Heterogeneous guilt sensitivities and incentive effects
- 466 Downloads
- 3 Citations
Abstract
Psychological games of guilt aversion assume that preferences depend on (beliefs about) beliefs and on the guilt sensitivity of the decision-maker. We present an experiment designed to measure guilt sensitivities at the individual level for various stake sizes. We use the data to estimate a structural choice model that allows for heterogeneity, and permits that guilt sensitivities depend on stake size. We find substantial heterogeneity of guilt sensitivities in our population, with 60% of decision makers displaying stake-dependent guilt sensitivity. For these decision makers, we find that average guilt sensitivities are significantly different from zero for all stakes considered, while significantly decreasing with the level of stakes.
Keywords
Guilt sensitivity Psychological game theory Heterogeneity Stakes Dictator gameJEL Classification
A13 C91Notes
Acknowledgements
The authors thank audiences of seminars at the universities of Amsterdam, Copenhagen, Frankfurt, Gothenborg, Heidelberg, Innsbruck, Mannheim, Munich, Pennsylvania, and Tilburg, at the Max Planck Institute of Economics in Jena, at the Nordic Conference of Behavioral and Experimental Economics in Stockholm, and at IMEBE in Madrid for helpful comments. Furthermore, we would like to thank the editor and two anonymous referees for very helpful comments. Suetens acknowledges financial support from the Netherlands Organization for Scientific Research (NWO) through the VIDI program (Project No. 452-11-012).
Supplementary material
References
- Abdellaoui, M., Barrios, C., & Wakker, P. P. (2007). Reconciling introspective utility with revealed preference: Experimental arguments based on prospect theory. Journal of Econometrics, 138, 356–378.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Andreoni, J., & Bernheim, B. D. (2009). Social image and the 50–50 norm: A theoretical and experimental analysis of audience effects. Econometrica, 77, 1607–1636.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Armantier, O., & Treich, N. (2013). Eliciting beliefs: Proper scoring rules, incentives, stakes and hedging. European Economic Review, 62, 17–40.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Attanasi, G., Battigalli, P., & Manzoni, E. (2015). Incomplete-information models of guilt aversion in the trust game. Management Science, 62(3), 648–667.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Attanasi, G., Battigalli, P., and Nagel, R. (2013). Disclosure of belief-dependent preferences in a trust game. Mimeo.Google Scholar
- Babcock, L., & Loewenstein, G. (1997). Explaining bargaining impasse: The role of self-serving biases. The Journal of Economic Perspectives, 11(1), 109–126.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Battigalli, P., & Dufwenberg, M. (2007). Guilt in games. American Economic Review Papers and Proceedings, 97, 170–176.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Battigalli, P., & Dufwenberg, M. (2009). Dynamic psychological games. Journal of Economic Theory, 144, 1–35.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Baumeister, R., Stillwell, A., & Heatherton, T. (1994). Guilt: An interpersonal approach. Psychological Bulletin, 115, 243–267.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Bellemare, C., Kröger, S., & van Soest, A. (2008). Measuring inequity aversion in a heterogeneous population using experimental decisions and subjective probabilities. Econometrica, 76, 815–839.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Bellemare, C., Sebald, A., & Strobel, M. (2011). Measuring the willingness to pay to avoid guilt: Estimation using equilibrium and stated belief models. Journal of Applied Econometrics, 26, 437–453.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Bellemare, C., Sebald, A., & Suetens, S. (2017). A note on testing guilt aversion. Games and Economic Behavior, 102, 233–239.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Bicchieri, C. (2006). The grammar of society: The nature and dynamics of social norms. Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
- Bicchieri, C., & Xiao, E. (2009). Do the right thing: But only if others do so. Journal of Behavioral Decision Making, 22(2), 191–208.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Bicchieri, C., Xiao, E., & Muldoon, R. (2011). Trustworthiness is a social norm, but trusting is not. Politics, Philosophy, and Economics, 10, 170–187.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Camerer, C., & Hogarth, R. (1999). The effects of financial incentives in experiments: A review and capital-labor-production framework. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 19, 7–42.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Carpenter, J., Verhoogen, E., & Burks, S. (2005). The effect of stakes in distribution experiments. Economics Letters, 86, 393–398.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Charness, G., & Dufwenberg, M. (2006). Promises and partnerships. Econometrica, 74, 1579–1601.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Ellingsen, T., Johannesson, M., Tjötta, S., & Torsvik, G. (2010). Testing guilt aversion. Games and Economic Behavior, 68, 95–107.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Fehr, E., & Schmidt, K. (1999). A theory of fairness, competition and cooperation. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 114, 817–868.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Fischbacher, U. (2007). z-Tree: Zurich toolbox for ready-made economic experiments. Experimental Economics, 10, 171–178.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Geanakoplos, J., Pearce, D., & Stacchetti, E. (1989). Psychological games and sequential rationality. Games and Economic Behavior, 1, 60–79.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Gibson, R., Tanner, C., & Wagner, A. (2013). Preferences for truthfulness: Heterogeneity among and within individuals. American Economic Review, 103, 532–548.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Gneezy, U., Meier, S., & Rey-Biel, P. (2011). When and why incentives (don’t) work to modify behavior. Journal of Economic Perspective, 25, 191–210.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Greiner, B. (2004). The online recruitment system ORSEE 2.0—A guide for the organization of experiments in economics. Technical report, University of Cologne, Working Paper Series in Economics 10.Google Scholar
- Güth, W., Schmittberger, R., & Schwarze, B. (1982). An experimental analysis of ultimatum bargaining. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 3(4), 367–388.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Holt, C., & Laury, S. (2002). Risk aversion and incentive effects. American Economic Review, 92, 1644–1655.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Khalmetski, K., Ockenfels, A., & Werner, P. (2015). Surprising gifts: Theory and laboratory evidence. Journal of Economic Theory, 159, 163–208.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Krupka, E. L., & Weber, R. A. (2013). Identifying social norms using coordination games: Why does dictator game sharing vary? Journal of the European Economic Association, 11, 495–524.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Noussair, C. N., Trautmann, S. T., & van de Kuilen, G. (2014). Higher order risk attitudes, demographics, and financial decisions. Review of Economic Studies, 81, 325–355.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Reuben, E., Sapienza, P., & Zingales, L. (2009). Is mistrust self-fulfilling? Economics Letters, 104, 89–91.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Schotter, A., & Sopher, B. (2007). Advice and behavior in intergenerational ultimatum games: An experimental approach. Games and Economic Behavior, 58(2), 365–393.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Selten, R. (1967). Die Strategiemethode zur Erforschung des Eingeschränkt Rationalen Verhaltens im Rahmen eines Oligopolexperiments. In H. Sauermann (Ed.), Beiträge zur Experimentellen Wirtschaftsforschung (pp. 136–168). Tübingen: J. C. B. Mohr.Google Scholar
- Smith, V., & Walker, J. (1993). Monetary rewards and decision costs in experimental economics. Economic Inquiry, 31, 245–261.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Trautmann, S. T., & van de Kuilen, G. (2015). Belief elicitation: A horse race among truth serums. Economic Journal (forthcoming).Google Scholar
- Vanberg, C. (2008). Why do people keep their promises? An experimental test of two explanations. Econometrica, 76, 1467–1480.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Yang, Y., Onderstal, S., & Schram, A. (2012). Inequity aversion revisited. Working paper, University of Amsterdam.Google Scholar