Appendix 1: Generating a collusive industry
The dataset that is used in the above regressions is generated by running the simulation model with the parameter values given in Table 5. Except for the number of cartelists m, these parameter values are randomly determined from uniform distributions within the bounds provided by Table 5.
Choosing n ∈ [7,15] is reasonable because, first, all firms would join the cartel with probability 1 if the number of firms was too small. Second, the time for calculating the participation-equilibrium rises exponentially in the number of firms and, thus, would be undesirably long for n > 15. From the viewpoint of economic theory, the size of ν is irrelevant as it only affects the size of prices and quantities but does not have an impact on the ratio of profit-measures. Using μ
upper
= 100 as an upper bound is reasonable as it suffices to produce rather homogeneous goods. Choosing a
1 ∈ [0.05, 1.0] is reasonable because values below 0.05 would indicate that marginal costs are quite negligible. The production of such firms may be supposed to rather generate fixed costs that, however, are beyond the scope of this model. Choosing a
4 ∈ [0.05, 0.15] gives economically meaningful yet not unrealistically large cost shocks. Drawing P from the wide interval [0.05, 0.4] reflects our lack of knowledge about the effectiveness of competition authorities. This is because one knows the number of discovered cartels but can hardly determine the number of undiscovered ones. The interval encloses the 15–20% detection probability that some studies suggest. Choosing r ∈ [0.05, 0.25] suggests that firms’ discount rate is somewhere between the return of government bonds and some (ambitious) firms’ target value of their return on equity. The number of cartelists m is determined endogenously as the mixed-strategy Nash-equilibrium of the cartel-formation game.