Skip to main content
Log in

Distinct role of targeting precision of Internet-based targeted advertising in duopolistic e-business firms’ heterogeneous consumers market

  • Published:
Electronic Commerce Research Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Advances in information technologies and e-commerce enable e-business firms to collect detailed consumers’ data and send Internet-based targeted advertising to their potential consumers accurately, thereby performing B2C sales. However, the perfect targeting for an e-business firm is always a challenge due to the asymmetric information between the firm and consumers. This essay starts by setting up a model with two horizontally differentiated firms competing in prices and targeted advertising at a variable targeting precision in an initially uninformed heterogeneous consumers market. The results indicate that both e-business firms should target only their advantage markets with optimal targeting precision. Otherwise, each e-business firm’s equilibrium profit might be lower or higher with Internet-based targeted advertising comparing to mass advertising, which depends on the effective choice of distinct targeting precision. Finally, the effective investment on the optimal targeting precision for e-business firms pursuing the maximum profit in the B2C sales model is generated.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2

Similar content being viewed by others

References

  1. Ansari, A., & Mela, C. (2003). E-customization. Journal of Marketing Research,40(2), 131–145.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  2. Athey, S., & Gans, J. S. (2010). The impact of targeting technology on advertising markets and media competition. Available at SSRN 1535325.

  3. Bergemann, D., & Bonatti, A. (2011). Targeting in advertising markets: Implications for offline versus online media. The Rand Journal of Economics,42(3), 417–443.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  4. Butter, H., & Petrakis, E. (1995). Price competition and advertising in oligopoly. European Economic Review,39, 1075–1088.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  5. Butters, G. (1977). Equilibrium distributions of sales and advertising prices. Review of Economic Studies,44, 465–491.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  6. Celik, L. (2007). Strategic informative advertising in a horizontally differentiated duopoly. Mimeo, CERGE-EI 2008, Working Paper series (ISSN 1211-3298); Center for Economic Research and Graduate Education, Academy of Sciences of the Czech Republic, Economics Institute.

  7. Chen, Y., Narasimhan, C., & Zhang, Z. J. (2001). Individual marketing with imperfect targetability. Marketing Science,20(1), 23–41.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  8. Chen, Y., & Iyer, G. (2002). Consumer addressability and customized pricing. Marketing Science,21, 197–208.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  9. Chen, Y., & Zhang, Z. J. (2009). Dynamic targeted pricing with strategic consumers. International Journal of Industrial Organization,27, 43–50.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  10. Elhadj-Ben Brahim, N. B., Lahmandi-Ayed, R., & Laussel, D. (2011). Is targeted advertising always beneficial? International Journal of Industrial Organization,29, 678–689.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  11. Esteban, L., Gil, A., & Hernández, J. M. (2001). Informative advertising and optimal targeting in a monopoly. The Journal of Industrial Economics,49(2), 161–180.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  12. Esteves, R. B. (2014). Price discrimination with private and imperfect information. The Scandinavian Journal of Economics,116(3), 766–796.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  13. Esteves, R. B., & Resende, J. (2016). Competitive targeted advertising with price discrimination. Marketing Science,35, 576–587.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  14. Esteban, L., & Hernández, J. M. (2007). Strategic targeted advertising and market fragmentation. Economics Bulletin,12(10), 1–12.

    Google Scholar 

  15. Gal-Or, E., & Gal-Or, M. (2005). Customized advertising via a common media distributor. Marketing Science,24(2), 241–253.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  16. Gal-Or, E., Gal-Or, M., May, J. H., & Spangler, W. E. (2006). Targeted advertising strategies on television. Management Science,52(5), 713–725.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  17. Grossman, G., & Shapiro, C. (1984). Informative advertising with differentiated products. Review of Economics Studies,51, 63–82.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  18. Hamilton, S. F. (2009). Informative advertising in differentiated oligopoly markets. International Journal of Industrial Organization,27(1), 60–69.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  19. Hallerman, D. (2010). Audience ad targeting: Data and privacy issues. eMarketer. Available at http://www.emarketer.com/Report.aspx.

  20. Hernández-García, J. M. (1997). Informative advertising, imperfect targeting and welfare. Economics Letters,55, 131–137.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  21. Iyer, G., Soberman, D., & Villas-Boas, J. M. (2005). The targeting of advertising. Marketing Science,24(3), 461–476.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  22. Johnson, J. P. (2013). Targeted advertising and advertising avoidance. The Rand Journal of Economics,44(1), 128–144.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  23. Liu, Q., & Serfes, K. (2004). Quality of information and oligopolistic price discrimination. Journal of Economics & Management Strategy,13(4), 671–702.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  24. Liu, Q., & Serfes, K. (2005). Imperfect price discrimination in a vertical differentiation model. International Journal of Industrial Organization,23(5), 341–354.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  25. Mukherjee, P., & Jansen, B. J. (2014). Performance analysis of keyword advertising campaign using gender-brand effect of search queries. Electronic Commerce Research and Applications,13(2), 139–149.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  26. Plummer, J., Rappaport, S. D., Hall, T., & Barocci, R. (2007). The online advertising playbook: Proven strategies and tested tactics from the advertising research foundation. Hoboken: John Wiley and Sons.

    Google Scholar 

  27. Roy, S. (2000). Strategic: “segmentation of a market”. International Journal of Industrial Organization,18, 1279–1290.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  28. Shaffer, G., & Zhang, Z. J. (2002). Competitive one-to-one promotions. Management Science,48(9), 1143–1160.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  29. Soberman, D. A. (2004). Additional learning and implications on the role of informative advertising. Management Science,50(12), 1744–1750.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  30. Stahl, D. (1994). Oligopolistic pricing and advertising. Journal of Economic Theory,64, 162–177.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  31. Stivers, A., & Tremblay, V. J. (2005). Advertising, search costs, and social Welfare. Information Economics and Policy,17, 317–333.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

Financial support provided by Zhejiang Provincial Natural Science Foundation of China (No. LY18G020015), China Postdoctoral Science Foundation Funded Project (No. 2017M621371), The Ministry of education of Humanities and Social Science project (19YJC630225) and National Natural Foundation of China (71673238) are gratefully acknowledged. The authors thank Dr. Leng Xue-fei, associate professor Gao Xin, and three reviewers for their valuable comments and suggestions, from which the paper benefited greatly.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Wu Dan.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Appendix

Appendix

1.1 Proof of Lemma 1

Proof

With imperfect targeting precision \(\alpha_{i}\), the e-business firm i’s profit is shown in below.

$$\pi_{i} = (p_{i} - c)\left[ {\int_{0}^{{\widehat{x}}} {\phi_{i} (x)\alpha_{i} dx + \int_{{\widehat{x}}}^{1} {\phi_{i} (x)\alpha_{i} (1 - \phi_{j} (x))dx} } } \right] - \frac{\lambda }{2}\int_{0}^{1} {(\phi_{i} (x))^{2} dx}$$
(18)

We define \(\phi_{i} = \phi_{i} (x)\) and \(\phi_{j} = \phi_{j} (x)\), \((i,j = 1,2)\). E-business firm \(i\)’s profit function in perceived advantage market is given by

$$\pi_{is} (\phi_{i} ) = (p_{i} - c)\widehat{x}\alpha_{i} \phi_{i} (x) - \frac{\lambda }{2}(\phi_{i} (x))^{2} \widehat{x}$$
(19)

Then, we choose \(\phi_{i} (x)\) that maximizes firm \(i\)’s profit respectively, when \(x_{i} \in [0,\widehat{x}]\), which implies that

$$\frac{{\partial \pi_{i} }}{{\partial \phi_{i} (x)}} = (p_{i} - c)\alpha_{i} - \lambda \phi_{i} (x) = 0$$
(20)

Likewise, \(\phi_{i} (x)\) that maximizes firm \(i\)’s profit respectively, when \(x_{i} \in [\widehat{x},1]\), which implies that

$$\frac{{\partial \pi_{i} }}{{\partial \phi_{i} (x)}} = (p_{i} - c)\alpha_{i} \left( {1 - \phi_{j} (x)} \right) - \lambda \phi_{i} (x) = 0$$
(21)

And symmetrically for Firm \(j\), which implies

$$\left\{ {\begin{array}{*{20}{l}} {\frac{{\partial \pi_{j} }}{{\partial \phi_{j} (x)}} = (p_{j} - c)\alpha_{j} \left( {1 - \phi_{i} (x)} \right) - \lambda \phi_{j} (x) = 0\begin{array}{*{20}{l}} {} & {} \\ \end{array} } \\ {\frac{{\partial \pi_{j} }}{{\partial \phi_{j} (x)}} = (p_{j} - c)\alpha_{j} - \lambda \phi_{j} (x) = 0\begin{array}{*{20}{l}} {\begin{array}{*{20}c} {} & {} \\ \end{array} } & {\begin{array}{*{20}c} {} & {} \\ \end{array} } & {} \\ \end{array} } \\ \end{array} } \right.$$
(22)

From these conditions in Eq. (20) and (23), we deduce that \(\phi_{i} (x)\) is a variable and equals to 1, or satisfied as \(\phi_{i} = \hbox{min} \left\{ {\frac{{(p_{i} - c)\alpha_{i} }}{\lambda },1} \right\}\) on \([0,\widehat{x}]\).

Likewise, \(\phi_{j} (x)\) is also variable and equals to \(\phi_{j} = \hbox{min} \left\{ {\frac{{(p_{j} - c)\alpha_{j} }}{\lambda },1} \right\}\) on \([\widehat{x},1]\). Consequently, \(\psi_{i} (x)\) is variable and equals to \(\psi_{i} = \frac{{(p_{i} - c)\alpha_{i} (1 - \phi_{j} )}}{\lambda }\) on \([\widehat{x},1]\) and \(\psi_{j} (x)\) is variable and equals to \(\psi_{j} = \frac{{(p_{j} - c)\alpha_{j} (1 - \phi_{j} )}}{\lambda }\) on \([0,\widehat{x}]\). □

1.2 Proof of Proposition 1

Proof

Here, based on the model of both e-business firms competing in targeted advertising with different targeting precision, F.O.C. condition on advertising intensity implies that

$$\left\{ {\begin{array}{*{20}l} {\frac{{\partial \pi _{i} }}{{\partial \phi _{i} }} = m_{i} \hat{x}\alpha _{i} - \lambda \phi _{i} \hat{x} = 0} \hfill \\ {\frac{{\partial \pi _{j} }}{{\partial \psi _{i} }} = m_{i} (1 - \hat{x})\alpha _{i} (1 - \phi _{j} ) - \lambda \psi _{i} (1 - \hat{x}) = 0} \hfill \\ \end{array} } \right.$$
(23)
  • When \(m_{i} < m_{j} - t\), from expression (4), \(\pi_{i1} = m_{i} \phi_{i} \alpha_{i} - \frac{\lambda }{2}\phi_{i}^{2}\). For a fixed \(m_{i}\), F.O.C. condition on \(\phi_{i}\) yields \(\phi_{i}^{*} = \frac{{m_{i} \alpha_{i} }}{\lambda }\), thus the result.

  • When \(m_{j} - t < m_{i} < m_{j} + t\), the profit is given by Eq. (4) as a function of \((\phi_{i} ,\psi_{i} )\). The Hessian matrix relative to these two variables writes with the following expression.

    $$\left( {\begin{array}{*{20}c} {\frac{{\partial^{2} \pi_{i} }}{{\partial \phi_{i}^{2} }}} & {\frac{{\partial^{2} \pi_{i} }}{{\partial \phi_{i} \partial \psi_{i} }}} \\ {\frac{{\partial^{2} \pi_{i} }}{{\partial \psi_{i} \partial \phi_{i} }}} & {\frac{{\partial^{2} \pi_{i} }}{{\partial \psi_{i}^{2} }}} \\ \end{array} } \right) = \left( {\begin{array}{*{20}c} {\frac{{ - \lambda (t - m_{i} + m_{j} )}}{2t}} & 0 \\ 0 & {\frac{{ - \lambda (t - m_{i} + m_{j} )}}{2t}} \\ \end{array} } \right)$$
    (24)

Note that this Hessian matrix is a negative definite matrix. Thus, if \((\phi_{i}^{*} ,\psi_{i}^{*} ) \in [0,1] \times [0,1]\), the global maximum profit of the e-business firm might be realized. Otherwise, the global maximum corresponds to a corner solution.

When \(\phi_{i}^{*} > 1\), we can get \(\frac{{\partial \pi_{i} }}{{\partial \phi_{i} }} > 0\), for all \(\phi_{i} \in [0,1]\). Therefore, the firm’s max profit \(\pi_{i}\) must be realized at \(\phi_{i} = 1\). Hence, \(\phi_{i}^{*} = \hbox{min} \left\{ {\frac{{m_{i} \alpha_{i} }}{\lambda },1} \right\}\) realizes the max profit of \(\pi_{i}\).

Finally, we consider the optimal value of \(\phi_{j}^{*}\). For \(\phi_{j}^{*} = 1\)(for instance, \(m_{j} [1 - \psi_{i} (1 - \alpha_{j} )] > \lambda\)), \(\frac{{\partial \pi_{i} }}{{\partial \psi_{i} }} < 0\) thus necessarily \(\psi_{i} = 0\). For \(\psi_{i} > \psi_{i}^{*}\), the maximum advertising intensity in the weak market is considered as \(\psi_{i}^{*} = \frac{{m_{i} \alpha_{i} }}{\lambda }(1 - \frac{{m_{j} \alpha_{j} }}{\lambda })\).

  • When \(m_{i} > m_{j} + t\), \(\pi_{i3} = m_{i} \alpha_{i} \psi_{i} (1 - \phi_{j} ) - \frac{\lambda }{2}\psi_{i}^{2}\). For a fixed \(m_{i}\), F.O.C. condition on the advertising intensity in the firm’s weak market yields \(\psi_{i}^{*} = \frac{{m_{i} \alpha_{i} (1 - \phi_{j} )}}{\lambda }\). As \(\phi_{i}^{*} = \frac{{m_{i} \alpha_{i} }}{\lambda }\), that means \(\phi_{j}^{*} = \frac{{m_{j} \alpha_{j} }}{\lambda }\). Therefore, \(\psi_{i}^{*} = \frac{{m_{i} \alpha_{i} }}{\lambda }(1 - \frac{{m_{j} \alpha_{j} }}{\lambda })\). □

1.3 Prof of Proposition 2

Proof

According to Eq. (2) and (4), the e-business firm’s profit can be easily expressed as follows.

$$\pi_{i} = m_{i} \left[ {\frac{{t - m_{i} + m_{j} }}{2t}\phi_{i} \alpha_{i} + \psi_{i} \frac{{t + m_{i} - m_{j} }}{2t}\alpha_{i} (1 - \phi_{j} )} \right] - \frac{\lambda }{2}\phi_{i}^{2} \frac{{t - m_{i} + m_{j} }}{2t} - \frac{\lambda }{2}\psi_{i}^{2} \frac{{t + m_{i} - m_{j} }}{2t}$$
(25)

Then, we simplify this expression (25) and can easily acquire the following result.

$$\pi_{i} = \frac{{\alpha_{i}^{2} }}{4t\lambda }\left[ {(m_{i}^{2} t - m_{i}^{3} + m_{i}^{2} m_{j} ) + (1 - \frac{{m_{j} \alpha_{j} }}{\lambda })^{2} (m_{i}^{2} t + m_{i}^{3} - m_{i}^{2} m_{j} )} \right]$$
(26)

That means the expression (26) can be simplified in below.

$$\pi_{i}^{*} = \frac{{\alpha_{i}^{2} }}{4t\lambda }(2\lambda^{2} m_{i}^{2} t - 2\lambda m_{j} \alpha_{j} m_{i}^{2} t - 2\lambda m_{j} \alpha_{j} m_{i}^{3} + 2\lambda m_{j}^{2} \alpha_{j} m_{i}^{2} + m_{j}^{2} \alpha_{j}^{2} m_{i}^{2} t + m_{j}^{2} \alpha_{j}^{2} m_{i}^{3} - m_{j}^{3} \alpha_{j}^{2} m_{i}^{2} )$$
(27)

According to F.O.C. condition,

$$\frac{{\partial \pi_{i} }}{{\partial m_{i} }} = 4\lambda^{2} m_{i} t - 4\lambda m_{j} \alpha_{j} m_{i} t - 6\lambda m_{j} \alpha_{j} m_{i}^{2} + 4\lambda m_{j} \alpha_{j} m_{i} m_{j} + 2m_{j}^{2} \alpha_{j}^{2} m_{i} t + 3m_{j}^{2} \alpha_{j}^{2} m_{i}^{2} - 2m_{j}^{3} \alpha_{j}^{2} m_{i} = 0$$
(28)

In equilibrium, \(m_{i} = m_{j} = m\), that means \(P(m)\) can be expressed as Eq. (7).

$$P(m) = \alpha_{j}^{2} m^{3} - 2\alpha_{j} m^{2} (\lambda - \alpha_{j} t) - 4\alpha_{j} \lambda mt + 4\lambda^{2} t$$

Note that the F.O.C. condition on m is given in below.

$$\frac{\partial P(m)}{\partial m} = 3m^{2} \alpha_{j}^{2} - 4m\alpha_{j} (\lambda - \alpha_{j} t) - 4\alpha_{j} \lambda t$$
(29)
$$P(2t) = 4t(2\alpha_{j} t - \lambda )^{2} > 0$$
(30)
$$P\left( {t + \frac{\lambda }{2}} \right) = \alpha_{j}^{2} \left( {t + \frac{\lambda }{2}} \right)^{3} - 2\alpha_{j} \left( {t + \frac{\lambda }{2}} \right)^{2} (\lambda - \alpha_{j} t) - 4\alpha_{j} \lambda \left( {t + \frac{\lambda }{2}} \right)t + 4\lambda^{2} t < 0$$
(31)

Hence, \(P(m)\) admits two positive roots. One of them is considered as \(2t < m^{*} < t + \frac{\lambda }{2}\). On the other hand,

$$\begin{aligned} P'(\lambda ) = \alpha_{j}^{2} \lambda^{3} - 2\alpha_{j} \lambda^{2} (\lambda - \alpha_{j} t) - 4\alpha_{j} \lambda^{2} t + 4\lambda^{2} t \\ = \lambda^{2} \left[ {(\lambda + 2t)\left( {1 - \alpha_{j} } \right)^{2} - \lambda + 2t} \right] \\ \end{aligned}$$
(32)

As \(3\lambda \alpha_{j} - 4\lambda < 0\) and \(4\alpha_{j} t - 4t < 0\), that means \(\frac{\partial P(\lambda )}{\partial \lambda } < 0\). The two positive roots of \(P(m)\), they exist, are larger than the advertising cost parameter \(\lambda\). As a result, \(P(m) > 0\) for all \(m \in [0,\lambda ]\) and shows no effect on the rival’s targeting precision. The Proposition 2 can be obtained after solving the game. □

1.4 Proof of Corollary 1 and Proposition 3

Proof

According to F.O.C. condition,

$$\frac{{\partial \pi_{i}^{*} }}{\partial m} = \frac{{m\alpha_{i}^{2} }}{{2\lambda^{3} }}[2(\lambda - m\alpha_{j} )^{2} + m\alpha_{j} \lambda ] > 0$$
(33)

Here, the implicit function theorem is used to seek the variation of the margin profit at equilibrium \(m^{*}\) as well as the advertising cost parameter \(\lambda\).

$$\frac{{dm^{*} }}{d\lambda } = - \frac{{P_{\lambda }^{'} }}{{P_{m}^{'} }}$$
(34)
$$\frac{\partial P(m)}{\partial \lambda } = 2(4\lambda t - 2\alpha_{j} mt - \alpha_{j} m^{2} )$$
(35)

Then, the following expression can be deduced.

$$P(\sqrt {2\lambda t/\alpha_{j} } ) = 2\lambda (2\lambda t - 2\alpha_{j} m^{2} ) < 0$$
(36)

Finally, replacing in this expression m by \(m = \sqrt {2\lambda t/\alpha_{j} }\), and then \(P(\sqrt {2\lambda t/\alpha_{j} } ) = - \frac{{m\alpha_{j} }}{2}\frac{{\partial P(\sqrt {2\lambda t/\alpha_{j} } )}}{\partial \lambda } < 0\).

Consequently,\(\sqrt {2\lambda t/\alpha_{j} } > m^{*}\), which implies \(2\lambda (2\lambda t - 2\alpha_{j} m^{2} ) > 0\). Hence, according to Eq. (36), for \(m = m^{*}\),\(\frac{{\partial P(m = m^{*} )}}{\partial \lambda } < 0\), thus \(\frac{{dm^{*} }}{d\lambda } > 0\). □

1.5 Proof of Proposition 6 and Proposition 7

Proof

In equilibrium, \(m_{i} = m_{j} = m\), and then it is easy to obtain both firms’ optimal profits in below.

$$\pi_{i}^{*} = \frac{{m^{2} \alpha_{i}^{2} }}{2\lambda }\left[ - \frac{{m^{3} \alpha_{i} }}{2\lambda } - \left(\frac{{\alpha_{i} }}{2\lambda } - 1 \right)m^{2} - m + \frac{9}{8}\right]$$
(37)
$$\pi_{j}^{*} = \frac{{m^{2} (2\lambda - m\alpha_{i} )^{2} }}{{8\lambda^{3} }}$$
(38)

Consequently, the related conclusion of Proposition 6 can be obtained. □

Proof

Then, we compare the firm \(i\)’s equilibrium targeting intensity in its advantage market and weak market as proof of the aforementioned Lemma 1.

$$\frac{{\varphi_{i}^{*} }}{{\psi_{i}^{*} }} = \frac{{\alpha_{is} \lambda }}{{\alpha_{iw} (\lambda - m_{j} \alpha_{js} )}}$$
(39)

Consequently, the related conclusion of Proposition 7 can be obtained. □

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Jiang, Z., Dan, W. & Jie, L. Distinct role of targeting precision of Internet-based targeted advertising in duopolistic e-business firms’ heterogeneous consumers market. Electron Commer Res 20, 453–474 (2020). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10660-019-09388-x

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10660-019-09388-x

Keywords

Navigation