Skip to main content
Log in

Risk preferences and contract choices

  • Original Paper
  • Published:
Experimental Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

We conducted a series of field experiments to investigate the ability of experimentally measured risk preferences to predict the contractual choices of workers in the real labour market. In a first set of experiments we twice measured workers’ risk preferences using the lottery approach of Holt and Laury (Am Econ Rev 92(5):1644–165, 2002). These workers subsequently participated in a contract-choice experiment, making 12 decisions. For each decision, the worker chose between his/her regular piece-rate contract and a particular fixed wage contract, each distinguished by the level of the fixed wage. One of the twelve decisions was then chosen at random and the worker was paid according to his/her choice for that decision over a period of two working days. We estimate the effect of risk preferences on contractual choices, controlling for measurement error and worker ability. Risk preferences effectively predict contract choices—risk-averse workers are more likely to select fixed-wage contracts. High-ability workers prefer piece-rates.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5
Fig. 6

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Related papers exploit laboratory experiments to consider the risk-incentives trade-off from the point of view of the firm. Corgnet and Hernán-González (2020) and Chowdhury and Karakostas (2019) find that principals diminish incentives in risky settings.

  2. Other evidence supporting sorting on the basis of HL measured risk preferences is more indirect. For example, Bellemare and Shearer (2010) conducted HL lotteries on a sample of tree planters who were paid piece rates. They noted that tree planters had a higher risk tolerance, on average, than was reported by Dave et al. (2010) who used a more representative sample. The evidence that we present adds to these studies, allowing for a direct test of sorting since we measure the risk preferences and observe the contract choices for the same set of workers. By applying the HL lotteries and the contract-choice experiments to the same sample, we can link the contracts chosen to individual risk preferences.

  3. Dohmen and Falk (2011) state: “An interesting question is whether the sorting patterns that we observe in the lab generalize qualitatively to labor markets outside the lab.” (Cadsby, Song, and Tapon, 2007) also address the issue and finish their paper stating: “Future research should explore the effectiveness of such mechanisms and their interactions with various forms of pay for performance in different organizational settings.”

  4. Such heterogeneity has been noted in other contexts as well; see, for example, (Bombardini and Trebbi, 2012) and Petrolia et al. (2013).

  5. Occasionally workers will be paid a fixed wage, if, for example, conditions on a block are very poor or a block is unexpectedly added to a contract; see Paarsch and Shearer (2000) for a discussion.

  6. Firms are required by law to pay the British Columbia minimum wage. This involves topping up a worker’s earnings if the worker does not plant enough trees to earn the minimum wage. Workers who are consistently incapable of doing so are fired.

  7. The firm is subject to fines if government inspections uncover too many poorly planted trees.

  8. The firm periodically moves workers between crews if and when more workers are needed in a given area. These decisions were taken by upper management and were independent of worker performance during the experiment.

  9. A complete description of the experimental protocol is available in the Supplementary file "Appendix 2".

  10. All of the planters working in the firm at the visited locations were invited to participate. They were compensated $20 for their time, typically 20-25 minutes. All of the planters agreed to participate.

  11. Workers did not know that the lottery would be repeated at higher stakes when they were participating in the LS lottery.

  12. Participants in the lotteries were aware that there would be a second experiment in which they could influence the manner in which they were paid. However the exact nature of the contract-choice experiment (including the contracts that would be offered) was not known.

  13. The low number of inconsistent responses is possibly due to the highly educated workforce. As noted in Section 5.2, over 85% of the workers in our sample have some university education and over 65% have a university degree. This contrasts with studies such as Jacobson and Petrie (2009) where participants had an average of primary education or Dave et al. (2010) where only 11% of participants had a post-secondary education.

  14. The decision sheets, along with a complete presentation of the experimental protocol, are presented in Supplementary file "Appendix 2".

  15. The small number of participants in each session and the close proximity of the researcher during the experiment, minimised opportunities for discussion during the experiment and the possibility of peers affecting choices.

  16. A complete presentation of the experimental protocol is provided in Supplementary file "Appendix 1".

  17. The reader should be aware that this may introduce some ambiguity into the risky contract.

  18. A worker who did not want to be paid under fixed wages could simply choose his/her regular piece rate at each decision.

  19. The worker’s choices are said to be consistent if he/she switches only once from lottery A to lottery B.

  20. Discussions with this worker revealed that he/she would have chosen the fixed-wage contract only if the guaranteed wage was greater than $700.

  21. We only use observations for which earnings are greater than the minimum wage of $83.6 in British Columbia. This excludes planters who only worked part of a day.

  22. See Shearer (2004) for a discussion of this point.

  23. The test was conducted using the signrank command in Stata. The Kolmogorov-Smirnov test also failed to reject the null hypothesis that the distributions were identical.

  24. Restricting the sample to workers who made consistent choices in both lotteries had no effect on the results.

  25. The reader should be aware that other interpretations of the changing responses are possible. Changing risk preferences (Holt and Laury, 2002; Bombardini and Trebbi, 2012) is one possibility, although it is not clear why the risk preferences measured in the HS lottery would be more relevant for predicting contract choices than those from the LS lottery (see Section 7, below). Order effects (Harrison, Johnson, McInnes, and Rutström, 2006) could also be present. While we do not rule these out, we note that earnings from the LS lottery have no predictive power over HS lottery choices. The coefficient on earnings in the LS lottery is statistically insignificant in a regression explaining the number of safe choices in the HS lottery. The p-value is over 0.6. It is also possible that individual’s strategies evolved as they learned about how to play the lottery. Many experimental studies include preliminary practice rounds to allow participants to learn. (Lusk and Shogren (2007) provide a discussion of the benefits of this in the experimental auctions literature). Again, while we do not rule this out, we note that a natural measure of learning is comparing the number of mistakes (or inconsistent choices) that were made in filling out the lottery sheet. In our case, the number of inconsistent choices was negligible in both LS lottery and HS lottery, suggesting that learning was not a primary consideration. Another possiblity is that participants took the lottery more seriously at higher stakes. Levitt and List (2007b) argue that as stakes rise, monetary considerations take a more prominent place in individuals’ utility functions, affecting experimental responses.

  26. The results are qualitatively the same if we use average daily earnings to measure ability.

  27. Below, we exploit the ORIV methods, developed by Gillen et al. (2019), to control for measurement error. Following their suggestion, we standardarize the regression variables by subtracting off their mean and dividing by their standard deviation. For comparability, we use the same standardized variables in all regressions reported in Table 8.

  28. The results are qualitatively the same if we include this worker in our sample, although slightly less significant. For example, the coefficient on safe choices in the modified ORIV regression in Table 8 remains negative and statistically significant at the 10% level of significance with a p-value of 0.068.

  29. Including worker characteristics, such as age, gender, experience, tenure and education, had no significant effect on the regression results.

  30. Measurment error in explanatory variables causes OLS estimators to be biased towards zero; see, for example (Davidson and MacKinnon, 2004).

  31. This is similar to arguments over the relative importance of ability bias and measurement error in determining OLS estimates of the returns to schooling. Applying instrumental variables to those models often led to larger estimates of the return to schooling. This caused many researchers to doubt the relative importance ability bias; see Card (1999) for a detailed discussion.

  32. We received a number of comments from the participants during the HS lottery expressing how much more exited and nervous they were in drawing their chips. While anecdotal, this is consistent with participants taking this lottery more seriously.

References

  • Ackerberg, D. A., & Botticini, M. (2002). Endogenous matching and the empirical determinants of contract form. Journal of Political Economy, 110(3), 564–591.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Allen, D. W., & Lueck, D. (1999). The role of risk in contract choice. Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization, 15(3), 704–736.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Andersen, S., Harrison, G. W., Lau, M. I., & Rutström, E. E. (2008). Eliciting risk and time preferences. Econometrica, 76(3), 583–618.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bago, J.-L., & Shearer, B. (2020). Risk preferences and contract choices. CRREP Working Paper 2020-15.

  • Bellemare, C., & Shearer, B. (2010). Sorting, incentives and risk preferences: Evidence from a field experiment. Economics Letters, 108(3), 345–348.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bellemare, C., & Shearer, B. (2013). Multidimensional heterogeneity and the economic importance of risk and matching: Evidence from contractual data and field experiments. The RAND Journal of Economics, 44(2), 361–389.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Belzil, C., & Sidibé, M. (2016). Internal and external validity of experimental risk and time preferences. Working paper IZA, 10348.

  • Binswanger, H. P. (1980). Attitudes toward risk: Experimental measurement in Rural India. American Journal of Agricultural Economics, 62(3), 395–407.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bombardini, M., & Trebbi, F. (2012). Risk aversion and expected utility theory: An experiment with large and small stakes. Journal of the European Economic Association, 10(6), 1348–1399.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cadsby, C. B., Song, F., & Tapon, F. (2007). Sorting and incentive effects of pay for performance: An experimental investigation. The Academy of Management Journal, 50(2), 387–405.

    Google Scholar 

  • Camerer, C. (2015). The promise and success of lab—field generalizability in experimental economics: A critical reply to levitt and list. In G. Fréchette & A. Schotter (Eds.), Handbook of Experimental Economic Methodology, 362.

  • Card, D. (1999). The causal effect of education on earnings. In O. Ashenfelter & D. Card (Eds.), Handbook of Labor Economics (Vol. 3, pp. 1801–1863). Elsevier.

    Google Scholar 

  • Charness, G., Garcia, T., Offerman, T., & Villeval, M. C. (2020). Do measures of risk attitude in the laboratory predict behavior under risk in and outside of the laboratory? Journal of Risk and Insurance, 60(2), 99–123.

    Google Scholar 

  • Charness, G., Gneezy, U., & Imas, A. (2013). Experimental methods: Eliciting risk preferences. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 87, 43–51.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chowdhury, S. M., & Karakostas, A. (2019). An experimental investigation of the ‘tenuous trade-off’ between risk and incentives in organizations. Theory and Decision, 88(1), 1096–1114.

    Google Scholar 

  • Corgnet, B., & Hernán-González, R. (2020). Revisiting the trade-off between risk and incentives: The shocking effect of random shocks? Theory and Decision, 65(3), 153–190.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dave, C., Eckel, C., Johnson, C., & Rojas, C. (2010). Eliciting risk preferences: When is simple better? Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 87, 219–243.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Davidson, R., & MacKinnon, J. G. (2004). Econometric Theory and Methods. Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dohmen, T., & Falk, A. (2011). Performance pay and multidimensional sorting: Productivity, preferences, and gender. The American Economic Review, 101(2), 556–590.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dohmen, T., Falk, A., Huffman, D., & Sunde, U. (2010). Are risk aversion and impatience related to cognitive ability? American Economic Review, 100(June), 1238–1260.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dohmen, T., Falk, A., Huffman, D., Sunde, U., Schupp, J., & Wagner, G. G. (2011). Individual risk attitudes: Measurement, determinants, and behavioral consequences. Journal of the European Economic Association, 9(3), 522–550.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Falk, A., & Heckman, J. (2009). Lab experiments are a major source of knowledge in the social sciences. Science, 362, 535–538.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ferrall, C., & Shearer, B. (1999). Incentives and transactions costs within the firm: Estimating an agency model usingpayroll records. Review of Economic Studies, 66, 309–338.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gayle, G.-L., & Miller, R. A. (2015). Identifying and testing models of managerial compensation. Review of Economic Studies, 82, 1074–1118.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gillen, B., Snowberg, E., & Yariv, L. (2019). Experimenting with measurement error: Techniques with applications to the caltech cohort study. Journal of Political Economy, 127(4), 1826–1863.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gneezy, U., & List, J. A. (2006). Putting behavioral economics to work: Testing for gift exchange in laobr markets using field experiments. Econometrica, 74, 1365–1384.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hardeweg, B., Menkhoff, L., & Wabel, H. (2013). Experimentally validated survey evidence on individual risk attitudes in rural Thailand. Economic Development and Cultural Change, 61(4), 859–888.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Harrison, G. W., Johnson, E., McInnes, M. M., & Rutström, E. E. (2006). Risk aversion and incentive effects: Comment. American Economic Review, 95(3), 897–901.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Harrison, G. W., & List, J. A. (2004). Field experiments. Journal of Economic Literature, 42(4), 1009–1055.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Holmstrom, B. (1979). Moral hazard and observability. Bell Journal of Economics, 10(1), 74–91.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Holt, C. A., & Laury, S. K. (2002). Risk aversion and incentive effects. The American Economic Review, 92(5), 1644–1655.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jacobson, S., & Petrie, R. (2009). Learning from mistakes: What do inconsistent choices over risk tell us? Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 38(2), 143–158.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jin, J., & Wang, X. (2020). Farmers‘ risk preferences and agricultural weather index insurance uptake in rural China. International Journal of Disaster Risk Science, 7(4), 366–373.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lazear, E. P. (1986). Salaries and piece rates. The Journal of Business, 59(3), 405–431.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lazear, E. P. (2000). Performance pay and productivity. The American Economic Review, 90(5), 1346–1361.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Levitt, S., & List, J. A. (2007). Viewpoint: On the generalizability of lab behaviour to the field. Canadian Journal of Economics, 40(2), 347–370.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Levitt, S., & List, J. A. (2007). What do laboratory experiments measuring social preferences reveal about the real world? Journal of Economic Perspectives, 21(2), 153–174.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lusk, J. L., & Coble, K. H. (2005). Risk perceptions, risk preference, and acceptance of risky food. American Journal of Agricultural Economics, 87(2), 393–405.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lusk, J. L., & Shogren, J. F. (2007). Experimental Auctions: Methods and Applications in Economic and Marketing Research. Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Macleod, W. B., & Malcomson, J. M. (1989). Implicit contracts, incentive compatibility, and involuntary unemployment. Econometrica, 57(2), 447–480.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Paarsch, H. J., & Shearer, B. (2000). Piece rates, fixed wages, and incentive effects: Statistical evidence from payroll records. International Economic Review, 41(1), 59–92.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Paarsch, H. J., & Shearer, B. S. (1999). The response of worker effort to piece rates: Evidence from the British Columbia tree-planting industry. Journal of Human Resources, 643–667.

  • Petrolia, D., Landry, C., & Coble, K. (2013). Risk preferences, risk perceptions and flood insurance. Land Economics, 89(2), 227–245.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pratt, J. W. (1964). Risk aversion in the small and in the large. Econometrica, 32, 122–136.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Prendergast, C. (1999). The provision of incentives in firms. Journal of Economic Literature, 37(1), 7–63.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Prendergast, C. (2000). What trade-off of risk and incentives? The American Economic Review, 90(2), 421–425.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shapiro, C., & Stiglitz, J. E. (1984). Equilibrium unemployment as a worker discipline device. American Economic Review, 74(3), 433–444.

    Google Scholar 

  • Shearer, B. (2004). Piece rates, fixed wages and incentives: Evidence from a field experiment. The Review of Economic Studies, 71(2), 513–534.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stiglitz, J. E. (1975). Incentives, risk, and information: Notes towards a theory of hierarchy. Bell Journal of Economics, 6(2), 552–579.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Bruce Shearer.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

We thank Roberto Weber, Marie Claire Villeval and two anonymous referees for their helpful comments and suggestions. We also thank Sylvain Dessy, Claude-Denis Fluet, Bernard Fortin, Sonia Laszlo, and Luca Tiberti, as well as participants at the the Societé canadienne des sciences économiques (Ottawa, 2017) and the Canadian Economic Association Meetings (McGill, 2018). Financial support from SSHRC (Shearer), FRQSC (Shearer) and CRREP (Bago) is gratefully acknowledged. The replication material for this study is available at https://osf.io/vewp9.

Supplementary Information

Below is the link to the electronic supplementary material.

Supplementary file 1 (PDF 123 KB)

Rights and permissions

Springer Nature or its licensor holds exclusive rights to this article under a publishing agreement with the author(s) or other rightsholder(s); author self-archiving of the accepted manuscript version of this article is solely governed by the terms of such publishing agreement and applicable law.

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Bago, JL., Shearer, B. Risk preferences and contract choices. Exp Econ 25, 1374–1398 (2022). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10683-022-09768-5

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Revised:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10683-022-09768-5

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation