Skip to main content
Log in

The determinants of multilateral bargaining: a comprehensive analysis of Baron and Ferejohn majoritarian bargaining experiments

  • Original Paper
  • Published:
Experimental Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

We analyze the data sets of all majoritarian Baron and Ferejohn (Am Political Sci Rev 83(4):1181–1206, 1989) experiments through 2018. By exploiting the variation of the experimental parameters, we are able to identify how group size, discount factor (cost of agreement delay), voting weights, and communication affect bargaining outcomes and dynamics. The outcomes are qualitatively in line with the stationary subgame perfect equilibrium, i.e., minimum winning coalitions are modal; proposers demand larger shares than non-proposers; and most agreements are reached without delay. Experience and communication between players move outcomes closer to the equilibrium. However, bargaining dynamics are not stationary. Behavior following a disagreement is history-dependent in the form of retaliation towards failed proposers and their supporters, which, if rationally expected, may deter proposers from demanding high shares.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. In this article, we focus on the closed amendment rule that has received wide attention. A version of the model where another player must agree to move a proposal for a vote is not discussed here.

  2. We include treatments that yield symmetric predictions and in which the funds to be distributed are exogenous in our analysis. We also incorporate treatments that allow for costless communication.

  3. We have three group sizes, communication treatments, and six discount factors from 0.5 to 1, for a total of 10 treatments. Not all combinations of discounting, group sizes, and communication have been investigated. We explain our sample and selection criteria in Sect. 3.

  4. Exceptions are Fréchette et al., (2005b) who report no evidence of retaliation for previous proposers and Bradfield and Kagel (2015) who report that teams discuss retaliation and act on it.

  5. See Section 3.1 in Norman (2002).

  6. See Section 3 in the Online Appendix for a study-by-study explanation of which treatments were included.

  7. In the body of the paper we focus on multilevel random effects models. Our results are robust to clustering at the study level and having only subject random effects.

  8. This only holds for \(\delta \in (0,1]\), not for \(\delta =0\).

  9. See, for example, how the proposer’s share increases with experience in Figure 3 of Fréchette et al., (2003), Figure 1 in both Agranov and Tergiman (2014) and Baranski and Kagel (2015), and Table 6 in Miller and Vanberg (2015).

  10. We are especially grateful to the anonymous referees who offered valuable insights regarding the sample selection for regression analysis.

  11. In Table 1 of the Online Appendix we conduct the same regressions focusing only on treatments without communication and the results remain.

  12. In further regression analysis that we conduct below, we find that discounting starts to have the equilibrium predicted effect on behavior as subjects gain experience.

  13. Recall that, in our sample of analysis, some experiments have asymmetric weights yet all predict symmetric expected values, thus the proposer’s share should be independent of them according to the SSPE.

  14. The net effect of \(\delta\) on the proposer’s share becomes significantly negative after period 13 in groups of 3 and period 11 in groups of 5 (Wald tests yield p=0.083 and p=0.078, respectively).

  15. It is 60.1 percent of all round 1 proposals, 60.2 of accepted proposals.

  16. An equal split is defined as a division of the pie in which each member’s share is within 5 percentage points of \(\frac{1}{\text {Group Size}}\).

  17. For consistency with our previous estimations, we initially conducted a mixed effects probit regression with study, but we reject this specification in favor of the OLS model (L.R. test, p-value>0.1). The variance estimates were not significant at conventional levels and the intra-class correlation coefficients were below 5 percent in each cluster level.

  18. The reason we estimate OLS regressions is because we were unable to estimate probit regression models for groups of 5 due to lack of convergence in the maximization of the likelihood function. We attempted several integration methods and parameters, but could not obtain convergence. Probit model estimations for all other cases lead to similar conclusions to those obtained from the linear probability models shown here.

  19. In treatments with communication, there are only 6 observations in groups of 3 and 9 observations in groups of 5 thus we cannot conduct a separate analysis.

  20. The p-values are obtained from linear regressions clustering at the study level controlling for experience.

  21. A similar result holds when focusing on whether a member is included or excluded from the coalition. See Figure 1 in the Online Appendix.

References

  • Adams, J. S. (1965). Inequity in social exchange. In Advances in experimental social psychology (Vol. 2, pp. 267–299). Elsevier.

  • Agranov, M. (2020). Legislative bargaining experiments. Private communication with the author. To appear in “Bargaining: Current Research and Future Directions” edited by Emin Karagozoglu and Kyle Hyndman

  • Agranov, M., & Tergiman, C. (2014). Communication in multilateral bargaining. Journal of Public Economics, 118, 75–85.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baranski, A. (2016). Voluntary contributions and collective redistribution. American Economic Journal: Microeconomics, 8(4), 149–73.

    Google Scholar 

  • Baranski, A., & Kagel, J. H. (2015). Communication in legislative bargaining. Journal of the Economic science Association, 1(1), 59–71.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baron, D. P., & Ferejohn, J. A. (1989). Bargaining in legislatures. American political science review, 83(4), 1181–1206.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bolton, G. E., & Ockenfels, A. (2000). Erc: A theory of equity, reciprocity, and competition. American Economic Review, 90(1), 166–193.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bradfield, A. J., & Kagel, J. H. (2015). Legislative bargaining with teams. Games and Economic Behavior, 93, 117–127.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Diermeier, D., & Gailmard, S. (2006). Self-interest, inequality, and entitlement in majoritarian decision-making. Quarterly Journal of Political Science, 1(4), 327–350.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Diermeier, D., & Morton, R. (2005). Experiments in majoritarian bargaining. Social choice and strategic decisions (pp. 201–226). Springer.

  • Drouvelis, M., Montero, M., & Sefton, M. (2010). Gaining power through enlargement: Strategic foundations and experimental evidence. Games and Economic Behavior, 69(2), 274–292.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Eraslan, H., & Evdokimov, K. S. (2019). Legislative and multilateral bargaining. Annual Review of Economics, 11(1), 443–472.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fehr, E., & Schmidt, K. M. (1999). A theory of fairness, competition, and cooperation. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 114(3), 817–868.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fréchette, G., Kagel, J. H., & Morelli, M. (2005a). Behavioral identification in coalitional bargaining: An experimental analysis of demand bargaining and alternating offers. Econometrica, 73(6), 1893–1937.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fréchette, G., Kagel, J. H., & Morelli, M. (2005b). Nominal bargaining power, selection protocol, and discounting in legislative bargaining. Journal of Public Economics, 89(8), 1497–1517.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fréchette, G. R., Kagel, J. H., & Lehrer, S. F. (2003). Bargaining in legislatures: An experimental investigation of open versus closed amendment rules. American Political Science Review, 97(2), 221–232.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fréchette, G. R., & Vespa, E. (2017). The determinants of voting in multilateral bargaining games. Journal of the Economic Science Association, 3(1), 26–43.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Harrington, J. E. (1990). The role of risk preferences in bargaining when acceptance of a proposal requires less than unanimous approval. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 3(2), 135–154.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kagel, J. H., Sung, H., & Winter, E. (2010). Veto power in committees: an experimental study. Experimental Economics, 13(2), 167–188.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Maaser, N., Paetzel, F., & Traub, S. (2019). Power illusion in coalitional bargaining: An experimental analysis. Games and Economic Behavior, 117, 433–450.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McKelvey, R. D. (1991). An experimental test of a stochastic game model of committee bargaining. In T. R. Palfrey (Ed.), Contemporary Laboratory Research in Political Economy. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Miller, L., Montero, M., & Vanberg, C. (2018). Legislative bargaining with heterogeneous disagreement values: Theory and experiments. Games and Economic Behavior, 107, 60–92.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Miller, L., & Vanberg, C. (2013). Decision costs in legislative bargaining: An experimental analysis. Public Choice, 155(3–4), 373–394.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Miller, L., & Vanberg, C. (2015). Group size and decision rules in legislative bargaining. European Journal of Political Economy, 37, 288–302.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Montero, M. (2007). Inequity aversion may increase inequity. The Economic Journal, 117(519), C192–C204.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Morelli, M. (1999). Demand competition and policy compromise in legislative bargaining. American Political Science Review, 93(4), 809–820.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Norman, P. (2002). Legislative bargaining and coalition formation. Journal of Economic Theory, 102(2), 322–353.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nunnari, S., & Zapal, J. (2016). Gambler’s fallacy and imperfect best response in legislative bargaining. Games and Economic Behavior, 99, 275–294.

  • Palfrey, T. R. (2016). Experiments in political economy. In J. H. Kagel & A. E. Roth (Eds.), The Handbook of Experimental Economics (Vol. 2, pp. 347–434). Princeton University Press, Princeton.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tversky, A., & Kahneman, D. (1974). Judgment under uncertainty: Heuristics and biases. Science, 185(4157), 1124–1131.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgement

We would like to thank Marina Agranov, Anthony Bradfield, Daniel Diermeier, Guillaume Frechette, Sean Gailmard, Tanushree Jhunjhunwala, John H. Kagel, Luis Miller, Maria Montero, Hankyoung Sung, and Chloe Tergiman for kindly sharing their data sets and explaining their structure in detail to us. Without their help, it would been impossible to write this article. Sima Basel and Luis Quesada offered excellent research assistance. We are also grateful for the valuable comments provided by participants at the 4th Bargaining Experiments, Empirics, and Theory (BEET) workshop, Olivier Bochet, Simon Siegenthaler, as well as the generous guidance provided by the Editor, Roberto Weber, and two anonymous referees. Baranski gratefully recognizes financial support by Tamkeen under the NYU Abu Dhabi Research Institute Award CG005. All errors remain our own.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Andrzej Baranski.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Supplementary Information

Below is the link to the electronic supplementary material.

Supplementary file 1 (pdf 241 kb)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Baranski, A., Morton, R. The determinants of multilateral bargaining: a comprehensive analysis of Baron and Ferejohn majoritarian bargaining experiments. Exp Econ 25, 1079–1108 (2022). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10683-021-09734-7

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Revised:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10683-021-09734-7

Navigation