Skip to main content
Log in

Individualism, collectivism, and trade

  • Original Paper
  • Published:
Experimental Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

While economists recognize the important role of formal institutions in the promotion of trade, there is increasing agreement that institutions are typically endogenous to culture, making it difficult to disentangle their separate contributions. Lab experiments that assign institutions exogenously and measure and control individual cultural characteristics can allow for clean identification of the effects of institutions, conditional on culture, and help us understand the relationship between behavior and culture, under a given institutional framework. We focus on cultural tendencies toward individualism/collectivism, which social psychologists highlight as an important determinant of many behavioral differences across groups and people. We design an experiment to explore the relationship between subjects’ degree of individualism/collectivism and their willingness to abandon a repeated, bilateral exchange relationship in order to seek potentially more lucrative trade with a stranger, under enforcement institutions of varying strength. Overall, we find that individualists tend to seek out trade more often than collectivists. A diagnostic treatment and additional analysis suggests that this difference may reflect both differential altruism/favoritism to in-group members and different reactions to having been cheated in the past. This difference is mitigated somewhat as the effectiveness of enforcement institutions increases. Nevertheless we see that cultural dispositions are associated with willingness to seek out trade, regardless of institutional environment.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5
Fig. 6
Fig. 7

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Triandis, in this book, coined the terms idiocentrism and allocentrism for individual-level analysis of individualism and collectivism. In this paper, however, we use the more familiar terms individualism and collectivism.

  2. The only exception to this that we’ve been able to find is a discussion of “holistic individualism” among followers of New Age religions (Farias and Lalljee 2008).

  3. Figure B1 in Online Appendix B displays the distribution of choices in the risk preference elicitation for the curious reader.

  4. Since e.g. risk-averse agents may still prefer not to trade in the SPNE of the SE treatment, and risk-lovers may prefer to trade, even in the WE treatment, we included the risk \(\times\) treatment interactions. Lower values of the variable “risk” imply more risk-aversion. Wald tests indicate that there is no statistically significant correlation with risk preferences in the NE, WE, or SE treatment, p values = 0.70, 0.11, and 0.31, respectively.

  5. Subjects, from the farmers’ point of view, see the common stage narration. They are informed that this stage lasted for four periods in the sessions conducted in the same laboratory a year ago. Next, subjects read the NE treatment narration. For details, see Online Appendix B.2.

  6. Subjects see the same sequence of narration as a traveling merchant would in the NE treatment. For details, see Online Appendix B.2.

  7. Third party enforcement is mainly imposed through a “court” that probabilistically punishes non-sharing behavior. Fehr and Fischbacher (2004), however, used human third party enforcement in both a dictator and prisoner’s dilemma game. They find that human third party enforcement punishes selfish behavior roughly \(60\%\) of time at a cost to herself and therefore encourages sharing/cooperation.

  8. Although in this experiment an exogenously implemented enforcement mechanism mitigates the relationship between culture and willingness to trade, in practice institutions are rarely exogenously imposed. In a recent experiment which compares the endogenous institutional choices of individualists and collectivists, Hajikhameneh (Working paper) found that collectivists are inclined to employ an informal reputation system to enforce trade when both a reputation system and a formal enforcement mechanism are simultaneously available. This suggests that cultural dispositions also influence preferences over institutions, which may help explain why some cultures are less likely to develop and employ formal enforcement institutions, despite their apparent effectiveness.

References

  • Berg, J., Dickhaut, J., & McCabe, K. (1995). Trust, reciprocity, and social history. Games and Economic Behavior, 10(1), 122–142.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bernhard, H., Fischbacher, U., & Fehr, E. (2006). Parochial altruism in humans. Nature, 442(7105), 912–915.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bohnet, I., Frey, B. S., & Huck, S. (2001). More order with less law: On contract enforcement, trust, and crowding. American Political Science Review, 95(1), 131–144.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bohnet, I., Greig, F., Herrmann, B., & Zeckhauser, R. (2008). Betrayal a version: Evidence from Brazil, China, Oman, Switzerland, Turkey, and the USA. American Economic Review, 98, 294–310.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bohnet, I., Harmgart, H., Tyran, J.-R., et al. (2005). Learning trust. Journal of the European Economic Association, 3(2–3), 322–329.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bohnet, I., & Huck, S. (2004). Repetition and reputation: Implications for trust and trustworthiness when institutions change. American Economic Review, 94(2), 362–366.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cassar, A., d’Adda, G., & Grosjean, P. (2014). Institutional quality, culture, and norms of cooperation: Evidence from behavioral field experiments. The Journal of Law and Economics, 57(3), 821–863.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cassar, A., Friedman, D., & Schneider, P. H. (2010). A laboratory investigation of networked markets. The Economic Journal, 120(547), 919–943.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Charness, G., Du, N., & Yang, C.-L. (2011). Trust and trustworthiness reputations in an investment game. Games and Economic Behavior, 72(2), 361–375.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chiu, L.-H. (1972). A cross-cultural comparison of cognitive styles in Chinese and American children. International Journal of Psychology, 7(4), 235–242.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cox, J. C. (2004). How to identify trust and reciprocity. Games and Economic Behavior, 46(2), 260–281.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cox, J. C., & Deck, C. A. (2005). On the nature of reciprocal motives. Economic Inquiry, 43(3), 623–635.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Eckel, C. C., & Wilson, R. K. (2004). Is trust a risky decision? Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 55(4), 447–465.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Farias, M., & Lalljee, M. (2008). Holistic individualism in the age of aquarius: Measuring individualism/collectivism in new age, catholic, and atheist/agnostic groups. Journal for the Scientific Study of Religion, 47(2), 277–289.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fehr, E. (2009). On the economics and biology of trust. Journal of the European Economic Association, 7(2–3), 235–266.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fehr, E., & Fischbacher, U. (2004). Third-party punishment and social norms. Evolution and Human Behavior, 25(2), 63–87.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fehr, E., & List, J. A. (2004). The hidden costs and returns of incentives-trust and trustworthiness among ceos. Journal of the European Economic Association, 2(5), 743–771.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fehr, E., & Rockenbach, B. (2003). Detrimental effects of sanctions on human altruism. Nature, 422(6928), 137–140.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fischbacher, U. (2007). z-tree: Zurich toolbox for ready-made economic experiments. Experimental Economics, 10(2), 171–178.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Green, E. G., Deschamps, J.-C., & Paez, D. (2005). Variation of individualism and collectivism within and between 20 countries a typological analysis. Journal of Cross-Cultural Psychology, 36(3), 321–339.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Greif, A. (1994). Cultural beliefs and the organization of society: A historical and theoretical reflection on collectivist and individualist societies. Journal of Political Economy, 102, 912–950.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Greif, A. (2000). The fundamental problem of exchange: A research agenda in historical institutional analysis. European Review of Economic History, 4(03), 251–284.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hajikhameneh, A. (Working paper). Individualism, collectivism, and alternative enforcement mechanisms in exchange.

  • Hakim, N., Simons, D. J., Zhao, H., & Wan, X. (2017). Do easterners and westerners differ in visual cognition? A preregistered examination of three visual cognition tasks. Social Psychological and Personality Science, 8, 142–152.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Healy, P. J. (2007). Group reputations, stereotypes, and cooperation in a repeated labor market. American Economic Review, 97(5), 1751–1773.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Henrich, J. (2014). Rice, psychology, and innovation. Science, 344(6184), 593–594.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hofstede, G. (1980). Culture’s consequences. Beverly Hills: Sage.

    Google Scholar 

  • Holt, C., & Laury, S. (2002). Risk aversion and incentive effects. American Economic Review, 92(5), 1644–1655.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Houser, D., Schunk, D., & Winter, J. (2010). Distinguishing trust from risk: An anatomy of the investment game. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 74(1), 72–81.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Huck, S., & Lünser, G. K. (2010). Group reputations: An experimental foray. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 73(2), 153–157.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hui, C. H., & Triandis, H. C. (1986). Individualism-collectivism a study of cross-cultural researchers. Journal of Cross-Cultural Psychology, 17(2), 225–248.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ji, L.-J., Zhang, Z., & Nisbett, R. E. (2004). Is it culture or is it language? Examination of language effects in cross-cultural research on categorization. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 87(1), 57.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Johnson, N. D., & Mislin, A. A. (2011). Trust games: A meta-analysis. Journal of Economic Psychology, 32(5), 865–889.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Karlan, D. S. (2005). Using experimental economics to measure social capital and predict financial decisions. American Economic Review, 95, 1688–1699.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Karni, E. (2009). A mechanism for eliciting probabilities. Econometrica, 77(2), 603–606.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kimbrough, E. O., & Rubin, J. (2015). Sustaining group reputation. Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization, 31(3), 599–628.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kimbrough, E. O., & Vostroknutov, A. (2016). Norms make preferences social. Journal of the European Economic Association, 14(3), 608–638.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kitayama, S., Duffy, S., Kawamura, T., & Larsen, J. T. (2003). Perceiving an object and its context in different cultures a cultural look at new look. Psychological Science, 14(3), 201–206.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kitayama, S., Park, H., Sevincer, A. T., Karasawa, M., & Uskul, A. K. (2009). A cultural task analysis of implicit independence: Comparing north America, Western Europe, and East Asia. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 97(2), 236.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kreps, D. M., Milgrom, P., Roberts, J., & Wilson, R. (1982). Rational cooperation in the finitely repeated prisoners’ dilemma. Journal of Economic Theory, 27(2), 245–252.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Krupka, E. L., & Weber, R. A. (2013). Identifying social norms using coordination games: Why does dictator game sharing vary? Journal of the European Economic Association, 11(3), 495–524.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kuran, T. (2010). Institutional causes of economic underdevelopment in the middle east: A historical perspective. Research of Institutional Economics, 3, 16.

    Google Scholar 

  • Leibbrandt, A., Gneezy, U., & List, J. A. (2013). Rise and fall of competitiveness in individualistic and collectivistic societies. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences, 110(23), 9305–9308.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Markus, H. R., & Kitayama, S. (1991). Culture and the self: Implications for cognition, emotion, and motivation. Psychological Review, 98(2), 224.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McCabe, K. A., Rigdon, M. L., & Smith, V. L. (2003). Positive reciprocity and intentions in trust games. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 52(2), 267–275.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nisbett, R. E., Peng, K., Choi, I., & Norenzayan, A. (2001). Culture and systems of thought: Holistic versus analytic cognition. Psychological Review, 108(2), 291.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • North, D. C. (1990). Institutions, institutional change and economic performance. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Osborn, J., Wilson, B. J., & Sherwood, B. R. (2015). Conduct in narrativized trust games. Southern Economic Journal, 81(3), 562–597.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Oyserman, D., Coon, H. M., & Kemmelmeier, M. (2002). Rethinking individualism and collectivism: Evaluation of theoretical assumptions and meta-analyses. Psychological Bulletin, 128(1), 3–72.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • R Development Core Team. (2012). R: A language and environment for statistical computing. Vienna, Austria: R Foundation for Statistical Computing. ISBN 3-900051-07-0.

  • Romney, A. K., & d’Andrade, R. G. (1964). Cognitive aspects of English kin terms. American Anthropologist, 66(3), 146–170.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schechter, L. A. (2005). Trust, trustworthiness, and risk in rural Paraguay. Ph.D. thesis, Citeseer.

  • Schwartz, S. H. (1992). Universals in the content and structure of values: Theoretical advances and empirical tests in 20 countries. Advances in Experimental Social Psychology, 25, 1–65.

    Google Scholar 

  • Smith, V. L., & Wilson, B. J. (2017). Sentiments, conduct, and trust in the laboratory. Social Philosophy and Policy, 34(1), 25–55.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Talhelm, T., Haidt, J., Oishi, S., Zhang, X., Miao, F. F., & Chen, S. (2015). Liberals think more analytically (more “weird”) than conservatives. Personality and Social Psychology Bulletin, 41(2), 250–267.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Talhelm, T., Zhang, X., Oishi, S., Shimin, C., Duan, D., Lan, X., et al. (2014). Large-scale psychological differences within china explained by rice versus wheat agriculture. Science, 344(6184), 603–608.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Triandis, H. C. (1995). Individualism and collectivism. Boulder: Westview Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Triandis, H. C. (2001). Individualism-collectivism and personality. Journal of Personality, 69(6), 907–924.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Triandis, H. C., Bontempo, R., Villareal, M. J., Asai, M., & Lucca, N. (1988). Individualism and collectivism: Cross-cultural perspectives on self-ingroup relationships. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 54(2), 323.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Triandis, H. C., McCusker, C., & Hui, C. H. (1990). Multimethod probes of individualism and collectivism. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 59(5), 1006.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

The authors thank the Social Science and Humanities Research Council of Canada and the Teaching and Learning Centre at Simon Fraser University for financial support. We would also like to thank the editor and two anonymous referees,Tanya Broesch, Kevin Chen, Greg Dow, David Freeman, David Jacks, Laurence Iannaccone, Michael McBride, Angela de Oliviera, Rob Oxoby, Jared Rubin, John Spraggon, and audiences at the 2015 Economic Science Association North American meeting, 2016 Association for the Study of Religion, Economics and Society Annual Conference, and the University of Massachusetts-Amherst Behavioral and Experimental Economics Reading Group for helpful comments. Figures were created using the open-source statistical software R.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Erik O. Kimbrough.

Electronic supplementary material

Below is the link to the electronic supplementary material.

Supplementary material 1 (pdf 411 KB)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Hajikhameneh, A., Kimbrough, E.O. Individualism, collectivism, and trade. Exp Econ 22, 294–324 (2019). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10683-017-9560-1

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Revised:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10683-017-9560-1

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation