If you’re helping someone and expecting something in return, you’re doing business not kindness.
Unknown.
Abstract
Reciprocity has been shown to be sensitive to perceived intentions, however, not much is known about the intensity of reciprocal responses to the precise nature of those intentions. For example, a person can strategically appear to be kind while being self-serving or can be selflessly (genuinely) kind. Do these two intentions elicit different reciprocal reactions? We propose a conjecture that self-serving but generous actions diminish the positively reciprocal response, compared to selfless generous actions. We classify actions that increase a recipient’s maximum payoff, but by less than the giver’s maximum payoff, as being self-serving generous actions, while classifying actions that increase a recipient’s maximum payoff by more than the giver’s as selfless generous actions. We hypothesize that selfless generous actions are considered more generous than self-serving generous actions, and that self-serving generous actions will therefore result in a diminished reciprocal response. We test this conjecture using two novel experimental designs. We find some evidence that subjects perceive self-serving generous actions as being less generous than selfless generous actions, but no empirical support for our conjecture on the diminished reciprocal response.
Similar content being viewed by others
Notes
As will become clearer in our design the strategic element stems from the fact that the FMs can receive more back than their outside option. This is possible in all our treatments; in our self-serving treatments, more people will be taking the action for strategic reasons as it is more feasible that they will receive back more.
Other shortcomings and limitations of belief-dependent models of reciprocity are discussed in Hinz and Nicklisch (2015) who explore the continuity of the reference value [employed by Rabin (1993) and Dufwenberg and Kirchsteiger (2004)] and the continuity of the intention factor (Falk and Fischbacher 2006) in a series of mini-ultimatum games. They find that the distance of the observed offers to the proposed reference value provides a poor measure for their kindness and that a pairwise comparison of offers à la Falk and Fischbacher’s model cannot explain behavior in richer settings.
What definition best approximates self-serving generosity under what circumstances is an interesting empirical question in its own right; however, we leave such explorations for future research.
SMs can spend the entirety of the amount they are sent by the FM, but are limited in not reducing the FM’s final payoff below zero.
The theory is general (N players), however, the two player case is presented for ease of explanation. We present the theory in its original version, where ‘me’ represents the SM and ‘you’ the FM.
\(A_{X}\) is the preference ordering after observing the action that creates opportunity set X, where X \(\in\) C.
In Dufwenberg and Gneezy (2000), x took the values of 4, 7, 10, 13, and 16. In our experiment we chose x = 4 for replication purposes, and x = − 2 as it was the first negative instance counting down in steps of three from x = 4.
A power analysis is presented in Appendix E of the ESM.
Minimum wage in New Zealand was NZ$13.50 per hour at the time of the experiments.
We adopt a conservative approach and report 2-sided tests throughout the paper.
A Mann–Whitney test on pooled data from both FMs and SMs reports p = .007.
See also Woods and Servátka (2016) for evidence of psychological forward induction and the updating of beliefs in the environment of the Lost Wallet Game.
Note the deliberate similarity to the Investment Game, where amounts invested by the FM are typically tripled for the SM to split.
CFS do not mention moves that are determined by chance, so we assume that MGT ordering is determined by the expected value of \(m_{G}^{*}\) and \(y_{G}^{*}\). Such an assumption seems natural and intuitive, and a similar approach is used by Sebald (2010) to extend Dufwenberg and Kirchsteiger (2004).
A power analysis is presented in Appendix E of the ESM.
Using pooled data of both FM and SM generosity perceptions, a Mann–Whitney test reports: for H4 p = .073; for H5 p = .035; and for H6 p = .536. Note that such an approach provides support for H5 and mild evidence in support of H4.
References
Andreoni, J., Harbaugh, W., & Vesterlund, L. (2003). The carrot or the stick: Rewards, punishments, and cooperation. American Economic Review, 93(3), 893–902.
Andreoni, J., & Miller, J. (2002). Giving according to GARP: An experimental test of the consistency of preferences for Altruism. Econometrica, 70(2), 737–753.
Bardsley, N. (2008). Dictator game giving: Altruism or artefact? Experimental Economics, 11(2), 122–133.
Berg, J., Dickhaut, J., & McCabe, K. (1995). Trust, reciprocity, and social history. Games and Economic Behavior, 10, 122–142.
Blount, S. (1995). When social outcomes aren’t fair: The effect of causal attributions on preferences. Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes, 63(2), 131–144.
Bolton, G. E., & Ockenfels, A. (2000). ERC: A theory of equity, reciprocity, and competition. American Economic Review, 90(1), 166–193.
Brandts, J., & Charness, G. (2011). The strategy versus the direct-response method: A first survey of experimental comparisons. Experimental Economics, 14, 375–398.
Bruni, L., Corazzini, L., & Stanca, L. (2009). Testing theories of reciprocity: Do motivations matter? Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 71(2), 233–245.
Camerer, C. F. (2003). Behavioral game theory: Experiments in strategic interaction. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
Cappelen, A. W., Nielsen, U. H., Sørensen, E. Ø., Tungodden, B., & Tyran, J.-R. (2013). Give and take in dictator games. Economic Letters, 118(2), 280–283.
Charness, G. B. (2004). Attribution and reciprocity in an experimental labor market. Journal of Labor Economics, 22(3), 665–688.
Charness, G., & Dufwenberg, M. (2006). Promises and partnership. Econometrica, 74(6), 1579–1601.
Chaudhuri, A. (2008). Experiments in economics: Playing fair with money. London: Routledge.
Cox, J. C. (2004). How to identify trust and reciprocity. Games and Economic Behavior, 46, 260–281.
Cox, J. C., & Deck, C. A. (2005). On the nature of reciprocal motives. Economic Inquiry, 43(3), 623–635.
Cox, J. C., & Deck, C. A. (2006). Assigning intentions when actions are unobservable: The impact of trembling in the trust game. Southern Economic Journal, 73(2), 307–314.
Cox, J. C., Friedman, D., & Gjerstad, S. (2007). A tractable model of reciprocity and fairness. Games and Economic Behavior, 59(1), 17–45.
Cox, J. C., Friedman, D., & Sadiraj, V. (2008a). Revealed Altruism. Econometrica, 76(1), 31–69.
Cox, J. C., List, J., Price, M., Sadiraj, V., & Samek, A. (2016). Moral costs and rational choice: Theory and experimental evidence. Working paper 2016.
Cox, J. C., Sadiraj, K., & Sadiraj, V. (2008b). Implications of trust, fear, and reciprocity for modelling economic behavior. Experimental Economics, 11(1), 1–24.
Cox, J. C., Servátka, M., & Vadovič, R. (2010). Saliency of outside options in the lost wallet game. Experimental Economics, 13(1), 66–74.
Cox, J. C., Servátka, M., & Vadovič, R. (2017). Status quo effects in fairness games: Reciprocal responses to acts of commission vs. acts of omission. Experimental Economics, 20, 1–18.
Dufwenberg, M., & Gneezy, U. (2000). Measuring beliefs in an experimental lost wallet game. Games and Economic Behavior, 30(2), 163–182.
Dufwenberg, M., & Kirchsteiger, G. (2004). A theory of sequential reciprocity. Games and Economic Behavior, 47(2), 268–298.
Dufwenberg, M., Servátka, M., & Vadovič, R. (2017). Honesty and informal agreements. Games and Economic Behavior, 102(2017), 269–285.
Falk, A., Fehr, E., & Fischbacher, U. (2008). Testing theories of fairness—Intentions matter. Games and Economic Behavior, 62(1), 287–303.
Falk, A., & Fischbacher, U. (2006). A theory of reciprocity. Games and Economic Behavior, 54(2), 293–315.
Fehr, E., & Gächter, S. (2000). Fairness and retaliation: The economics of reciprocity. The Journal of Economic Perspectives, 14(3), 159–181.
Fehr, E., & Schmidt, K. M. (1999). A theory of fairness, competition, and cooperation. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 114(3), 817–868.
Fehr, E., & Schmidt, K. M. (2006). The economics of fairness, reciprocity and Altruism—Experimental evidence and new theories. In S. Kolm & J. M. Ythier (Eds.), Handbook of the economics of giving, Altruism and reciprocity. Amsterdam: Elsevier.
Fischbacher, U. (2007). z-Tree: Zurich toolbox for ready-made economic experiments. Experimental Economics, 10(2), 171–178.
Gaechter, S., & Renner, E. (2010). The effects of (incentivized) belief elicitation in public goods experiments. Experimental Economics, 13(3), 364–377.
Gneezy, U., Güth, W., & Verboven, F. (2000). Presents or investments? An experimental analysis. Journal of Economic Psychology, 21(5), 481–493.
Greiner, B. (2015). Subject pool recruitment procedures: organizing experiments with ORSEE. Journal of the Economic Science Association, 1(1), 114–125.
Hinz, J., & Nicklisch, A. (2015). Reciprocity models revisited: Intention factors and reference value.Hamburg Wiso Working Paper Series 2015/25.
Johnson, N. D., & Mislin, A. A. (2011). Trust games: A meta-analysis. Journal of Economic Psychology, 32, 865–889.
Kritikos, A., & Bolle, F. (2004). Approaching fair behavior: Distributional and reciprocal preferences. Research on Economic Inequality, 11, 149–181.
Likert, R. (1932). A technique for the measurement of attitudes. Archives of Psychology, 22(140), 5–55.
McCabe, K., Rigdon, M., & Smith, V. (2003). Positive reciprocity and intentions in trust games. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 52, 267–275.
Offerman, T. (2002). Hurting hurts more than helping helps. European Economic Review, 46(8), 1423–1437.
Rabin, M. (1993). Incorporating fairness into game theory and economics. American Economic Review, 83(5), 1281–1302.
Schlag, K., Tremewan, J., & van der Weele, J. (2015). A penny for your thoughts: A survey of methods for eliciting beliefs. Experimental Economics, 18(3), 457–490.
Sebald, A. (2010). Attribution and reciprocity. Games and Economic Behavior, 68(1), 339–352.
Selten, R. (1967). Die Strategiemethode zur Erforshung des eingeschränkt rationalen Verhaltens im Rahmen eines Oligopolexperiments. In H. Sauermann (Ed.), Beiträge zur experimentellen Wirtschaftsforschung (pp. 136–168). Tübingen: Mohr.
Servátka, M., & Vadovič, R. (2009). Unequal outside options in the lost wallet game. Economics Bulletin, 29(4), 2870–2883.
Sobel, J. (2005). Interdependent preferences and reciprocity. Journal of Economic Literature, 43, 392–436.e.
Woods, D. (2013). Does self-serving generosity diminish reciprocal behaviour. (M.Com.), University of Canterbury, Christchurch.
Woods, D., & Servátka, M. (2016). Testing psychological forward induction and the updating of beliefs in the lost wallet game. Journal of Economic Psychology, 56, 116–125.
Acknowledgements
We would like to thank the editor Lata Gangadharan, Tim Cason, Jeremy Clark, Andreas Nicklisch, Vjollca Sadiraj, Daniel Schunk, Radovan Vadovič, and two anonymous referees for helpful comments, as well as participants of various conferences, workshops, and seminars where this work was presented. This paper is based on Daniel Woods’ Masters thesis written at the University of Canterbury (Woods 2013). Funding was provided by the College of Business and Economics, University of Canterbury and the Macquarie Graduate School of Management.
Author information
Authors and Affiliations
Corresponding author
Electronic supplementary material
Below is the link to the electronic supplementary material.
Rights and permissions
About this article
Cite this article
Woods, D., Servátka, M. Nice to you, nicer to me: Does self-serving generosity diminish the reciprocal response?. Exp Econ 22, 506–529 (2019). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10683-018-9561-8
Received:
Revised:
Accepted:
Published:
Issue Date:
DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10683-018-9561-8