Skip to main content
Log in

The coordinating power of social norms

  • Original Paper
  • Published:
Experimental Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

A popular empirical technique to measure norms uses coordination games to elicit what subjects in an experiment consider appropriate behavior in a given situation (Krupka and Weber in J Eur Econ Assoc 11(3):495–524, 2013). The Krupka–Weber method works under the assumption that subjects use their normative expectations to solve the coordination game. However, subjects might use alternative focal points to coordinate, in which case the method may deliver distorted measurements of the social norm. We test the vulnerability of the Krupka–Weber method to the presence of alternative salient focal points in two series of experiments with more than 3000 subjects. We find that the method is robust, especially when there are clear normative expectations about what constitutes appropriate behavior.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Institutional subscriptions

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. See Bicchieri (2006) for a discussion of the differences between social norms, moral norms and personal norms.

  2. All experiments were programmed using the software LIONESS (Giamattei et al., 2020).

  3. In the instructions we explicitly told subjects that the other participants they were trying to coordinate with were other AMT workers from the US who were completing the same task, using the same decision screen as the subject. See Appendix A in the Online Supplemental Materials (OSM) for the instructions used in the study.

  4. We find no difference between T4 and T5 (p = 0.489), or between T1 and T2 (p = 0.253). We find significant differences between T3 and both T1 and T2 (p = 0.011 in either case). Throughout the paper we report p-values corrected for multiple comparisons using the false discovery rate procedure described in Simes (1986) and Benjamini and Hochberg (1995). In the case of the two pilot experiments, we correct for the fact that there are 10 possible bilateral comparisons between the 5 treatments.

  5. In the analysis below we will adjust p-values for multiple hypothesis testing (44 tests in total). To take this into account in the power analysis, we performed a conservative version of our power calculations with α = (0.05/44) = 0.001 and find that the minimum detectable effect size for each comparison is 0.37.

  6. We focus on data from the baseline KW treatment, instead of the treatments with visual labels, because the visual labels affect the heterogeneity of ratings. Thus, the baseline KW treatment offers a cleaner benchmark for the degree of normative consensus about the different actions in the game.

  7. There is one exception: we introduced an attention check in the experimental software to improve the quality of responses. The check was positioned after the decision-making part of the experiment. We exclude from the analysis observations that do not pass the check (78 subjects). Results are unchanged if we do not exclude these subjects.

  8. As in Study 1, we will adjust p values for multiple hypothesis testing (55 tests in total). A more conservative power analysis that takes this into account shows that the minimum detectable effect size for each comparison is 0.26.

  9. In theory, the presence of alternative focal points may confound the elicitation of norms without resulting in dispersed ratings, for instance if the alternative focal point is sufficiently strong to sway a large majority of subjects to use it as a coordination device in the Krupka–Weber task. Empirically, we do not think that this is very plausible given that in our experiment we still observe dispersion in the Krupka–Weber ratings for the overgenerous actions even when we introduce very salient alternative focal points in the task.

References

  • Bacharach, M., & Bernasconi, M. (1997). The variable frame theory of focal points: An experimental study. Games and Economic Behavior, 19(1), 1–45

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Banerjee, R. (2016). On the interpretation of bribery in a laboratory corruption game: Moral frames and social norms. Experimental Economics, 19(1), 240–267

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bardsley, N., Mehta, J., Starmer, C., & Sugden, R. (2010). Explaining focal points: Cognitive hierarchy theory versus team reasoning*. The Economic Journal, 120(543), 40–79

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barr, A., Lane, T., & Nosenzo, D. (2018). On the social appropriateness of discrimination. Journal of Public Economics, 164, 153–164

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Benjamini, Y., & Hochberg, Y. (1995). Controlling the false discovery rate: A practical and powerful approach to multiple testing. Journal of the Royal Statistical Society Series B (Methodological), 57(1), 289–300

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bicchieri, C. (2006). The grammar of society: The nature and dynamics of social norms. Cambridge University Press.

  • Bicchieri, C., Dimant, E., Gaechter, S., & Nosenzo, D. (2019). Observability, social proximity, and the erosion of norm compliance. SSRN discussion paper 3355028. Rochester, NY.

  • Burks, S. V., & Krupka, E. (2012). A multimethod approach to identifying norms and normative expectations within a corporate hierarchy: Evidence from the financial services industry. Management Science, 58(1), 203–217

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bursztyn, L., González, A. L., & Yanagizawa-Drott, D. (2020). Misperceived social norms: Women working outside the home in Saudi Arabia. American Economic Review, 110(10), 2997–3029

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Butler, J., Giuliano, P., & Guiso, L. (2016). Trust and cheating. The Economic Journal, 126(595), 1703–1738

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chang, D., Chen, R., & Krupka, E. (2019). Rhetoric matters: A social norms explanation for the anomaly of framing. Games and Economic Behavior, 116, 158–178

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Charness, G., & Sontuoso, A. (2019). The doors of perception. Working paper https://digitalcommons.chapman.edu/esi_working_papers/292/

  • Crawford, V. P., Gneezy, U., & Rottenstreich, Y. (2008). The power of focal points is limited: Even minute payoff asymmetry may yield large coordination failures. American Economic Review, 98(4), 1443–1458

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • d’Adda, G., Darai, D., Pavanini, N., & Weber, R. A. (2017). Do Leaders affect ethical conduct? Journal of the European Economic Association, 15(6), 1177–1213

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • d’Adda, G., Dufwenberg, M., Passarelli, F., & Tabellini, G. (2020). Social norms with private values: Theory and experiments. Games and Economic Behavior, 124, 288–304

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Erkut, H., Nosenzo, D., & Sefton, M. (2015). Identifying social norms using coordination games: Spectators vs stakeholders. Economics Letters, 130, 28–31

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fehr, E., & Schurtenberger, I. (2018). Normative foundations of human cooperation. Nature Human Behaviour, 2(7), 458–468

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gächter, S., Gerhards, L., & Nosenzo, D. (2017). The importance of peers for compliance with norms of fair sharing. European Economic Review, 97(C), 72–86

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gächter, S., Molleman, L., & Nosenzo, D. (2021). When and why people follow rules. Working paper under preparation.

  • Gächter, S., Nosenzo, D., & Sefton, M. (2013). Peer effects in pro-social behavior: Social norms or social preferences? Journal of the European Economic Association, 11(3), 548–573

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gangadharan, L., Jain, T., Maitra, P., & Vecci, J. (2016). Social identity and governance: The behavioral response to female leaders. European Economic Review, 90, 302–325

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Giamattei, M., Yahosseini, K. S., Gächter, S., & Molleman, L. (2020). LIONESS Lab: A free web-based platform for conducting interactive experiments online. Journal of the Economic Science Association, 6(1), 95–111

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Guala, F., & Mittone, L. (2010). How history and convention create norms: An experimental study. Journal of Economic Psychology, 31(4), 749–756

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hargreaves Heap, S., Arjona, D. R., & Sugden, R. (2014). How portable is level-0 behavior? A Test of level-k theory in games with non-neutral frames. Econometrica, 82(3), 1133–1151

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • He, S., & Wu, J. (2020). Compromise and coordination: An experimental study. Games and Economic Behavior, 119, 216–233

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Holm, H. J. (2000). Gender-based focal points. Games and Economic Behavior, 32(2), 292–314

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Isoni, A., Poulsen, A., Sugden, R., & Tsutsui, K. (2013). Focal points in tacit bargaining problems: Experimental evidence. European Economic Review, 59, 167–188

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Isoni, A., Poulsen, A., Sugden, R., & Tsutsui, K. (2019). Focal points and payoff information in tacit bargaining. Games and Economic Behavior, 114, 193–214

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kimbrough, E. O., & Vostroknutov, A. (2016). Norms make preferences social. Journal of the European Economic Association, 14, 608–638

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kimbrough, E. O., & Vostroknutov, A. (2018). A portable method of eliciting respect for social norms. Economics Letters, 168, 147–150

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Krupka, E., Leider, S., & Jiang, M. (2017). A meeting of the minds: Informal agreements and social norms. Management Science, 63(6), 1657–2048

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Krupka, E., & Weber, R. A. (2009). The focusing and informational effects of norms on pro-social behavior. Journal of Economic Psychology, 30(3), 307–320

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Krupka, E., & Weber, R. A. (2013). Identifying social norms using coordination games: Why does dictator game sharing vary? Journal of the European Economic Association, 11(3), 495–524

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lewis, D. (1969). Convention: A philosophical study. Blackwell.

  • Maniadis, Z., Tufano, F., & List, J. A. (2014). One swallow doesn’t make a summer: New evidence on anchoring effects. American Economic Review, 104(1), 277–290

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mehta, J., Starmer, C., & Sugden, R. (1994a). Focal points in pure coordination games—An experimental investigation. Theory and Decision, 36(2), 163–185

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mehta, J., Starmer, C., & Sugden, R. (1994b). The nature of salience—An experimental investigation of pure coordination games. American Economic Review, 84(3), 658–673

    Google Scholar 

  • Nikiforakis, N., Oechssler, J., & Shah, A. (2014). Hierarchy, coercion, and exploitation: An experimental analysis. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 97, 155–168

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ostrom, E. (2000). Collective action and the evolution of social norms. The Journal of Economic Perspectives, 14(3), 137–158

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Parravano, M., & Poulsen, O. (2015). Stake size and the power of focal points in coordination games: Experimental evidence. Games and Economic Behavior, 94, 191–199

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Reuben, E., & Riedl, A. (2013). Enforcement of contribution norms in public good games with heterogeneous populations. Games and Economic Behavior, 77(1), 122–137

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schelling, T. (1960). The strategy of conflict. Harvard University Press.

  • Schram, A., & Charness, G. (2015). Inducing social norms in laboratory allocation choices. Management Science, 61(7), 1531–1546

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Simes, R. J. (1986). An improved Bonferroni procedure for multiple tests of significance. Biometrika, 73(3), 751–754

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sitzia, S., & Zheng, J. (2019). Group behaviour in tacit coordination games with focal points—An experimental investigation. Games and Economic Behavior, 117, 461–478

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sugden, R. (1986). The economics of rights, co-operation and welfare. (2005th ed.). Palgrave Macmillan.

Download references

Acknowledgements

We received helpful comments from the Editor Lata Gangadharan, two anonymous referees, Abigail Barr, Zvonimir Bašić, Georgia Michailidou, Adriaan Soetevent and Bob Sugden. We acknowledge funding from the Luxembourg Institute of Socio-Economic Research (LISER) and the Aarhus University Research Foundation (AUFF Starting Grant 36835).

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Daniele Nosenzo.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Supplementary Information

Below is the link to the electronic supplementary material.

Supplementary file1 (DOCX 2273 KB)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Fallucchi, F., Nosenzo, D. The coordinating power of social norms. Exp Econ 25, 1–25 (2022). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10683-021-09717-8

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Revised:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10683-021-09717-8

Keywords

JEL Classificatios

Navigation