Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Increasing Paper and Cardboard Recycling: Impacts on the Forest Sector and Carbon Emissions

  • Published:
Environmental Modeling & Assessment Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Recycling is emerging as both a viable alternative to extraction in many industries and a cornerstone of the circular economy. In this paper, we assess the role of paper and cardboard recycling on the forest sector, from both an economic and carbon perspective. For this purpose, we add the recycling industry to an existing forest-sector model in an attempt to capture its effects on other wood products and the overall forest resource. As the forest sector has an important potential for climate change mitigation, this model allows us to assess the effects of increased paper and cardboard recycling on the availability of the natural resource and the carbon balance of the forest sector. We show that these results are strongly linked to the hypotheses of substitutability and/or complementarity of recycled pulp and virgin pulpwood. Although we find increased emissions at the pulp sector level, the effects on emissions in other wood products are small. When pulp products are considered substitutes, we find the impact on total net sequestration to be positive. In the case where pulp products are considered complements, we find the impact on total net sequestration to be negative.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Subscribe and save

Springer+ Basic
$34.99 /Month
  • Get 10 units per month
  • Download Article/Chapter or eBook
  • 1 Unit = 1 Article or 1 Chapter
  • Cancel anytime
Subscribe now

Buy Now

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5

Similar content being viewed by others

Data Availability

Data to calibrate the model is available at https://ffsm-project.org/wiki/en/home. Other sources of data are described in Sect. 2.3 and are from previously published articles or from publicly available reports.

Code Availability

The source code of the model is available at https://ffsm-project.org/wiki/en/home.

Notes

  1. In the rest of the paper, pulpwood refers to the virgin material, as opposed to recycled pulp.

  2. https://ffsm-project.org/wiki/en/home

  3. ISO 14040 and ISO 14044.

  4. See Caurla [36] for a full description of the model, and https://ffsm-project.org/wiki/en/doc/home#published_articles for any further extension.

  5. See Caurla et al. [38].

  6. See Caurla et al. [35] for the detailed construction of the composite supply of primary products.

  7. Results for panels are very similar as for fuelwood, and results for softwood sawnwood and plywood are very similar for hardwood sawnwood. They can be provided upon request by the reader.

  8. Unlike Table 2 where we show GHG emissions amounts, we produce in Tables 3, 4, and 6 GHG substitution and sequestration, where a negative sign means more emissions, and a positive sign more mitigation.

  9. Note that we do not display results for lands covered with a mix of conifers and broadleaves, which are very stable in terms of volumes and areas.

References

  1. ADEME and FEDEREC. (2017). Evaluation environnementale du recyclage en France selon la méthodologie de l’analyse de cycle de vie, Agence de l’Environnement et de la Maîtrise de l’Energie.

  2. UNEP. (2019). Resource efficiency and climate change - material efficiency strategies for a low-carbon future, United Nations Environment Programme.

  3. ADEME. (2019) Analyse du cycle de vie des flux de déchets recyclés sur le territoire français, Agence de l’Environnement et de la Maîtrise de l’Energie.

  4. ADEME and Bio by Deloitte. (2017). Bilan National du Recyclage 2005–2014, Agence de l’Environnement et de la Maîtrise de l’Energie.

  5. Lobianco, A., Caurla, S., Delacote, P., & Barkaoui, A. (2016). Carbon mitigation potential of the French forest sector under threat of combined physical and market impacts due to climate change. Journal of Forest Economics, 23, 4–26. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jfe.2015.12.003

    Article  Google Scholar 

  6. Hoel, M. (1978). Resource extraction and recycling with environmental costs. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 5(3), 220–235. https://doi.org/10.1016/0095-0696(78)90010-4

    Article  Google Scholar 

  7. Smith, V. L. (1972). Dynamics of waste accumulation: Disposal versus recycling. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 86(4), 600–616. https://doi.org/10.2307/1882044

    Article  Google Scholar 

  8. Huhtala, A. (1999). Optimizing production technology choices: Conventional production vs. Recycling, Resource and Energy Economics, 21(1), 1–18. https://doi.org/10.1016/S0928-7655(98)00030-X

    Article  Google Scholar 

  9. Lafforgue, G., & Lorang, E. (2022). Recycling under environmental, climate and resource constraints. Resource and Energy Economics, 67, 101278. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.reseneeco.2021.101278

    Article  Google Scholar 

  10. Di Vita, G. (2004). Renewable resources and waste recycling. Environmental Modeling & Assessment, 9(3), 159–167.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  11. Acuff, K., & Kaffine, D. T. (2013). Greenhouse gas emissions, waste and recycling policy. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 65(1), 74–86. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jeem.2012.05.003

    Article  Google Scholar 

  12. Tsiliyannis, C. A. (2008). Apportionment of recycle to industrial reuser and consumer. Environmental Modeling & Assessment, 13(2), 195–208. https://doi.org/10.1007/s10666-007-9111-9

    Article  Google Scholar 

  13. Vahdani, B., Razmi, J., & Tavakkoli-Moghaddam, R. (2012). Fuzzy possibilistic modeling for closed loop recycling collection networks. Environmental Modeling & Assessment, 17(6), 623–637. https://doi.org/10.1007/s10666-012-9313-7

    Article  Google Scholar 

  14. Lee, M., & Ma, H.-O. (2021). Substitution possibility between unpriced pulp and wastepaper in the U.S. paper and paperboard industry. Environmental and Resource Economics, 18(3), 251–273.

  15. Lundmark, R., & Olsson, A. (2015). Factor substitution and procurement competition for forest resources in Sweden. International Journal of Production Economics, 169, 99–109. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ijpe.2015.07.029

    Article  Google Scholar 

  16. Lundmark, R., & Söderholm, P. (2003). Structural changes in Swedish wastepaper demand: A variable cost function approach. Journal of Forest Economics, 9(1), 41–63. https://doi.org/10.1078/1104-6899-00022

    Article  Google Scholar 

  17. Mansikkasalo, A., Lundmark, R., & Söderholm, P. (2014). Market behavior and policy in the recycled paper industry: A critical survey of price elasticity research. Forest Policy and Economics, 38, 17–29. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.forpol.2013.08.011

    Article  Google Scholar 

  18. ERPC. (2015). European Declaration on Paper Recycling. European Recovered Paper Council.

  19. Zink, T., & Geyer, R. (2017). Circular economy rebound. Journal of Industrial Ecology, 21(3), 593–602. https://doi.org/10.1111/jiec.12545

    Article  Google Scholar 

  20. Deadman, D., & Turner, R. K. (1981). Modeling the supply of wastepaper. Journal of environmental economics and management, 8(1), 100–103.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  21. Edgren, J. A., & Moreland, K. W. (1990). An econometric analysis of paper and wastepaper markets. Resources and Energy, 11(3), 299–319.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  22. Newman, D. H. (1987). An econometric analysis of the southern softwood stumpage market: 1950–1980. Forest Science, 33, 932–945.

    Google Scholar 

  23. Byström, S., & Lönnstedt, L. (1997). Paper recycling: Environmental and economic impact. Resources, Conservation and Recycling, 21(2), 109–127. https://doi.org/10.1016/S0921-3449(97)00031-1

    Article  Google Scholar 

  24. Merrild, H., Damgaard, A., & Christensen, T. H. (2009). Recycling of paper: Accounting of greenhouse gases and global warming contributions. Waste Management & Research, 27(8), 746–753. https://doi.org/10.1177/0734242X09348530

    Article  CAS  Google Scholar 

  25. Nakamura, S. (1999). An interindustry approach to analyzing economic and environmental effects of the recycling of waste. Ecological Economics, 28(1), 133–145.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  26. Cook-Patton, S. C., et al. (2020). Mapping carbon accumulation potential from global natural forest regrowth. Nature, 585(7826), 545–550. https://doi.org/10.1038/s41586-020-2686-x

    Article  CAS  Google Scholar 

  27. Sathre, R., & O’Connor, J. (2010). Meta-analysis of greenhouse gas displacement factors of wood product substitution. Environmental Science & Policy, 13(2), 104–114.

    Article  CAS  Google Scholar 

  28. Churkina, G., et al. (2020). Buildings as a global carbon sink. Nature Sustainability, 3(4), 269–276. https://doi.org/10.1038/s41893-019-0462-4

    Article  Google Scholar 

  29. Tatoutchoup, D., & Gaudet, G. (2011). The impact of recycling on the long-run forestry. Canadian Journal of Economics/Revue canadienne d’économique, 44(3), 804–813. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1540-5982.2011.01655.x

    Article  Google Scholar 

  30. Tatoutchoup, F. D. (2016). Optimal rate of paper recycling. Forest Policy and Economics, 73, 264–269. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.forpol.2016.09.022

    Article  Google Scholar 

  31. Riviere, M., Caurla, S., & Delacote, P. (2020). Evolving integrated models from narrower economic tools: The example of forest sector models. Environmental Modeling & Assessment, 25(4), 453–469. https://doi.org/10.1007/s10666-020-09706-w

    Article  Google Scholar 

  32. Buongiorno, J., Zhu, S., Zhang, D., Turner, J., & Tomberlin, D. (2003). The global forest products model: Structure, estimation, and applications. Elsevier.

  33. Pieratti, E., Paletto, A., De Meo, I., Fagarazzi, C., & Migliorini, R. (2019). Assessing the forest-wood chain at local level: A multi-criteria decision analysis (MCDA) based on the circular bioeconomy principles. Annals of Forest Research, 62https://doi.org/10.15287/afr.2018.1238

  34. D’Amato, D., Gaio, M., & Semenzin, E. (2020). A review of LCA assessments of forest-based bioeconomy products and processes under an ecosystem services perspective. Science of The Total Environment, 706, 135859. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.scitotenv.2019.135859

    Article  CAS  Google Scholar 

  35. Caurla, S., Lecocq, F., Delacote, P., & Barkaoui, A. (2010). The French Forest Sector Model version 1.0. Presentation and theoretical foundations, LEF, INRA, Working Paper.

  36. Caurla, S. (2012). Modélisation de la filière forêt-bois française - Évaluation des impacts des politiques climatiques, PhD thesis, AgroParisTech.

  37. Caurla, S., Delacote, P., Lecocq, F., & Barkaoui, A. (2013). Stimulating fuelwood consumption through public policies: An assessment of economic and resource impacts based on the French Forest Sector Model. Energy Policy, 63, 338–347. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.enpol.2013.07.111

    Article  Google Scholar 

  38. Caurla, S., Delacote, P., Lecocq, F., Barthès, J., & Barkaoui, A. (2013). Combining an inter-sectoral carbon tax with sectoral mitigation policies: Impacts on the French forest sector. Journal of Forest Economics, 19(4), 450–461. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jfe.2013.09.002

    Article  Google Scholar 

  39. Lobianco, A., Delacote, P., Caurla, S., & Barkaoui, A. (2016). Accounting for active management and risk attitude in forest sector models: An impact study on French forests. Environmental Modeling & Assessment, 21(3), 391–405. https://doi.org/10.1007/s10666-015-9483-1

    Article  Google Scholar 

  40. Petucco, C., Lobianco, A., & Caurla, S. (2019). Economic evaluation of an invasive forest pathogen at a large scale: The case of ash dieback in France. Environmental Modeling & Assessment. https://doi.org/10.1007/s10666-019-09661-1

    Article  Google Scholar 

  41. Armington, P. S. (1969). A theory of demand for products distinguished by place of production. Staff Papers - International Monetary Fund, 16(1), 159. https://doi.org/10.2307/3866403

    Article  Google Scholar 

  42. Sauquet, A., Lecocq, F., Delacote, P., Caurla, S., Barkaoui, A., & Garcia, S. (2011). Estimating Armington elasticities for sawnwood and application to the French Forest Sector Model. Resource and Energy Economics, 33(4), 771–781. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.reseneeco.2011.04.001

    Article  Google Scholar 

  43. Samuelson, P. A. (1952). Spatial price equilibrium and linear programming. The American economic review, 42(3), 283–303.

    Google Scholar 

  44. Palmer, K., Sigman, H., & Walls, M. (1997). The cost of reducing municipal solid waste. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 33(2), 128–150. https://doi.org/10.1006/jeem.1997.0986

    Article  Google Scholar 

  45. Lenglet, J., Courtonne, J.-Y., & Caurla, S. (2017). Material flow analysis of the forest-wood supply chain: A consequential approach for log export policies in France. Journal of Cleaner Production, 165, 1296–1305. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jclepro.2017.07.177

    Article  Google Scholar 

  46. Montagné, C., & Niedzwiedz, A. (2010). Comptes intégrés économiques et environnementaux de la forêt en France, p. 14.

  47. Copacel. (2016). Rapport annuel 2016, Union Française des Industries des Cartons, Papiers et Celluloses.

  48. Lafforgue, G., & Rouge, L. (2019). A dynamic model of recycling with endogenous technological breakthrough. Resource and Energy Economics, 57, 101–118. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.reseneeco.2019.04.002

    Article  Google Scholar 

  49. Gamfeldt, L., et al. (2013). Higher levels of multiple ecosystem services are found in forests with more tree species. Nature Communications, 4(1), 1340. https://doi.org/10.1038/ncomms2328

    Article  CAS  Google Scholar 

  50. Ayres, R. U. (2007). On the practical limits to substitution. Ecological Economics, 61(1), 115–128. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ecolecon.2006.02.011

    Article  Google Scholar 

  51. Latta, G. S., Sjølie, H. K., and Solberg, B. (2013). A review of recent developments and applications of partial equilibrium models of the forest sector. Journal of Forest Economics, 19(4), 350–360. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jfe.2013.06.006

Download references

Acknowledgements

The authors acknowledge very valuable comments from the participants of the CEC and BETA seminars, of the 2020 FAERE annual conference, and of the 2021 EAERE congress. This paper has been significantly improved by the comments of Sylvain Caurla, Miguel Rivière, two anonymous reviewers, and the editor. All errors remain the responsibility of the authors.

Funding

This research is part of the Agriculture and Forestry research program by the Climate Economics Chair. The BETA contributes to the Labex ARBRE ANR-11-LABX-0002–01.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Contributions

All authors contributed to the conception of the study. AL and EL designed and coded the model extension. EL carried out calibrations and simulations. The first draft of the manuscript was written by EL, and all authors commented on and edited previous versions of the manuscript. All authors read and approved the final manuscript.

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Etienne Lorang.

Ethics declarations

Ethics Approval

Not applicable.

Consent to Participate

Not applicable.

Consent for Publication

Not applicable.

Conflict of Interest

The authors declare no competing interests.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Appendix

Appendix

  1. A.

    The Samuelson problem in the FFSM model

Starting with the GFPM (The Global Forest Products Model) model by Buongiorno et al. [32], forest market models generally use net social surplus maximization to solve prices and quantities equilibria (see Rivière et al. [31] and Latta et al. [51] for a general description and review of these models).

Samuelson [43] formalizes the optimal transport problem with regions having supply and demand functions for a certain product. A certain amount of the product is traded between regions depending on the price difference between regions and including transportation costs. He obtains equilibrium conditions through the maximization of a net social payoff that consists in the sum of the consumers and the suppliers’ surpluses minus the cost of transport from one region to the other.

The FFSM model can be seen as an extension of the Samuelson framework, with the introduction of the transformation industries (see Caurla et al. [35]). With this new framework, Caurla [36] demonstrates that an equilibrium also exists. Mathematically, the maximization problem relies on the following sum of surpluses:

$$\begin{aligned}& \sum_{p,i}\left({\int }_{0}^{{D}_{p,i}}{P}_{p,i}\left(D\right)dD-{P}_{p,i}{D}_{p,i}\right)+\sum_{w,i}\left({P}_{w,i}{S}_{w,i}-{\int }_{0}^{{S}_{w,i}}{P}_{w,i}\left(S\right)dS\right) \\ & \quad +\sum_{p,i}{P}_{p,i}{S}_{p,i}-\sum_{p,i}{c}_{p}{S}_{p,i}-\sum_{w,i}{P}_{w,i}{D}_{w,i} +\sum_{p,i,j\ne i}\left({P}_{p,j}-{P}_{p,i}-{C}_{p,i,j}\right){e}_{p,i,j} \\ & \quad +\sum_{w,i,j\ne i}\left({P}_{w,j}-{P}_{w,i}-{C}_{w,i,j}\right){e}_{w,i,j}\qquad,\end{aligned}$$
(5)

with \(i,j\) referring to regions, \(w, p\) referring to primary and transformed products respectively; prices \(P\), demand \(D\), supply \(S\), exchanged amounts \(e\) as endogenous decision variables; and transformation costs \(c\) (including \({c}_{recy}\) for recycling industries) transportation costs \(C\) as exogenous variables. Prices \(P\) come from inverse demand and supply functions \(P(D)\) and \(P(S)\), by inverting Eqs. (1) and (2) for the specific case of waste and recycled pulp products (and similarly, with their specific subscripts for other products). The first two terms of Eq. (5) represent the consumers and suppliers’ surpluses; terms three to five represent the surplus of the transformation industry; and the last two terms represent the surpluses of trade agents. The maximization of the global surplus gives us the market equilibrium (under assumptions of perfect markets). Detailed setup and resolution can be found in Caurla et al. [35] and Caurla [36].

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Lorang, E., Lobianco, A. & Delacote, P. Increasing Paper and Cardboard Recycling: Impacts on the Forest Sector and Carbon Emissions. Environ Model Assess 28, 189–200 (2023). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10666-022-09850-5

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10666-022-09850-5

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation