.722423

  • Duca JV, Muellbauer J, Murphy A (2010) Housing markets and the financial crisis of 20072009: lessons for the future. Journal of Financial Stability 6.4:203–217

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Farhi E, Tirole J (2012) Information, tranching and liquidity. Institut d’conomie Industrielle (IDEI), Toulouse

    Google Scholar 

  • French K, Baily M, Campbell J, Cochrane J, Diamond D, Duffie D, Stulz R (2010) The Squam Lake Report, Fixing the Financial System

  • Gorton GB (2008) The panic of 2007 no. w14358, National Bureau of Economic Research

  • Hirshleifer J (1971) The private and social value of information and the reward to inventive activity. Am Econ Review 61.4:561–574

    Google Scholar 

  • Holmstrom B (2012) Presidential Address, Econometric Society, ASSA meetings, Chicago, January 5–8, 2012

  • Hurst E, Keys B, Seru A, Vavra J (2014) Regional Risk Sharing Through the U.S. Mortgage Market

  • Pagano M, Volpin P (2010) Securitization, disclosure and liquidity. Review of Financial Studies, forthcoming

  • Poterba JM,Weil DN, Shiller R (1991) House price dynamics: The role of tax policy and demography. Brook Pap Econ Act:143–203

  • Vickery J, Wright J (2010) TBA trading and liquidity in the agency MBS market. FRB of New York Staff Report:468

Download references

Acknowledgments

Dr. Pavlov acknowledges financial support from the Social Sciences and Humanities Research Council of Canada. Dr.Wachter acknowledges the assistance from the Research Sponsors Program of the Zell/Lurie Real Estate Center at Wharton.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Andrey Pavlov.

Appendix: 2 periods, 2 states

Appendix: 2 periods, 2 states

Transparent Mortgage Markets

The lender gets \({L_{0}^{j}}{R}\) if the borrower repays, and p 1 j H if the borrower defaults.

Assume city A starts with the low income shock and city B starts with the high income shock: \({y_{0}^{A}}=y_{L}\), \({y_{0}^{B}}=y_{H}\).

If we denote the ratio \(\frac {{p_{t}^{A}}}{{p_{t}^{B}}}\) with θ t , then the income shock effects imply that θ 1 < θ 0. Without loss of generality let assume that θ 0 = 1, then the income shock effects are depicted in the fact that θ 1 < 1.

The probability city A will have a low shock next period is given by:

\( P\left \{ {y_{1}^{A}}=y_{L} | {y_{0}^{A}}= y_{L} \right \} =\frac {1+\rho }{2} \)

Where ρ ∈ [−1, 1] is the auto-correlation for income. We assume income follows a two-state Markov Chain:

$${y_{t}^{j}}\sim\left(\begin{array}{cc} \frac{1+\rho}{2} & \frac{1-\rho}{2} \\ \frac{1-\rho}{2} & \frac{1+\rho}{2}\end{array}\right).$$

For simplicity we assume that the spatial correlation in income shocks is perfectly negative ρ A, B = −1, so whenever city A has a bad shock, city B will have a good shock vice-versa.

In a transparent market, the lender’s expected profit to city j is:

$$\begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} \mathbb{E}\left[ {\pi_{t}^{j}} \right] &=& -{L_{t}^{j}} + \eta \mathbb{E}_{t} \min\left[ {L_{t}^{j}} R , p_{t+1}^{j} H \right]\\ &=& -{L_{t}^{j}} + \eta {L_{t}^{j}} R \cdot P\left\{ {L_{t}^{j}} R \leq p_{t+1}^{j} H \right\} +\eta H \mathbb{E}_{t}\left[ p_{t+1}^{j} | {L_{t}^{j}} R > p_{t+1}^{j} H \right] \end{array} $$

The zero expected profit condition implies:

\({L_{0}^{A}} = \eta \left (\frac {1-\rho }{2} \right ) {L_{0}^{A}} R + \eta \left (\frac {1+\rho }{2} \right ) {p_{1}^{A}}H\)\({\kern 11pt} {L_{0}^{A}} \left (1- \eta \left (\frac {1-\rho }{2} \right ) R \right ) = \eta \left (\frac {1+\rho }{2} \right ) H {p_{1}^{A}} \)\({\kern 11pt} {L_{0}^{A}} = \frac { \eta \left (\frac {1+\rho }{2} \right ) H } { \left (1- \eta \left (\frac {1-\rho }{2} \right ) R \right ) } {p_{1}^{A}}\)

Likewise,

$${L_{0}^{B}} = \eta \left( \frac{1+\rho}{2} \right) {L_{0}^{B}} R + \eta \left( \frac{1-\rho}{2} \right) {p_{1}^{B}} H$$
$${L_{0}^{B}} = \frac{ \eta \left( \frac{1-\rho}{2} \right) H } { \left(1- \eta \left( \frac{1+\rho}{2} \right) R \right) } {p_{1}^{B}} $$

In an opaque market, the lender’s zero profit condition is:

\( L_{0} = \frac {1}{2} \eta L_{0} R \cdot \left (\frac {1-\rho }{2}\right ) + \frac {1}{2} \eta \left (\frac {1+\rho }{2} \right ) H {p_{1}^{A}}\\ {\kern 11pt}+ \frac {1}{2} \eta \left (\frac {1+\rho }{2} \right ) L_{0} R + \frac {1}{2} \eta \left (\frac {1-\rho }{2} \right ) H {p_{1}^{B}} \)\({\kern 11pt} L_{0} = \frac {1}{2} \eta L_{0} R\\ {\kern 11pt}+\frac {1}{2} \eta H \left [\left (\frac {1+\rho }{2} \right ) {p_{1}^{A}} {\kern 11pt}+ \left (\frac {1-\rho }{2} \right ) {p_{1}^{B}}\right ]\)\({\kern 11pt} L_{0} \left (1 - \frac {1}{2} \eta R \right ) = \frac {1}{2} \eta H \left [\left (\frac {1+\rho }{2} \right ) {p_{1}^{A}} + \left (\frac {1-\rho }{2} \right ) {p_{1}^{B}}\right ] \)\({\kern 11pt} L_{0} = \frac { \frac {1}{2} \eta H } { \left (1 - \frac {1}{2} \eta R \right ) } p_{1} \)

Where \(p_{1}= \left [\left (\frac {1+\rho }{2} \right ) {p_{1}^{A}} + \left (\frac {1-\rho }{2} \right ) {p_{1}^{B}}\right ]\), and we have \({p_{1}^{A}}<p_{1}<{p_{1}^{B}}\), also notice that in the opaque market case, each city receives the same loan L 0.

Proposition 1

If ρ > 0, then

if ηR > 1:

if ηR < 1: \({L_{0}^{A}} > L_{0} > {L_{0}^{B}}\) If income is negatively correlated ρ < 0, then signs are reversed. But this is not the case we are interested in.

The case we study has ρ > 0 and ηR > 1. Plugging this into the equilibrium price function: \({p_{0}^{j}} = \frac {1}{\gamma } \left (\alpha + {y_{0}^{j}} + {L_{0}^{j}} - H \right )\) Since the loan to city A under transparency is smaller than the loan to city A under opacity \({L_{0}^{A}}<L_{0}\) , the transparent price is lower than the opaque price: \(p_{0}^{A,trans} = \frac {1}{\gamma } \left (\alpha + {y_{0}^{j}} + {L_{0}^{A}} - H \right ) < \frac {1}{\gamma } \left (\alpha + {y_{0}^{j}} + L_{0} - H \right ) = p_{0}^{A,opaque} \) Likewise: \(p_{0}^{B,trans} = \frac {1}{\gamma } \left (\alpha + {y_{0}^{j}} + {L_{0}^{B}} - H \right ) > \frac {1}{\gamma } \left (\alpha + {y_{0}^{j}} + L_{0} - H \right ) = p_{0}^{B,opaque} \)

NOTE: we have assumed that city A starts with a bad income shock at time 0 and city B starts with a good income shock. Ex ante with probability \(\frac {1}{2}\) we have \({y_{0}^{A}}=y_{L}\) and \({y_{0}^{B}}=y_{H}\) , and with probability \(\frac {1}{2}\) we have \({y_{0}^{A}}=y_{H}\) and \({y_{0}^{B}}=y_{L}\) . However, ex ante neither city knows which state of the world they will start in they will prefer opacity to have smoother house prices.

The lesson from this model is that a geographically transparent mortgage market has more volatile house prices which are more strongly correlated to local risks.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Pavlov, A., Wachter, S. & Zevelev, A.A. Transparency in the Mortgage Market. J Financ Serv Res 49, 265–280 (2016). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10693-014-0211-9

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Revised:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10693-014-0211-9

Keywords

Navigation