Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Abstract

The present work proposes a theoretical framework to examine if details in the design of a consensual political system that incorporates proportional representation in the election process are necessary for it to take advantage of an inherent affinity to better accommodate the preferences of the members of a society. It is also examined if these details relate to the introduction of a satisfactory level of accountability for officials and lower levels of corruption.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Institutional subscriptions

Fig. 1
Fig. 2

Similar content being viewed by others

References

  • Acemoglu, D., Johnson, S., & Robinson, J. A. (2005). Institutions as a fundamental cause of long-run growth. In P. Aghion & S. Durlauf (Eds.), Handbook of Economic Growth. Amsterdam: Elsevier.

  • Acemoglu, D., & Robinson, J. (2012). The origins of power, prosperity and poverty. Why nations fail. New York: Crown and Crown.

    Google Scholar 

  • Altman, D. (2011). Direct democracy worldwide. New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Arrow, K. (1951). Social choice and individual values. New Haven, New York/London: Wiley/Chapman & Hall.

    Google Scholar 

  • Austen-Smith, D., & Banks, J. (1988). Elections, coalitions, and legislative outcomes. American Political Science Review, 82(2), 405–422.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Benno, T., Schneider, F., & Macinytre, A. (2011). Shadow economy, voice and accountability and corruption. In Friedrich Schneider (Ed.), Handbook on the shadow economy. Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bitros, G., & Karayiannis, A. (2013). Creative crisis in democracy and economy. New York: Springer.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Blais, A., & Bodet, M. (2006). Does proportional representation foster closer congruence between citizens and policy makers? Comparative Political Studies, 39(12), 1243–1262.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blomberg, B., Hess, G., & Weerapana, A. (2004). The impact of voter initiatives on economic activity. European Journal of Political Economy, 20(1), 207–226.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blume, L., Müller, J., & Voigt, S. (2009). The economic effects of direct democracy—a first global assessment. Public Choice, 140(3), 431–461.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Buchanan, J. (1986). The constitution of economic policy. Lecture to the memory of Alfred Nobel, December 8, 1986.

  • Cheibub, J. A., Gandhi, J., & Vreeland, J. R. (2010). Democracy and dictatorship revisited. Public Choice, 143(1–2), 67–101.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Colomer, J. (2001). Political institutions: Democracy and social choice. Oxford and New York: Oxford University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Colomer, J. (2005). It’s parties that choose electoral systems (or, Duverger’s laws upside down). Political Studies, 53(1), 1–21.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Colomer, J. (2008). Institutional design. In Todd Landmann & Neil Robinson (Eds.), Handbook of comparative politics. London: Sage.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cronin, T. (1999). Direct democracy the politics of initiative, referendum and recall. London, England, Cambridge, Massachusetts: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • de Montesquieu, Baron. (1748). De l’ Esprit des Lois, Livre XI. Reprint 1995. Paris: Éditions Gallimard.

  • de Tocqueville, A. (1835). De la Démocratie en Amérique. Nouvelle édition 1992. Hors série Connaissance. Paris: Gallimard.

  • Feld, L., & Savioz, M. (1997). Direct democracy matters for economic performance: An empirical investigation. Kyklos, 50(4), 507–538.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Frey, B., & Stutzer, A. (2000). Happiness, economy and institutions. Economic journal, 110(466), 918–938.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gerring, J., & Thacker, S. (2004). Political institutions and corruption: The role of unitarism and parliamentarism. British Journal of Political Science, 34, 295–330.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hillman, A. (2003). Public finance and public policy. Responsibilities and limitations of governments. New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Huber, J. (1996). The vote of confidence in parliamentary systems. The American Political Science Review, 90(2), 269–282.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Huber, J., & Bingham, P. (1994). Congruence between citizens and policymakers in two versions of liberal democracy. World Politics, 46(403), 291–326.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kaufmann, D., Kraay, A. (2002). Growth without governance, November, World Bank Policy Research Working Paper No. 2928.

  • Kaufmann, D., Kraay, A., & Zoido-Lobaton, P. (2000). Governance matters: From measurement to action, finance and development, 37(2). Washington DC: International Monetary Fund.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kunicova, J., & Rose-Ackerman, S. (2005). Electoral rules and constitutional structures as constraints on corruption. British Journal of Political Science, 35, 573–606.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Laffont, J., & Meleu, M. (2001). Separation of powers and development. Journal of Development Economics, 64, 129–145.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lederman, D., Loayza, N., & Reis, S. (2005). Accountability and corruption. Political institutions matter. Economics and Politics, 17(3), 1–35.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lijphart, A. (1999). Patterns of democracy. Government forms and performance in thirty six countries. New Haven: Yale University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lintott, A. (1999). The constitution of the roman empire. New York: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lizzeri, A., & Persico, N. (2001). The provision of public goods under alternative electoral incentives. The American Economic Review, 91(1), 225–239.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Madison, J. (1788a). Federalist Paper no 41. General view of the powers conferred by the constitution. The Independent Journal, January 19.

  • Madison J., (1788b). Federalist Paper no 51. The Structure of the Government Must Furnish the Proper Checks and Balances Between the Different Departments. The Independent Journal, February 6.

  • Mantzavinos, C., North, D., & Shariq, S. (2003). Learning, institutions and economic performance. Preprints of the Max Planck Institute for Research on Collective Goods. 13, Bonn.

  • Massicotte, L., & Blais, A. (1999). Mixed electoral systems: A conceptual and empirical survey. Electoral Studies, 18, 341–366.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Matsusaka, J. (2004). For the many or the few: The initiative, public policy, and american democracy. Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Matsusaka, J. (2005). The eclipse of legislatures: Direct democracy in the 21st century. Public Choice, 124, 157–177.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Matsusaka, J. (2014). Disentangling the direct and indirect effects of the initiative process. Public Choice, 160, 345–366.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nicoletti, G., Scarpetta, S. (2005). Regulation and economic performance: Product market reforms and productivity in the OECD, OECD Economics Department Working Papers, No. 460, OECD Publishing.

  • North, D. (1989). Institutions and economic growth: An historical introduction. New York: Elsevier.

    Google Scholar 

  • North, D. (1990). Institutions, institutional change and economic performance. New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • North, D., & Thomas, R. P. (1999). The rise of the western world. A new economic history. New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Olson, M. (1982). The rise and decline of nations. New Haven: Yale University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Panagopoulos, E. (1996). The greek roots of the american constitution. Athens: Papazisis Publishing House.

    Google Scholar 

  • Persson, T., Roland, G., & Tabellini, G. (1997). Separation of powers and accountability: Towards a formal approach to comparative politics. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 112(4), 1163–1202.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Persson, T., & Tabellini, G. (1999). Alfred marshall lecture. The size and scope of government—Comparative politics with rational politicians. European Economic Review, 43(4–6), 699–735.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Persson, T., & Tabellini, G. (2003). Munich lectures in economics. The economic effects of constitutions. Massachusetts: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Persson, T., & Tabellini, G. (2006). Democracy and development: The devil in the details. The American Economic Review, 96(2), 319–324.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Persson, T., Tabellini, G., & Trebbi, F. (2003). Electoral rules and corruption. Journal of the European Economic Association, 1, 958–989.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Robinson J., Torvik R. (2008). Endogenous presidentialism. NBER Working Paper 14603.

  • Sakellariou, M. (2007). Comparing the athenian democracy with new democracies. Filologos, 127, January–March, Malliaris Paideia: Athens.

  • Sartori, G. (1997). Comparative constitutional engineering (2nd ed.). New York: New York University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Stiglitz, J. (1987). Principal and agent. The New Palgrave: A Dictionary of Economics, 3, 966–971.

    Google Scholar 

  • Svensson, J. (2005). Eight questions about corruption. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 19, 19–42.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Treisman, D. (2007). What have we learned about the causes of corruption from ten years of cross national empirical research? Annual Review of Political Science, 10, 211–244.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Voigt, S. (2011). Positive constitutional economics II—A survey of recent development. Public Choice, 146, 205–256.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Weingast, B. (1997). The political foundations of democracy and the rule of law. The American Political Science Review, 91(2), 245–263.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

We thank Emma Galli, Giorgios Chortareas, Dimitris Makris, Konstantinos Pilpilidis, as well anonymous referees for extensive and constructive comments and suggestions. The usual disclaimer applies.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Michael Mitsopoulos.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Mitsopoulos, M., Pelagidis, T. A model of constitutional design and corruption. Eur J Law Econ 44, 67–90 (2017). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10657-015-9486-z

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10657-015-9486-z

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation