Skip to main content
Log in

Understanding the Price Dynamics in the Jiangsu SO2 Emissions Trading Program in China: A Multiple Periods Analysis

  • Published:
Environmental Modeling & Assessment Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Because emissions permits can be considered to be a pseudo-commodity, the permit price in the emissions trading markets has already attracted great interest from the economic literature. This research took the Jiangsu sulfur dioxide (SO2) emissions trading program in China as a case study to examine the price dynamics over the next 10 years (2011–2020) based on Jiangsu’s new SO2 emissions trading policy design. An adaptive agent-based simulation model was developed to estimate the price dynamics as well as the impact of energy price, policy design, and new environmental regulation on the permit price. The results showed that the equilibrium price of the Jiangsu SO2 emissions trading market is approximately 4.20 CNY/kg, and the permit price will fluctuate around this price if the other conditions are not changed. If the coal price increases during 2011–2016, the permit price will decline to 2.79 CNY/kg by 2020 under China’s current coal–electricity price mechanism. In addition, the banking mechanism will smooth the price fluctuations and the average permit price will be generally higher when banking is not allowed. Finally, the stricter environmental regulation will reduce the market supply of permits and will raise the permit price. According to China’s potential new SO2 discharge standard, the permit price will jump to 11 CNY/kg. The quantification of the permit price dynamics can help power plants to make decisions on emissions trading.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5
Fig. 6
Fig. 7

Similar content being viewed by others

References

  1. Wang, J. N., Dong, Z. F., Yang, J. T., Li, Y. S., & Yan, G. (2008). Emission trading programs: the updated progress and its development for China. Paper presented at the International Workshop on Emissions Trading Programs: Policy Innovation and Business Opportunity Nanjing, China, 12 Nov 2008.

  2. Leung, D. Y. C., Yung, D., Ng, A., Leung, M. K. H., & Chan, A. (2009). An overview of emissions trading and its prospects in Hong Kong. Environmental Science & Policy, 12(1), 92–101. doi:10.1016/j.envsci.2008.09.002.

    Article  CAS  Google Scholar 

  3. Tao, J. L., & Mah, D. N. (2009). Between market and state: dilemmas of environmental governance in China’s sulphur dioxide emission trading system. Environment and Planning C: Government and Policy, 27, 175–188.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  4. Burtraw, D., Evans, D. A., Krupnick, A., Palmer, K., & Toth, R. (2005). Economics of pollution trading for SO2 and NO x . Annual Review of Energy and the Environment, 30, 253–289.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  5. Tietenberg, T. H. (2006). Emissions trading: principles and practice (2nd ed.). Washington DC: Resources for the Future.

  6. Soleille, S. (2006). Greenhouse gas emission trading schemes: a new tool for the environmental regulator’s kit. Energy Policy, 34(13), 1473–1477.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  7. Weber, C. L., & Matthews, H. S. (2007). Embodied environmental emissions in U.S. international trade, 1997–2004. Environmental Science Technology, 41, 4875–4881.

    Google Scholar 

  8. Taschini, L. (2010). The endogenous price dynamics of emission permits in the presence of technology change. Paper presented at the “Weather Derivatives and Risk” Workshop, Berlin, 27–28 January.

  9. Ellerman, A. D., & Buchner, B. K. (2007). The European Union Emissions Trading Scheme: origins, allocation, and early results. Review of Environmental Economics and Policy, 1(1), 66–87. doi:10.1093/reep/rem003.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  10. Boutabba, M. A., Beaumais, O., & Lardic, S. (2012). Permit price dynamics in the U.S. SO2 trading program: a cointegration approach. Energy Economics, 34(3), 714–722. doi:10.1016/j.eneco.2011.04.004.

  11. Benz, E., & Trück, S. (2009). Modeling the price dynamics of CO2 emission allowances. Energy Economics, 31(1), 4–15. doi:10.1016/j.eneco.2008.07.003.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  12. Hitzemann, S., & Uhrig-Homburg, M. (2011). Understanding the price dynamics of emission permits: a model for multiple trading periods. http://ssrn.com/abstract=1763182.

  13. Chesney, M., & Taschini, L. (2012). The endogenous price dynamics of emission allowances and an application to option pricing. Applied Mathematical Finance, 1–29. doi:10.1080/1350486x.2011.639948.

  14. Stranlund, J. K., & Moffitt, L. J. (2011). Enforcement and price controls in emissions trading. Working paper. http://www.webmeets.com/AERE/2011/prog/viewpaper.asp?pid=65.

  15. Fell, H., Burtraw, D., Morgenstern, R., Palmer, K., & Preonas, L. (2010). Soft and hard price collars in a cap-and-trade system: a comparative analysis. Working paper no. RFF DP 10-27.

  16. Alberola, E., Chevallier, J., & Ceze, B. (2008). Price drivers and structural breaks in the European carbon prices 2005–2007. Energy Policy, 36(2), 787–797.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  17. Chesney, M., & Taschini, L. (2008). The endogenous price dynamics of emission allowances and an application to CO 2 option pricing. Switzerland: Swiss Banking Institute, University of Zurich.

  18. Convery, F. J., & Redmond, L. (2007). Market and price developments in the European Union Emissions Trading Scheme. Review of Environmental Economics and Policy, 1(1), 88–111.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  19. Mansanet-Bataller, M., Pardo, A., & Valor, E. (2007). CO2 prices, energy and weather. The Energy Journal, 28(3), 67–86.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  20. Ellerman, A. D., Schmalensee, R., Joskow, P. L., Montero, J. P., & Bailey, E. M. (1997). Emissions trading under the U.S. Acid Rain Program: evaluation of compliance costs and allowance market performance. Cambridge: MIT Center for Energy and Environmental Policy Research.

  21. Zhang, W., & Wang, X. J. (2002). Modeling for point–non-point source effluent trading: perspective of non-point sources regulation in China. Science of the Total Environment, 292(3), 167–176. doi:10.1016/s0048-9697(01)01105-6.

    Article  CAS  Google Scholar 

  22. Wang, X., Zhang, W., Huang, Y., & Li, S. (2004). Modeling and simulation of point–non-point source effluent trading in Taihu Lake area: perspective of non-point sources control in China. Science of the Total Environment, 325(1–3), 39–50. doi:10.1016/j.scitotenv.2004.01.001.

    Article  CAS  Google Scholar 

  23. Hoffmann, V. H., Trautmann, T., & Schneider, M. (2008). A taxonomy for regulatory uncertainty—application to the European Emission Trading Scheme. Environmental Science & Policy, 11(8), 712–722. doi:10.1016/j.envsci.2008.07.001.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  24. Jiao, J.-L., Hong, Z., & Wei, Y.-M. (2010). Impact analysis of China’s coal–electricity price linkage mechanism: results from a game model. Journal of Policy Modeling, 32, 574–588. doi:10.1016/j.jpolmod.2010.05.002.

    Google Scholar 

  25. Burtraw, D., & Szambelan, S. J. (2009). U.S. emissions trading markets for SO 2 and NO x . Washington DC: Resources for the Future.

  26. Zhang, F. (2007a). Does uncertainty matter? A stochastic dynamic analysis of bankable emission permit trading for global climate change policy. World Bank Policy Research Working Paper 4215.

  27. Shennach, S. M. (2000). The economics of pollution permit banking in the context of Title IV of the 1990 Clean Air Act Amendments. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 40(3), 189–210.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  28. Boutaba, M. A., Beaumais, O., & Lardic, S. (2008). Permit price dynamics in the U.S. SO 2 trading scheme: a cointegration approach. Rouen: University of Rouen.

  29. Helfand, G. E., Moore, M. R., & Liu, Y. (2007). The intertemporal market for sulfur dioxide allowances. Ann Arbor: School of Natural Resources and Environment, University of Michigan.

  30. Chen, G. J., Tan, Z. F., Guo, L. Z., & Guan, Y. (2007). Risk analysis model for firepower companies under coal–electricity price linkage. Modern Electric Power (Chinese), 24(2), 74–78.

    Google Scholar 

  31. Zhang, F. (2007b). China’s coal pricing mechanism needs improvement. International Business. http://ezinearticles.com/?Chinas-Coal-Pricing-Mechanism-Needs-Improvement&id=1223991.

  32. Guerci, E., Ivaldi, S., Pastore, S., & Cincotti, S. (2005). Modeling and implementation of an artificial electricity market using agent-based technology. Physica A: Statistical Mechanics and its Applications, 355, 69–76.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  33. Tesfatsion, L. (2006). Agent-based computational economics: a constructive approach to economic theory. In K. L. Judd, & L. Tesfatsion (Eds.), Handbook of computational economics (vol. 2, pp. 831–880). Amsterdam: Elsevier.

  34. Veit, D. J., Weidlich, A., & Krafft, J. A. (2009). An agent-based analysis of the German electricity market with transmission capacity constraints. Energy Policy, 37(10), 4132–4144. doi:10.1016/j.enpol.2009.05.023.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  35. Walter, I., & Gomide, F. Electricity market simulation: multiagent system approach. In Proceedings of the 2008 ACM Symposium on Applied Computing, Fortaleza, Ceara, Brazil, 2008 (pp. 34–38). 1363695: ACM. http://doi.acm.org/10.1145/1363686.1363695.

  36. Genoesea, M., Sensfuß, F., Mosta, D., & Rentza, O. (2007). Agent-based analysis of the impact of CO2 emission trading on spot market prices for electricity in Germany. Pacific Journal of Optimization, 3(3), 401–423.

    Google Scholar 

  37. Mizuta, H., & Yamagata, Y. (2001). Agent-based simulation and greenhouse gas emission trading. In Proceedings of the 2001 Winter Simulation Conference.

  38. Sichao, K., Yamamoto, H., & Yamaji, K. (2010). Evaluation of CO2 free electricity trading market in Japan by multi-agent simulations. Energy Policy, 38(7), 3309–3319. doi:10.1016/j.enpol.2010.02.002.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  39. Nie, T. Y., & Xu, W. (2009). Emissions trading in Chongqing, China. China Environment News. http://www.cenews.com.cn/xwzx/zhxw/ybyw/200912/t20091228_629186.html.

  40. Cliff, D. (2002). Evolution of market mechanism through a continuous space of auction-types. CEC’02. Proceedings of the 2002 Congress on Evolutionary Computation, 2, 2029–2034.

  41. Posada, M., Hernández, C., & López-Paredes, A. (2005). Emissions permits auctions: an ABM analysis. Paper presented at the Third Annual Conference of the European Social Simulation Association, Koblenz.

  42. Walsh, W. E., Das, G., Tesauro, G., & Kephart, J. O. (2002). Analyzing complex strategic interactions in multi-agent games. Paper presented at the 8th Conference on Artificial Intelligence, Canada.

  43. Nicolaisen, J., Petrov, V., & Tesfatsion, L. (2001). Market power and efficiency in a computational electricity market with discriminatory double auction pricing. IEEE Trans on Evolutionary Computation, 5(5), 504–523.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  44. Cliff, D., & Bruten, J. (1997). Zero is not enough: on the lower limit of agent intelligence for continuous double auction markets. Technical Report HP-1997-141, Hewlett Packard Laboratories.

  45. Das, R., Hanson, J. E., Kephart, J. O., & Tesauro, G. (2001). Agent-human interactions in the continuous double auction. Paper presented at the International Joint Conferences on Artificial Intelligence (IJCAI), Seattle, USA.

  46. MEP (2011). Emission standard of air pollutants for thermal power plants (draft). http://wenku.baidu.com/view/7365b03383c4bb4cf7ecd1c9.html.

  47. Phaneuf, D. J., & Requate, T. (2002). Incentives for investment in advanced pollution abatement technology in emission permit markets with banking. Environmental and Resource Economics, 22(369–390).

  48. JSEPB (2002). SO 2 emission permit allocation scheme of electric power industry in Jiangsu Province. Suqian: Jiangsu Environmental Protection Bureau.

  49. JSFB (2006). The pool purchase price (PPP) of power plants in Jiangsu Province (vol. [2006]223). Jiangsu: Jiangsu Financial Bureau.

  50. JSEPB, JSFB, & JSPB (2007). Notice of the adjustment of emissions discharge fee standard. Jiangsu Environmental Protection Bureau, Jiangsu Financial Bureau, and Jiangsu Price Bureau. http://hjj.mep.gov.cn/pwsf/dfjl/200707/t20070705_106246.htm.

  51. Zhan, W. J., & Zhan, J. Y. (2008). Zero intelligence plus strategies in continues double auction market. Management Review, 20(5), 44–51.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

This paper was supported by the National Science Foundation of China (grant no. 71273004).

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Bing Zhang.

Appendices

Appendix 1: Marginal Profits

The representative firms’ optimization problem is:

$$ \max \pi = G{q^k}{p_e} - {p_c}q - \phi \alpha q\theta {\kappa^{{\frac{1}{{1 - {\theta^{*}}}}}}} - {p_d}\alpha q(1 - \theta ) $$
(14)
$$ {\mathrm{subject} \mathrm{to}\text{:}}\quad A - \alpha q(1 - \theta ) = 0 $$
(15)

We define the Lagrangian expression as:

$$ L = G{q^k}{p_e} - {p_c}q - \phi \alpha q\theta {\kappa^{{\frac{1}{{1 - \theta }}}}} - {p_d}\alpha q(1 - \theta ) + \lambda (A - \alpha q(1 - \theta )) $$
(16)

The necessary first-order conditions determining a maximum at (q *, θ *, λ *, x *) are:

$$ Gk{q^{*}}^{{^{{k - 1}}}}{p_e} - {p_c} - \phi \alpha \theta {\kappa^{{\frac{1}{{1 - {\theta^{*}}}}}}} - {p_d}\alpha (1 - {\theta^{*}}) - {\lambda^{*}}\alpha (1 - {\theta^{*}}) = 0 $$
(17)
$$ - \phi \alpha {q^{*}}{\kappa^{{\frac{1}{{1 - \theta }}}}}\left( {1 + \frac{{\theta \ln \kappa }}{{{{(1 - \theta )}^2}}}} \right) + {p_d}\alpha {q^{*}} + {\lambda^{*}}\alpha {q^{*}} = 0 $$
(18)

Solving Eq. 18, we have:

$$ {\lambda^{*}} = \phi {\kappa^{{\frac{1}{{1 - \theta }}}}}\left( {1 + \frac{{\theta \ln \kappa }}{{{{(1 - \theta )}^2}}}} \right) - {p_d} $$
(19)

Here, λ * is the Lagrangian multiplier and represents the marginal profits of a unit permit.

Appendix 2: Estimation of Future Price (p 2)

The shadow price of the emissions permit is influenced by the price of electricity and coal. Thus, we assume that all firms estimate the future price based on the status of current emission discharge (E 2 = E 1). Thus, we have:

$$ \max \pi = Gq_2^k{p_{{e2}}} - {p_{{c2}}}{q_2} - \phi \alpha {q_2}{\theta_2}{\kappa^{{\frac{1}{{1 - {\theta_2}}}}}} - {p_d}\alpha {q_2}(1 - {\theta_2}) - {p_2}{x_2} - a - b\left| {{x_2}} \right| $$
(20)
$$ {\mathrm{subject} \mathrm{to}\text{:}}\quad A + {x_2} - \alpha {q_2}(1 - {\theta_2}) = 0 $$
(21)

The solution is described by the following first-order equations:

$$ Gkq_2^{{k - 1}}{p_{{e2}}} - \phi \alpha {\kappa^{{\frac{1}{{1 - {\theta_2}}}}}}\left( {1 + \frac{{{\theta_2}\ln \kappa }}{{1 - {\theta_2}}}} \right) - {p_{{c2}}} = 0 $$
(22)
$$ \lambda = \phi {\kappa^{{\frac{1}{{1 - {\theta_2}}}}}}\left( {1 + \frac{{{\theta_2}\ln \kappa }}{{{{(1 - {\theta_2})}^2}}}} \right) - {p_d} $$
(23)
$$ - {p_2}\pm b + \lambda = 0 $$
(24)

where p c2 and p e2 are, respectively, the estimated coal price and electricity price for the next period. As E 1 = E 2 = αq 2(1 − θ 2), we have:

$$ Gk{q_2}^{{k - 1}}{p_{{e2}}} - \phi \alpha {\kappa^{{\frac{{\alpha {q_2}}}{{{E_1}}}}}}\left( {1 + \frac{{(\alpha {q_2} - {E_1})\ln \kappa }}{{{E_1}}}} \right) - {p_{{c2}}} = 0 $$
(25)

where q *2 is the solution of Eq. 22 and λ * is the Lagrangian multiplier, which represents the shadow price of one unit permit. Thus, firms estimate the future price as p 2 = λ * + b for sellers and p 2 = λ * − b for buyers. According to Eq. 25, p 2 is mainly affected by the estimated p c2 and p e2. Herein, we assume that the estimated percentage increase of p c is o. Thus, we have:

$$ {o_i} = \frac{{{p_{{ci2}}}}}{{{p_{{ci}}}}} $$
(26)

In our paper, we assume that coal price (p c ) increases 10 % annually from 2006 to 2010 and 5 % annually from 2011 to 2020. Thus, we set o i to be uniformly distributed over the range [0.05, 0.15] from 2006 to 2009 and [0.0, 0.1] from 2010 to 2009. p e2 is calculated based on Eq. 27. o i is generated at the beginning of every trading period.

$$ \Delta {p_{e}} = \frac{{\left( {1 - 30\% } \right)\Delta {p_{c}}q}}{{G{q^{k}}}} $$
(27)

Appendix 3: Learning Strategies

At a given time t, an individual ZIP agent (denoted by subscript i) calculates the shout price p i (t) from price λ i,j using the agent’s real valued profit margin μ i (t) according to:

$$ {p_i}(t) = {\lambda_{{i,j}}}\left( {1 + {\mu_i}(t)} \right) $$
(28)

This implies that a seller’s margin is raised by increasing μ i and lowered by decreasing μ i with the constraint that μ i (t) ∊ [−1, 0]:∀t. The aim is that the value of μ i for each trader should alter dynamically in response to the actions of other traders in the market, increasing or decreasing to maintain a competitive match between that trader’s shout price and the shouts of the other traders. According to the Widrow–Hoff “delta rule” [51], we have:

$$ Y\left( {t + 1} \right) = Y(t) + \varDelta (t) $$
(29)

where Y(t) is the actual output at time t, Y(t + 1) is the actual output in the next time step, and \( \varDelta (t) \) is the change in output, determined by the product of the learning rate coefficient v and the difference between Y(t) and the desired output at time t, denoted by D(t):

$$ \varDelta (t) = v\left( {D(t) - Y(t)} \right) $$
(30)

The following adaptation method is employed by the ZIP traders. When a trader is required to increase or decrease its profit margin, a “target price” (denoted τ i (t)) will be calculated for each trader and the Widrow–Hoff rule will then be applied to make the trader’s shout price in the next time step (p i (t + 1)) closer to the target price τ i (t). Because the shout price is calculated using the (fixed) limit price λ i,j and (variable) profit margin μ i , it is necessary to rearrange Eq. 27 to give an updated rule for the profit margin μ i in the transition from time t to t + 1:

$$ {\mu_i}\left( {t + 1} \right) = {{{\left( {{p_i}(t) + {\Delta_i}(t)} \right)}} \left/ {{{\lambda_{{i,j}}} - 1}} \right.} $$
(31)

where Δ i (t) is the Widrow–Hoff delta value calculated using the individual trader’s learning rate β i :

$$ {\Delta_i}(t) = {v_i}\left( {{\tau_i}(t) - {p_i}(t)} \right) $$
(32)

All that remains is to determine how to set the target price τ i (t). While a simple method would be to set the target price equal to the price of the last shout (i.e., τ i (t) = q(t)), this presents a significant problem. When the last shout price is very close to or equal to the trader’s current shout price (i.e., p(t) ≈ q(t)), the value of Δ i (t) given by Eq. 31 will be very small or 0. Thus, traders who would have shouted prices close to q(t) are likely to make negligible alterations to their profit margins, and so will shout very similar prices when next given the opportunity.

There are many ways in which the target price τ i (t) could be determined. In the our model, the target price is generated using a stochastic function of the shout price q(t):

$$ {\tau_i}(t) = {H_i}(t)q(t) + {Y_i}(t) $$
(33)

where H i is a randomly generated coefficient that sets the target price relative to the price q(t) of the last shout price and Y i (t) is a (small) random absolute price alteration (or perturbation). When the intention is to increase the dealer’s shout price, H i  > 1.0 and Y i  > 0.0; when the intention is to decrease it, 0.0 < H i  < 1.0 and Y i  < 0.0. In our model, we set H i to be uniformly distributed over the range [1.0, 1.05] for price increases and over [0.95, 1.0] for price decreases, giving relative rises or falls of up to 5 % and Y i is uniformly distributed over [0.0, 0.1] for increases and [−0.1, 0.0] for decreases. The value of each trader’s learning rate v i is randomly generated when the trader is initialized, using values uniformly distributed over [0.1, 0.5].

Appendix 4: Parameters Initialization

We assume that all power plants have the same value of k; therefore, we have the regression equation:

$$ \ln \left( {{g_i}} \right) = k\ln \left( {{q_i}} \right) + \ln {G_i} + \varepsilon $$
(34)

Here, ɛ is the error. Using the real data of 45 power plants, the regression results are presented in Table 3. The coefficient of ln q is the value k in Eq. 34. Therefore, we have k = 0.92011 (see Table 3).

Table 3 Regression results of Eq. 34

In addition, we assume that all the power plants have the same value of κ and distinct ϕ i . α i q i θ i is the emission reduction for power plant i. Thus, we have the regression equation:

$$ \ln {c_i} = \ln {\phi_i} + \ln {R_i} + {x_i}\ln \kappa + {\varepsilon_i} $$
(35)

Here, \( {x_i} = \frac{1}{{1 - {\theta_i}}} \) and ɛ is the error. Using the database of 45 power plants, the regression coefficient of x i is the value ln κ. Therefore, we have ln κ = 0.0565 and κ = 1.0581363(see Table 4).

Table 4 Regression results of Eq. 35

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Zhou, Y., Wu, Y., Zhang, B. et al. Understanding the Price Dynamics in the Jiangsu SO2 Emissions Trading Program in China: A Multiple Periods Analysis. Environ Model Assess 18, 285–297 (2013). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10666-012-9343-1

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10666-012-9343-1

Keywords

Navigation