1 Introduction

What regulatory rules are required to preserve the Internet as a non-discriminatory, public network and a platform for innovation? For almost two decades, this question has been at the centre of one of the most protracted controversies in the history of modern telecommunications: the network neutrality debate. While the origins of the debate can be traced back to the late 1990s and discussions about open access, it was law scholar Tim Wu (2002, 2003) who coined the term ‘network neutrality’ and the underlying narrative that the codification of non-discrimination principles is necessary to safeguard an open Internet.

While there has never been a generally accepted definition of what network neutrality entails (e.g., Krämer et al., 2013), a continuum of interpretations and a variety of regulations have emerged over time. Proponents of network neutrality regulations argue that the introduction of such rules is imperative in order to prevent gatekeeping broadband Internet service providers (ISPs) from selectively discriminating against (unaffiliated) content providers (CPs) by means of unreasonable network management and/or pricing, safeguard consumer choice, and maintain the public Internet as an open platform that facilitates permissionless innovation; opponents contend that such harmful behaviour cannot be expected. Rather, they argue, such regulations would unduly restrict the entrepreneurial freedom and lead to distorted investment decisions and innovation incentives. By 2015, after almost a decade of back-and-forth, both the EU and the U.S. had imposed strict forms of network neutrality regulations. Beyond imposing transparency rules, these regulations codified rules to prevent discriminatory behaviour and thus unreasonable network management. While some developed countries, like New Zealand and Australia, never implemented network neutrality regulations in the first place,Footnote 1 the U.S. reversed their regulations in 2017, thus returning to a less strict regime based mainly on transparency obligations. The EU, however, has maintained its course and recently published the second version of its net neutrality implementation guidelines (BEREC, 2020).

In contrast to the strong visions embedded in strict network neutrality regulations in the EU and some other OECD countries, clear evidence of the impact of net neutrality regulation on firm decisions does not exist thus far. This is remarkable, as net neutrality regulations represent a major market intervention with ambiguous welfare effects for key economic stakeholders in the Internet ecosystem (CPs, ISPs, and users). Numerous theoretical contributions have examined various trade-offs related to net neutrality regulation, in particular, its effects on network investments, content innovation, and social welfare (Easley et al., 2018; Greenstein et al., 2016). However, there still do not exist studies empirically assessing the welfare effect of net neutrality regulations, while only a very few (and mostly U.S.-based) studies provide evidence on its impact on ISPs’ network investment using rather broad measures of investment. This paper aims to contribute to this stream of analyses by providing first empirical results on the causal impact of net neutrality regulations on ISP platforms’ investment using a comprehensive and recent OECD panel data set for 32 countries for the years from 2000 to 2021 which covers the entire fiber deployment period. Our main dependent variable measures investment activities by ISPs in terms of newly installed fiber-based broadband connections. To obtain our main variable of interest, i.e., net neutrality regulations implemented in a particular OECD country, we reviewed past regulatory decisions and constructed indicator variables measuring the year of implementation of net neutrality regulations as well as the year of the first official announcement of intended measures in proposals or other official draft documents.

In order to identify causal effects, we employ panel data estimation techniques, including instrumental variables. We first explore a scenario in which we assume that decisions to implement or withdraw net neutrality regulations have been made by politicians who do not observe on a day-to-day basis relevant market outcome variables, but rather decide according to ideological and partisan views and in light of bureaucratic goals. We then relax the assumption that net neutrality regulations are uncorrelated with idiosyncratic error terms and re-estimate our empirical specification using two-stage least square estimation. Since net neutrality regulations have been implemented on the basis of political decisions, political economy variables should have strong predictive power. Accordingly, we employ measures of political orientation, government intervention, and the international state of net neutrality regulations as exogenous sources of variation.

In view of the core arguments of net neutrality proponents and opponents, as well as the main trade-offs identified in the relevant economics literature, we aim to investigate the following research question: Do net neutrality regulations lower the incentives of ISPs to invest in new fiber-based network infrastructure (as suggested by net neutrality opponents)?

We find that net neutrality exerts a negative impact on fiber investment. This empirical result indicates that strict network neutrality regulations slow down investment in fiber-based broadband connections and thus also indirectly on related subscriptions of consumers. Though we cannot provide an overall assessment on the effect of net neutrality regulations on social welfare, which would also have to take into account the impact on content provision and prices consumers have to pay for high-speed broadband connections, our main result indicates that net neutrality regulations seriously impact the deployment of general-purpose broadband infrastructures which generate considerable externalities across a wide range of sectors of the economy (Akerman et al., 2015; Briglauer & Gugler, 2019; Czernich et al., 2011; Lobo et al., 2020).

The remainder of this article is structured as follows. Section 2 provides an overview of the related theoretical and empirical literature. Section 3 discusses the relevant institutional background and provides a description of net neutrality regulations and historical developments, with a special focus on the EU and U.S. Section 4 then outlines our empirical specification and identification strategy. Section 5 characterizes our OECD panel data set. Section 6 discusses our main estimation results, while the final section concludes with a review of our main findings and most relevant policy implications for the ongoing debate.

2 Literature review and predictions

Economists approached the topic of network neutrality regulations somewhat belatedly. Scholars from other fields, such as law and computer science, had recognized the relevance of the topic earlier (Faulhaber, 2011). In the meantime, however, a considerable body of theoretical economic literature has formed. Acknowledging the large amount of literature, which has been summarized in several surveys, we briefly review the main findings from related economic theory models based on two-sided market frameworks in Sect. 2.1. In this Section we also briefly report the main results of a two-sided model we developed and presented in Appendix 1. In contrast, the empirical literature is still very scant, and is reviewed comprehensively in Sect. 2.2.

2.1 Theoretical contributions and predictions

A majority of the theoretical economic literature explores the impact of network neutrality regulations on market outcomes by applying game-theoretical analyses in the context of two-sided market frameworks. While typically investigating the effects of vertical control by ISPs, this literature conceptualizes network neutrality regulations as strict forms of ex-ante market interventions—either imposing traffic regulations that instate an egalitarian regime in which ISPs are legally obliged to treat all traffic equally, or else banning ISPs from charging CPs termination fees (i.e., positive prices for the delivery of content and applications to users). The impact of network neutrality regulations is then assessed based on the comparison of two different scenarios. One presents a ‘neutral’ scenario in which strict network neutrality is legally enforced and ISPs offer a single ‘best-effort’ service to all CPs. Price and quality differentiations are excluded. This scenario is compared with a second one in which ISPs can deviate from the best-effort service model. In addition to a best-effort-type basic and free service class, ISPs offer CPs prioritized traffic delivery via a premium service class against a fee. In these model frameworks, ISPs can – absent network neutrality regulations – freely enter into contractual agreements with CPs.

Schuett (2010), Sidak and Teece (2010), Faulhaber (2011), Krämer et al. (2013), Greenstein et al. (2016), Easley et al. (2018) and Jamison (2019) provide excellent reviews of this strand of literature. The model approaches typically assume imperfect competition and market structures characterized by monopolistic or duopolistic ISPs, which act as gatekeepers between CPs on one market side and users on the other. While the models explore different trade-offs related to market outcomes like social welfare, network investment, (content) innovation, and consumer prices, they vary with regard to the underlying modelling assumptions (e.g., concerning revenue models or traffic architectures and whether or how congestion and traffic stochastics are taken into account) and the market structures on the CP market side and the market for ISPs.

Choi and Kim (2010) is the first paper to examine investment under a strict network neutrality regime. The authors consider a monopolistic ISP and duopolistic CP market in a Hotelling framework and find that capacity expansion might decrease the sale price of the priority right under the discriminatory regime, leading to ambiguous effects on ISPs’ investment.Footnote 2 Another paper that examines the impact of network neutrality on ISP investment incentives is Cheng et al. (2011). The authors consider a setting of a monopolistic ISP and duopolistic CP market in a Hotelling framework and find that – “except in some specific circumstances” (Cheng et al., 2011, p. 60) – investment incentives for the ISP are higher under net neutrality. ISP’s investment incentives were also examined in Baranes and Vuong (2020). In their model, a monopolistic ISP could technically provide separate quality upgrades to two vertically differentiated CPs. The authors show that ISP provides asymmetric quality upgrades, in favor of the high-quality CP. However, this practice increases the degree of content differentiation, softening competition between the CPs. Their main result is that ISP’s investment level is higher if the ISP can charge the CPs, but this regulatory option might negatively affect CPs’ competition and the overall welfare.

Other papers adopted an oligopolistic setting both in the ISPs’ and CPs’ markets. Bourreau et al. (2015) analyze how the change from a strict network neutrality regime to a ‘discriminatory regime’ impacts social welfare, ISPs’ investments, and CPs’ innovation. Examining the case of two competing and horizontally differentiated ISPs and heterogeneous CPs, the authors find that removing a strict net neutrality regime would lead to higher ISP investments, more innovation by CPs, and increased social welfare. Similarly, Njoroge et al. (2017) also examine investment incentives of ISPs under both a neutral and non-neutral network regime. The authors model two interconnected ISPs competing over quality and prices for heterogenous CPs and heterogeneous consumers. They show that ISPs’ quality-investment levels are driven by the trade-off between softening price competition on the consumer side and increasing revenues extracted from CPs. Since in the non-neutral regime, ISPs can extract surplus through pricing CPs, ISPs’ investment levels are higher.

In Appendix 1, we also present a simplified model to capture the effect of network neutrality on ISPs’ investment incentives in presence of both a monopolistic or oligopolistic ISPs segment. We expand the model by Economides and Tåg (2012) by incorporating ISP investment to upgrade the network by deploying fiber-optic cable infrastructure in the access network. Such network investments increase broadband capacity and the quality characteristics of broadband services and applications, thus allowing CPs to offer better service and customer experience and more content to users. Our results show that both in a monopolistic ISP setting, ISP investment incentives are higher under a paid regime than under strict network neutrality in which no payments between CPs and ISPs are permitted. Instead, results are more ambiguous in an oligopolistic setting. ISPs’ investment is higher under the conditions that CPs value additional users more highly than users value additional CPs. Intuitively, in the presence of unrestricted duopolistic competition, ISPs compete to attract both users and CPs. On the one hand, investing in high-speed broadband infrastructure is fundamental to providing more capacity to both users and CPs, thus increasing market share. On the other hand, more intense competition attracts more users and this, in turn, attracts more CPs via cross-side externalities, especially when the value of an extra user for CPs is larger than the value of an extra CP for users. When the opposite case emerges, i.e. CPs value additional users less than users value additional CPs, however, our model results point out that net neutrality regulation does spur investment by ISPs, reverting the previous results. While we intentionally kept the model as simple as possible regarding the assumed market characterization and specification of the NN regulation as a strict zero-price rule à la Economides and Tåg (2012), our model emphasizes the relevance of the trade-off between net neutrality regulations and ISP investments and the need for sound empirically assessments.

2.2 Empirical contributions

Table 1 provides an overview of the available empirical evidence. Most contributions investigate the impact of net neutrality regulations on network investment. Existing evidence is mostly based on U.S. data using (too) broad measures (such as CAPEX) for investment, which are only indirectly impacted by net neutrality regulations. All available contributions find a negative impact of such regulations on network investment, which is also broadly in line with the theoretical analysis.Footnote 3 Only Lee and Kim (2014), as well as Layton (2017), use non-U.S. based data – from South Korea and two EU countries (Denmark and the Netherlands), respectively – to examine the impact on content innovation and social welfare. Due to this limited number of investigations, however, there is no conclusive evidence with respect to these outcome variables.

Table 1 Empirical contributions concerning the impact of net neutrality regulations. Source Own presentation

Reliable empirical evidence on the various channels of net neutrality regulation is very limited, even more when focusing on empirical studies with a reliable identification strategy. We use an insrumental variables (IV) approach by implementing political variables as identification of the decision to adopt net neutrality.

3 Institutional background

3.1 Scope of net neutrality regulations

Beyond imposing transparency requirements, network neutrality regulations codify conduct rules for the Internet to safeguard non-discrimination in, and the openness of, the public Internet. For the sake of preventing access ISPs from selectively discriminating against CPs (e.g., through the blocking of lawful content, throttling of traffic of unaffiliated CPs, or paid prioritization), these regulations introduce traffic rules that draw a dividing line between reasonable and unreasonable and thus prohibited forms of network management and pricing. In the economic literature, such regulations have been mainly conceptualized via two definitions: a ‘non-discrimination rule’ (NDR) and a very basic zero-price rule (ZPR) (Schuett, 2010, pp. 1, 2; Greenstein et al., 2016, p. 128). The NDR implies an egalitarian traffic regime in which there is no traffic prioritization. It is intended to prevent network management practices by ISPs that could be used to discriminate against specific CPs, e.g., based on the selective treatment of affiliated CPs or the degradation of non-affiliated CPs. The ZPR implies that ISPs must not charge CPs a termination fee for the (prioritized) delivery of traffic.

Modern broadband platforms support the delivery of more than just access to the Internet. Relevant capacities are shared between different types of services. Broadly speaking, one can distinguish between three distinct service types (Stocker, 2020). First, there are (non-IP) legacy services like voice telephony or cable television service. These services are not IP-based and are not considered Internet services. They are not subject to network neutrality regulations. Second, there are broadband Internet access services. These services provide users with Internet connectivity. They facilitate access to the global Internet population and the evolving range of content of the public Internet. This service category constitutes the focal point of the regulatory intervention of network neutrality rules, which restrict the scope of negotiations between ISPs and CPs regarding the delivery and/or pricing of content and application services and thus the entrepreneurial freedom of ISPs to introduce price and quality differentiations. Third, there are specialized services. Although similar in many respects to broadband Internet access services, other IP-based services (i.e., specialized services) are exempt from the same rules. These services are ‘private’/‘closed’ and available only to a subset of the Internet population. They are inherently application-specific and often rely on the heavy use of network management. Thus, the heterogeneous and stringent requirements regarding the quality of traffic delivery – as become relevant for a widening range of applications and use cases (e.g., IPTV, VoIP, Tactile Internet, or the IoT) – can be met in a customized fashion. The role of specialized services will increase in view of the anticipated role of purpose-built network slices in the context of next generation mobile access networks like 5G and beyond. The emergence of 5G and the rise and evolution of clouds (e.g., content delivery networks, CDNs) further imply that growing numbers of servers – and thus content, applications, and computing resources – are being moved closer to users. Servers are increasingly deployed within the networks of access ISPs, potentially rendering corresponding services more private, intra-ISP services. Taking these developments into account, the line between what is considered public Internet or private networking, and the distinction between services that are subject to the rules and those that are not, are becoming increasingly blurred (Stocker et al., 2020).

Figure 1 below illustrates the main market players involved, traffic flows, as well as actual and potential payment streams subject to net neutrality regulations, in a stylized fashion. ZPR and NDR rules apply only to access ISPs and more specifically to the ‘Broadband Internet Access Services’ they offer.

Fig. 1
figure 1

Network neutrality, market players, and payment streams — A stylized illustration

3.2 A concise history of net neutrality regulations in the EU and the U.S.

The first efforts to impose network neutrality in the U.S. can be traced back to a set of guiding principles for the conduct of ISPs that was presented in 2005 (FCC, 2005a; b). In 2010 the FCC adopted its Open Internet Order (OIO), instating transparency regulations and a regulatory market split: broadband Internet access services were subject to strict conduct rules while other IP-based services (i.e., specialized services) were exempt from these rules. A court decision found in 2014 that the FCC lacked the authority to implement such rules. This decision motivated subsequent efforts by the FCC – dominated by a Democratic majority – to reclassify relevant broadband services as a ‘telecommunications service’, thus assuming the authority to impose common carriage, utility-style regulation. In 2015, the FCC adopted the new Open Internet Order (FCC, 2015), which instated this reclassification as well as three net neutrality rules (no blocking, no throttling, no paid prioritization) and a general conduct rule to impose a non-discrimination standard. With President Trump taking office in 2017, and a shift in party majority within the FCC, the reclassification decision and strict network neutrality rules of the 2015 OIO were reversed in 2018 (FCC, 2018). The order is still active but has become the subject of debate once again under President Biden. Democratic FCC Chairwoman Jessica Rosenworcel is committed to bring back 2015 OIO-style net neutrality regulations.Footnote 4

Initially, the regulatory stance towards network neutrality was fundamentally different in the EU. The revised regulatory telecoms framework of 2009 contained a Declaration on Network Neutrality and introduced a set of comparatively soft regulations to deal with network neutrality issues via transparency rules (EC, 2009). After a series of member states began to consider the introduction of national network neutrality regulations, with Slovenia and the Netherlands introducing national legislation, the European Commission changed course. Arguably driven by the intent to prevent regulatory fragmentation within the Digital Single Market (Marcus, 2016, pp. 265–270), in 2013, the EC issued a proposal for a regulation that subsumed network neutrality regulations, aiming to implement enhanced transparency rules and a regulatory market split that contained strict network neutrality regulations. In 2015, Regulation (EU) 2015/2120 (European Union, 2015) was adopted. It reinstated harmonization among net neutrality regimes within the EU member states. In the fall of 2016, BEREC, the Body of European Regulators for Electronic Communications, released their first guidelines for the implementation of the regulations (BEREC, 2016), which have been revised in the meantime (BEREC, 2020). The regulation is still in force, which marks a fundamental difference from the situation in U.S. for the years from 2018 to 2021.

4 Regression framework

4.1 Empirical specification

In order to answer our research question, we estimate empirical models of investment in new (fiber-based) broadband access capacities (fiber_inv). Considering the relationship between fiber investment and fiber subscription, the former is logically a pre-condition for the subscription decision of consumers. Note that the subscription decision depends on new content innovation as willingness to pay for the “fiber-premium” is determined by the incremental benefit consumers derive from innovative applications and services that can be delivered only via high-speed broadband Internet access. The consumer’s subscription decision does not depend directly on net neutrality regulations, denoted with NNR, however, NNR indirectly exerts an impact on fiber subscription by affecting ISP investment incentives (see Eq. (11) and (19) in Appendix 1). In our empirical analysis we conduct Granger causality tests to examine this relationship but also a potential feedback mechanism from the number of subscriptions on investment.

Our empirical estimation equation for fiber investment for OECD country i in year t read as follows:

$${\mathrm{ln}(fiber\_inv}_{it})={\alpha }_{0}+{\alpha }_{1}{{\mathrm{ln}(fiber\_inv}_{it-1})+{\alpha }_{2}NNR}_{it}+{{\varvec{X}}}_{it}{\varvec{\gamma}}+{\alpha }_{i}+{\alpha }_{t}+{\varepsilon }_{it}$$
(1)

Since we use the logarithm of our dependent variable measuring fiber investment, the estimation results are interpreted as percentage changes, which facilitates cross-country comparisons. Also, residuals for fiber investment data in levels are positively skewed. The binary variable NNR indicates whether net neutrality regulations (as described in Sect. 3) were introduced in a certain OECD country in a specific year; no neutrality regulation represents the base category. Note that the presence of net neutrality regulations cannot be measured as a continuous variable, it rather represents a discretionary choice of legislators at the national or EU level. The coefficient on the net neutrality variable, α2, in Eq. (1) can be used to answer our research question. As we do not have all the necessary data to estimate equilibrium conditions as outlined in Appendix 1 we can only test the shift effect of introducing net neutrality regulations. Identifying the direction of the overall effect is, however, sufficient in view of our research question and allows us to derive essential policy implications.

We include a lagged dependent variable since large infrastructure projects, like fiber-based broadband deployment, can take years to complete in practice due to rigidities (Briglauer, 2015; Briglauer et al., 2018). The dynamic specification of Eq. (1) can also be empirically tested. If α1 is equal to 0, then there are no dynamics, whereas coefficient estimates between 0 and 1 are consistent with a dynamic adjustment process that leads to a steady state. Note that 1 −  α1 measures the speed of investment adjustment and the coefficients for the long-run (static) relationships can be derived from the dynamic model as α2/(1 −  α1) (Briglauer et al., 2018; Grajek & Röller, 2012). Equation (1) further contains a vector of covariates, Xit. We add fixed effects (αi) to capture time-invariant heterogeneity within countries and period effects (αt). Finally, εit represents an additive error term.

4.2 Identification strategy

First, in view of the potentially strong role of fixed effects as a determinant of broadband deployment, we start with an ordinary two-way fixed effects (FE) estimator. The fixed effects model ensures that individual country-level effects capture any time-invariant unobserved heterogeneity that is possibly correlated with the regressors. To obtain consistent estimates for the vector of coefficients, this specification requires strict exogeneity which represents a strong identifying assumption in general. However, major cost determinants of broadband investment, such as costs of civil engineering and network construction, are impacted by topographical factors such as ground conditions and stable regulations, including rights of way and provisions on network cooperation. These factors show either no or only very low variation over time and are therefore largely captured by the fixed effects (Briglauer et al., 2018). Furthermore, broadband infrastructure upgrades are subject to rather long investment horizons; hence, both represent a long-run decision that relies on the expectation of stable market conditions.

Period effects cover common shocks, such as macroeconomic business cycles, that are (to a large extent) common to all OECD countries, which already exhibit by their member status rather similar levels of economic development. Controlling for country fixed and period effects thus already provides strong support for the ‘selection on observables’ identifying assumption. In a similar vein, Akerman et al. (2015), examining basic broadband investment, summarize as follows: “We find that 89% of the variation in broadband coverage can be attributed to time-invariant municipality and industry characteristics and common time effects, while less than 1% of the variation in broadband coverage can be attributed to a large set of time-varying variables.”

Second, as shown in Sect. 3.2, net neutrality policy decisions have been subject to strong ideological and partisan views. An extreme case is the sequence of past net neutrality policy decisions in the U.S., where the nature of the debate surrounding net neutrality has been unusually partisan for an ICT issue (Jamison, 2019). Whereas the U.S. regulatory authority introduced strict net neutrality regulations in 2015 – the three Democratic commissioners voted for the 2015 decision and the two Republican commissioners voted against it – the decision was effectively vacated in 2017 when Republicans gained a 3:2 majority at the FCC. Despite Chairwoman Rosenworcel’s commitment to bring back 2015 OIO-style net neutrality regulations, the pending confirmation of the 5th FCC commissioner is currently delaying law making in this matter (DiMolfetta, 2022). Similarly, in other OECD countries, and within EU member states in particular, the shift in net neutrality regulations can be seen as an outcome of a political decision-making process such as bureaucrats striving to maximize harmonization within the EU. This bureaucratic goal is apparently not driven by relevant market variables such as investment, innovation, or subscription choices. Also, politicians do not observe on a day-to-day basis relevant market outcome variables and therefore do not react to market shocks. In that sense, our binary indicator variable measuring net neutrality regulations represents a political economy variable, which is presumably exogenous with respect to market decisions.

Third, to deal with remaining endogeneity concerns related to time-variant heterogeneity, we perform two-way fixed effects regressions with external instrumental variables. Using several instrumental variables not only allows us to test the validity of instruments but also our presumption of net neutrality regulations being an exogenous policy variable.

Whereas the partisan influence on net neutrality regulations has likely not been as strong in all OECD countries, left-wing political parties tend to exhibit a stronger preference for regulations and equality concerns in general (“free Internet for all”), whereas right-wing parties tend to prefer deregulation and market-driven outcomes. Accordingly, a variable measuring right- and left-wing political majorities should be an informative predictor of whether or not net neutrality regulations are implemented in a certain country. Similarly, we employ measures of the overall degree of governmental intervention in a certain OECD country. The higher the degree of overall public intervention, the greater the extent of sector-specific intervention such as net neutrality. These variables represent political economy variables at the national level. Finally, the discussion in Sect. 3.2 identified international spillover effects of net neutrality regulations, which have affected most of the developed countries since the early 2000s. Although these spillover effects might not induce policy debates and decisions in all regions, they have certainly impacted policy debates and decisions within supranational regions and similar jurisdictions.

Finally, the inclusion of a lagged dependent variable as a right-hand side regressor in Eq. (1) introduces another source of endogeneity. Estimating our baseline equations by means of an ordinary FE estimator would yield inconsistent and biased results, since the lagged dependent variable and the error terms would be correlated (Nickell, 1981). For this reason, we also employ a bias-corrected fixed-effects estimator (FEC), developed by Bruno (2005a, b) for dynamic and potentially unbalanced panel data, and a small number of cross-sectional units (N = 32).Footnote 5

5 Data

We investigate the effects of net neutrality regulations in 32 OECD countries using panel data for the years from 2000 to 2021. Note that our period of analysis covers the entire fiber-based broadband deployment period, which started with some early projects in Sweden, Norway, Japan and South Korea. The source for our dependent variables (Sect. 5.1) is the database of the FTTH Council Europe, which includes annual numbers of deployed fiber-based broadband connections for all OECD countries. Our main independent variable of interest, i.e., implemented net neutrality regulations in a particular OECD country, is constructed as a binary indicator based on our own research (Sect. 5.2). Finally, we use several other data sets for our control and instrumental variables (Sects. 5.3 and 5.4). All sources and variable definitions are described in detail in Table 4, while descriptive statistics are provided in Table 5 in Appendix 2. Because a few values are missing, there are fewer than the maximum number of observations.Footnote 6

5.1 Dependent variables: fiber investment and subscription

Our dependent variable measures relevant fiber investments by local access ISPs in logarithmic form, denoted with ln(fiber_inv). Fiber investment is measured in real terms as the absolute number of connections deployed, representing newly installed fiber-based broadband Internet access capacity in a given country. In contrast, fiber subscription measures the absolute number of subscribing consumers and businesses who show a willingness to pay for new high-speed broadband access and related content and services under a commercial contract.

We include all relevant fiber-based broadband technologies, which either deploy fiber-optic cables directly to the premises of consumers (homes or offices) or partly rely on old (‘legacy’) copper wire and coaxial cable connections in the remaining segment of the access network (‘hybrid fiber’) connecting the customer premises with the last distribution point. From that point on, all data transmission is fiber-based (see Table 4 in Appendix 2 for further technical details). Note that, instead of using broad investment measures such as CAPEX, we have a physical measure of investment, i.e., new fiber-based lines related to ISP local access networks, which are subject to net neutrality regulations (Sect. 3.1).

5.2 Main explanatory variables: net neutrality regulations

30 out of 32 selected OECD countries implemented net neutrality regulations as described in Sect. 3.1 during the period of analysis. Only Australia and New Zealand opted not to implement any net neutrality regulations during this period.Footnote 7 In all other OECD countries, there have been some kind of net neutrality regulations imposed for at least one year during the period from 2000 to 2021. Note that strict net neutrality regulations in terms of ZPR and/or NDR also include soft regulations such as codes of conduct or transparency regulations. The dummy variable NNR hence takes on value 1 if legally binding net neutrality regulations are implemented in country i in year t (and 0 otherwise). The date of the net neutrality regulations is based on the time of rulemaking via national or, in the case of EU member states, supranational legislation. As investment decisions are subject to strong rigidities, we also include lagged values of our net neutrality variable (L.NNR) in estimating Eq. (1). Moreover, if firms correctly anticipated (and responded to) future implementation of net neutrality regulations, then the effects of currently implemented regulations would underestimate the true total effect of net neutrality regulations. For this reason, we also consider the impact of the first public announcement of proposed net neutrality regulations and related expectation effects (NNR(expect)). Table 6 (Appendix 2) provides a detailed overview of net neutrality regulations in individual OECD countries with their respective year of rulemaking, date of first announcement, and sources.

5.3 Control variables

All control variables are described in detail in Table 4 of Appendix 2. The vector of investment covariates, Xit, contains measures of macroeconomic conditions relevant for the investment decision, including the long-term interest rate, lt_ir, and the investment freedom, free_invest, of a country. Deployment costs are determined by population density, pop_dens, in view of the strong role of economies of density in broadband deployment, and average wages, wages, capturing the costs of civil engineering work as construction work represents by far the largest share of total deployment costs. Investment further depends on market structural characteristics, such as the degree of competition among wireline cable TV broadband infrastructures, cable_comp, and from wireless broadband (mobile) networks, mobile_comp, as well as potential revenues captured by the average price level for telecommunications services, telecom_prices, and the potential market size proxied by basic broadband subscriptions, basic_broadband.

5.4 Instrumental variables

In order to capture the outcome of political election processes at EU and national levels, we grouped political parties into two ideologically distinct groups of “(rather) left-wing” and “(rather) right-wing”. The variable left_wing measures the share of the population of country i in year t voting for (rather) left-wing parties (Grajek & Röller, 2012). For all EU member states, the share is determined by the share of elected representatives joining a certain faction of the European Parliament. The different factions are then classified as (rather) left- or (rather) right-wing and the respective shares are cumulated. For all other (non-EU) countries, the political parties elected in the national parliamentary elections are classified as (rather) left-wing or (rather) right-wing. Table 7 (Appendix 2) provides an overview of country-specific sources. As another sort of political economy variable at the national level, we proxy governmental intervention in fiber deployment with the variable gov_spend, which measures the overall degree of governmental spending in the economy. We expect that more left-leaning governments, as well as governments showing higher levels of public spending, will favour regulatory measures such as interventionist net neutrality regulations.

Finally, we construct Hausman-type spatial instruments as another sort of a political economy variable at the international level. As the discussion in Sect. 3.2 illustrated, net neutrality regulations and the corresponding debates were subject to strong regional spillover effects. In view of the historical development of net neutrality regulations, we distinguish the following regions into which we categorize OECD countries accordingly: Europe, Americas, Australia & New Zealand, and Asia. Spatial instruments are then defined as the ratio of implemented (announced/proposed) net neutrality regulations in all other countries within a certain region (i.e., other than the focal country i) to the total number of other (i.e., non-focal) countries in that region and denoted with NNRi≠i (NNR(expect)j≠i).

6 Empirical results

Two-way fixed effects estimation results for the fiber investment equation are reported in Table 2.Footnote 8 In all the specifications, the coefficient of the lagged dependent variable is positive, but smaller than one, and highly significant, which means that investment is indeed subject to significant adjustment costs as expected. As described in Sect. 5.2, an ordinary FE estimator would yield inconsistent and biased results, since the lagged dependent variable and the error terms would be correlated (Nickell, 1981). It can be shown that OLS and FE estimators are likely to be biased in opposite directions in autoregressive models (Bond, 2002). Whereas OLS leads to upward biased estimates of the coefficient of lagged dependent variables, since the values of the lagged dependent variable are positively correlated with the omitted country fixed effects, FE estimates are downward biased for small T. Hence, if the dynamic model in Eq. (1) is correctly specified, the true coefficient estimates are between OLS and FE estimates. Comparing the respective coefficient estimate in regressions (1) to (3) to those in (5) to (6) in Table 2, we can indeed infer that the bias corrected (FEC) estimates lie within the interval of FE and OLS estimates. Also, the ‘dynamic bias’ introduced by including a lagged dependent variable appears to be not too severe and can thus be neglected in the further analysis of the causal effect of net neutrality regulations.Footnote 9

Table 2 Results for the fiber investment equation

The coefficient estimates of our main variable of interest, i.e., net neutrality regulations (NNR), point to a negative impact on fiber investment in all regressions in Table 2. Whereas the contemporaneous impact of implemented net neutrality regulations (NNR) and the coefficient of the variable reflecting expectations due to announcements of net neutrality regulations NNR(expect) are insignificant, the coefficient estimate of the lagged net neutrality variable (L.NNR) is significant at the 5% level in all FE regressions in regressions (1) to (4). As our net neutrality variables exhibit collinearity, we also conducted joint hypotheses tests. According to F-statistics tests (not reported), the group of net neutrality variables is jointly significant at the 5% level. Individual significance tests indicate that the negative impact of net neutrality does not immediately manifest in current investment plans of ISPs but only with some delay due to considerable rigidities in broadband deployment. The extent of this effect is, however, substantial. The respective coefficients of the lagged net neutrality variable in regressions (1) to (4) suggest that the introduction of NNR leads to a total decrease in new fiber investments by ISPs of about 22–25%.Footnote 10 We further examine whether net neutrality regulations might also capture regulatory intensity in general, the latter appears to be particularly strong under the EU regulatory framework. For this reason, we have also conducted regression (4) for the subset of European OECD states only. The respective coefficient estimates on the lagged net neutrality variable appears to be slightly higher ( − 0.268 in regression (4) vs.  − 0.256 in regression (2)) for European countries and thus provides some, albeit weak, support for our presumption.

Finally, we also interacted the net neutrality variables with the coefficient of the lagged dependent variable to test whether net neutrality also shows an impact on the speed of adjustment. The corresponding estimation coefficients were consistently insignificant (results not shown but available upon request). That is, while the desired capital stock decreases once but permanently by about 25%, there is, in contrast, no difference in the adjustment process to the long-term equilibrium. The adjustment process is driven by cost considerations of network deployment or regulatory hurdles (rights of ways, access regulations, etc.). Net neutrality regulations have no impact on these costs and factors of inertia.

All control variables in the fiber investment equation exhibit the expected signs when significant, which further reaffirms that our estimation equations are valid. Moreover, taking into account all controls, along with country fixed effects and period effects, our FE fiber investment estimation equation explains about 92% of the total within variation.

Regarding the identification of causal effects of NNR variables in the fiber investment equation, we further deal with remaining endogeneity concerns related to time-variant heterogeneity due to omitted variables by employing several sources of exogenous variation from instrumental variables (IV), as described in Sect. 4.2. Table 3 below reports the corresponding results of FE-IV estimations for the fiber investment equation where regressions (1) to (5) vary with respect to the number of observations and sets of included control and instrumental variables. Importantly, one can infer that all coefficient estimates of the lagged variable, L.NNR, remain negative and significant, although the coefficient estimates are much higher than the respective FE estimates in Table 2. Likewise, coefficient estimates of all other independent variables appear to be robust with respect to the FE and FE-IV estimators, having the same signs and similar magnitude of coefficients.

Table 3 FE-IV results for the fiber investment equation

Also, all postestimation analysis of residuals and regression diagnostics show that FE-IV estimation results represent reliable robustness analysis. According to Hansen J statistics of the overidentification test of all instruments, our respective instrument sets are jointly valid in all specifications in regressions (1) to (5). The Kleibergen-Paap (KP) test (LM statistic) of under-identification clearly rejects the null hypothesis that the estimation equation is underidentified for all regressions at the 5% significance level, implying that the excluded instruments are correlated with the endogenous regressors and thus relevant. Testing for the strength of instruments in the case of multiple endogenous variables, the inspection of the individual first-stage F-statistics is no longer sufficient. We therefore also reported Sanderson-Windmeijer multivariate F tests of excluded instruments (SWF) in our first stage results in Table 8, which suggest that our instruments are strong. Durbin-Wu-Hausman (DWH) endogeneity tests do not reject the null hypothesis of NNR variables being an exogenous variable in all regressions (1) to (5). Hence, DWH tests confirm our presumption that net neutrality regulations can, in fact, be considered as exogenous policy decisions and the respective coefficient estimates of NNR variables as reported in Table 2 are thus consistent and more efficient, representing a reliable basis for our policy conclusions in the final section.

Finally, another source of endogeneity might come from a potential indirect impact of NNR variables on investment via subscriptions on the demand side. Although such a channel is ruled out from our theoretical model, we examined this potential relationship empirically by conducting Granger causality tests. According to these tests, fiber investment indeed Granger-causes fiber subscription (p-value = 0.0000, H0: ln(fiber_inv) does not Granger-cause ln(fiber_sub)), but fiber subscriptions do not Granger-cause fiber investment (p-value = 0.1850, H0: ln(fiber_sub) does not Granger-cause ln(fiber_inv)).Footnote 11 This confirms our theoretical expectation and reaffirms us that our coefficient estimates represent true causal effects.

7 Summary and policy implications

Network neutrality regulations have been subject to major controversies in the telecommunications arena over the last two decades and major policy changes in some OECD countries. Despite substantial direct and indirect costs related to network neutrality regimes, there is no supportive evidence so far for the central claims of net neutrality proponents. In this paper, we focus on a specific effect that net neutrality may have on ISPs’ incentives to invest in high-speed broadband networks. More specifically, we provide first results on the causal impact of network neutrality regulations on fiber-based network investment by ISPs. Our empirical analysis finds that network neutrality regulations exert a significantly negative and substantial impact on fiber investments. Employing various panel estimation techniques, including instrumental variables, underlines the exogeneity of our variables measuring net neutrality policies in OECD countries, pointing to true causal effects. Comparing FE and FE-IV estimation results confirms our presumption that net neutrality regulations can be considered as an exogenous impact primarily driven by politics rather than relevant market outcomes. This negative effect does not allow us, however, assessing the overall effect of network neutrality regulations since other channels should be investigated, primarily the welfare effect of net neutrality policies on content provision and innovations. Still, as long as fiber-based investment is a precondition for consumer subscription, this also implies that net neutrality might generate another relevant societal cost.

Strict network neutrality regulations, as implemented in the EU and specified in the BEREC Guidelines, reveal a regulatory preference for network investments over the use of network management to avoid long-lasting or recurrent states of congestion (EU, 2015, Recital 15; BEREC, 2020, para. 93 at p. 29). This focus on ISP investments furthermore ignores the fact that other actors like large CPs, such as Google, Amazon, Facebook, Akamai, and Microsoft, have invested heavily in their own private networks of cables and strategically distributed servers – often jointly contributing to producing customer experience together with ISPs. Notably, these providers can to some extent introduce service differentiations and partly bypass the public and regulated Internet as they carry traffic via their private backbone networks and may also deliver content from servers positioned close to the users. From a user experience perspective, these and other mechanisms can act as technological substitutes for network management or network investment by ISPs. They are typically deployed by entities other than ISPs and provide a means for service differentiations that do not violate network neutrality regulations (Stocker et al., 2017, 2020). The majority of Internet traffic is already delivered via third-party CDNs like Akamai or Cloudflare or the distributed serving infrastructures of large CPs like Google, Netflix or Facebook that have strongly expanded their footprints of servers deployed within ISP networks in recent years (Gigis et al., 2021; Labovitz, 2019, 2020).Footnote 12 In addition to these developments, the emergence of 5G and beyond mobile broadband access networks emphasizes the future role of applications and use cases that vary considerably in their networking demands. For example, some of these applications are anticipated to have stringent demands with regard to reliable and (ultra) low latency connectivity and local computing via mobile edge computing. Notably, the delivery of such service is expected to require purpose-specific network slices – customized and application-driven virtual networks that can flexibly scale and adapt to meet the heterogeneous and dynamically changing requirements of an evolving set of different applications. Potential conflicts between anticipated 5G-based business models and strict network neutrality regulations have been discussed by several scholars (e.g., Yoo & Lambert, 2019; Frias and Martinez, 2017).

Such developments also raise questions regarding the scope and effectiveness of network neutrality regulations. Effective enforcement of network neutrality regulations requires a clear understanding of who the relevant players are, where the dividing lines between the (regulated) public Internet and (unregulated) specialized services are, and what types of network management practices are reasonable or not. In terms of welfare effects of net neutrality regulations, future research should seek to provide empirical evidence regarding relevant outcomes such as consumer prices for ISP access or content innovation. Also, as net neutrality regulations apply to mobile broadband networks as well, future research should investigate welfare related effects of net neutrality regulations on the deployment of mobile broadband networks as all previous empirical analyses exclusively referred to wireline broadband networks. Further empirical evidence is much needed in view of current developments related to the reintroduction of net neutrality regulation in the U.S. and current revisions of existing frameworks in the UK and EU.